View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

(on November 8)
To the Fourth Joint Central Bank Research Conference on Risk Management and
Systemic Risk, Frankfurt, Germany
(via videoconference)
Financial Regulation: Seeking the Middle Way
I am pleased to participate in the panel discussion at this Fourth Joint Central Bank Research
Conference. As I will make clear, I think conferences of this sort, by contributing to our
understanding of financial innovations, can play a critical role in policymakers' decisions.
Financial innovations have been coming at a rapid pace in recent years; new financial
products have been introduced and are expanding rapidly, and new institutions have taken
on prominent roles in key financial markets. Financial technologies have improved as well
and have the potential to contribute to the efficiency and resilience of financial markets.
However, with new products and institutions comes the potential for new risks to financial
stability. As a result, we policymakers are likely to be torn. On the one hand, we may want
to encourage welfare-improving innovations by limiting the extent of regulation. On the
other hand, because of possible systemic concerns, some policymakers may want to regulate
innovative instruments and institutions even as they are developing. In my view,
policymakers can best balance these goals by expending the effort needed to understand
financial innovations as they emerge and by avoiding overregulation that may stifle valuable
innovations.
When I talk about financial innovations, I have in mind several types of developments. A
far-reaching set of innovations--and the focus of this panel--is the development and
increasing popularity of products for the transfer of credit risk. Prominent among such
innovations are credit derivatives, asset-backed securities, and secondary-market trading of
syndicated loans. Another important development has been the rapid growth of the hedge
fund industry, about which we learned a lot this morning, and its expanded role in the
financial system. On the retail side, we have seen a proliferation of new lending products in
the United States, including home-equity lines of credit, interest-only and even negativeamortization mortgages, and subprime mortgages and consumer loans.
Today, I will discuss the potential benefits and drawbacks associated with new products and
institutions and a middle way that regulators might pursue as these new products and
institutions emerge.
Benefits and Drawbacks
Financial innovations hold the promise of improved efficiency and increased overall
economic welfare. For example, new products and markets can open the door to new
investment opportunities for a variety of market participants. And improved
risk-measurement and risk-management technologies can contribute to an improved
allocation of risk as risk is shifted to those more willing and able to bear it.
Financial innovations also have the potential to boost financial stability. Risk-transfer

mechanisms can not only better allocate risk but also reduce its concentration. Improved
efficiencies and increased competition may result in substantially lower trading costs and
may consequently improve liquidity in many markets. Better liquidity, which is instrumental
to faster and more accurate price discovery and therefore to more-informative prices, can
also be brought about by an increased presence of new institutions in new or existing
markets. The entry of those new institutions into new markets can, so long as the institutions
prove resilient, increase the availability of funds to borrowers in times of stress and may thus
reduce the likelihood of credit crunches.
Although financial innovations have the capacity to improve economic welfare overall, it is
natural for policymakers to worry that innovations may have unexpected and undesirable
side effects and may even represent new sources of systemic risk. For example,
policymakers may be concerned about unexpected price dynamics or problems in
infrastructure or operations. Market participants estimate how prices and investment flows
are likely to behave for new instruments, but their understanding becomes more detailed and
more accurate only as behavior under a variety of economic conditions is observed, and the
development of that understanding obviously takes time. Under turbulent conditions, or
when new information causes market participants to question their own investment
strategies, their behavior may change rapidly, leading to rapid price changes that may seem
outsized relative to changes in economic fundamentals. That was briefly the case recently in
the market for synthetic collateralized debt obligations. Market participants did not
anticipate the sharp decline in implied default correlations that followed the downgrades of
Ford and General Motors debt. Prices moved quite a bit for a short time as portfolios were
rebalanced, but spillovers to other markets were limited, and market volatility subsequently
eased.
Problems with the infrastructure or operations that support an innovation--including the
underlying legal documentation and accounting--are also likely to be revealed only over
time, as exemplified by the technical difficulties with restructuring clauses in credit default
swaps that became apparent a few years ago. In that case, default events and related payoffs
sometimes did not occur as expected, and so actual exposures differed from those investors
had intended. The result was a change in the value of existing contracts and a period of
market adjustment as new restructuring clauses were developed and implemented.
Of course, we should not want to prevent rapid price changes or changes in investment
flows, as such changes may be appropriate as new information about fundamentals emerges.
And the occurrence of glitches in new markets and institutions need not reflect policy
failures or provide evidence that an innovation is undesirable. Preventing all such
occurrences would probably require us to stop all innovation. But neither is it desirable that
growing pains in one market or at a few institutions spill over so strongly that the financial
system as a whole could be destabilized.
A Middle Way in Regulation
Policymakers have a range of strategies available for dealing with innovation. At one
extreme, in theory we could take a completely hands-off approach, allowing new financial
markets and instruments to develop without restrictions and indeed without any scrutiny,
trusting private market participants to do everything necessary for stability and efficiency.
At the other extreme, policymakers theoretically might be quite heavy-handed, either
imposing regulations on virtually every market and instrument to stop any innovations that,
in their judgment, could cause harm or, conversely, actively fostering or subsidizing
innovations seen as desirable.

Obviously, these are extreme positions, and I do not know of any practicing policymaker
who seriously wants to pursue either extreme course. Today I wish to argue for a middle
ground in which markets are allowed to work and develop and in which policymakers work
hard to understand new developments and to help market participants see the need for
improvements where appropriate. In my view, regulations should be imposed only when
market participants do not have the incentive or the capability to effectively manage the
risks created by financial innovation. For example, explicit or implicit subsidies of some
institutions could limit market discipline of their risk-taking, leading to a concentration of
risk so large that even the most sophisticated institutions would find it next to impossible to
manage the risk under stressful circumstances. Or policymakers may be concerned that some
potential parties to innovative contracts, especially in the retail arena, are insufficiently
knowledgeable to understand or manage the associated risks. I believe such instances are
rare. Making a case for early regulatory intervention is particularly difficult when the private
parties involved in an innovation are sophisticated because, in many cases, they will be the
first to recognize possible problems and will have strong incentives to fix them and also to
protect themselves against fraud or unfair dealing.
So how should policymakers proceed down this middle path? First of all, we need to
learn--we need to understand and evaluate the innovations that are taking place in financial
markets. This process should include information sharing with other authorities, including
those in other nations, in order to benefit from the experiences in other markets and regions.
The resulting improved understanding is often enough to prepare policymakers to deal with
any breakdowns that do occur and to avoid having the breakdowns turn into systemic
problems. The U.S. response to the century date change is an example from a different
context that fits into this category. In that case, policymakers worked hard to understand the
complex practical issues and to share that knowledge with financial firms. Those firms
independently evaluated the risks they faced and took appropriate action to manage them
effectively.
Improved understanding may also ease concerns about potential risks. For example, in light
of the effects of financial consolidation on the number of firms acting as dealers in the
market for dollar interest rate options, the Federal Reserve became concerned about possible
risks to the functioning of that market. These concerns included questions about the
adequacy of risk management at the remaining dealers and about the possible effects that
problems at one of those dealers could have on its counterparties and market liquidity.
However, further investigation by Federal Reserve staff suggested that market participants
were generally managing their market and counterparty risks effectively and that those
hedging risk in the options market would not unduly suffer from a temporary disruption in
liquidity. Our wariness about concentration in this market has not disappeared as a result of
our improved understanding, but it has diminished. In general, improved knowledge about
financial innovations may prevent the imposition of unwarranted restrictions and is surely a
precursor to intelligent regulation in the event it is warranted.
A second step for policymakers walking the middle path should be to ensure that market
participants have the proper incentives and the information they need to protect themselves
from any problems related to new products, markets, or institutions; by so doing,
policymakers can perhaps mitigate those problems. Policymakers should insist that regulated
firms effectively manage the risks associated with new activities and markets, thereby
fostering effective market discipline of risk-taking, including risk-taking by unregulated
firms. Such an insistence generally does not require new regulation but rather is an

application of existing regulation in a potentially new context. One of the lessons of the
difficulties at Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM) was that the hedge fund had been
able to achieve very high levels of leverage because some regulated counterparties had not
appropriately managed their counterparty risk exposures. Subsequently, both banks and
supervisors had to reassess what such management entailed. Clearly, supervisors should
strongly encourage institutions to know their risk posture and to be able to control it and
react appropriately as circumstances change. Policymakers should insist on similarly high
risk-management standards for regulated financial institutions that provide retail products.
As a case in point, bank supervisors in the United States recently issued guidance about the
management of risks related to home-equity lines of credit. This guidance did not involve
new regulation of these instruments but rather reminded institutions offering such products
that they have an obligation to manage the resulting risks appropriately.
A pervasive lack of awareness about the risks embedded in new financial products certainly
increases the likelihood that users of those products may face difficulties and that those
difficulties may become systemic. One way policymakers can help prevent this possibility
from happening is by supporting increased transparency and disclosure. Although
counterparties in wholesale markets should generally be expected to demand and obtain the
information they need to evaluate their risks, policymakers can no doubt help establish high
standards. In the case of retail transactions, support for efforts to foster the basic financial
literacy of households is a useful complement to efforts to promote appropriate disclosure.
The more consumers are equipped to interpret disclosures, the more effective those
disclosures are likely to be.
A third feature of the moderate approach I am trying to chart is an active dialogue between
policymakers and market participants. In my view, policymakers should serve as a voice for
the development of infrastructure and sensible standards and practices. Ideally such steps
would be taken by market participants of their own volition, but sometimes informal
interventions by policymakers can help foster cooperative efforts by market participants. For
example, partly in reaction to the report of the second Counterparty Risk Management
Policy Group, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York recently hosted a meeting with
representatives of major participants in the credit default swap market, as well as with their
domestic and international supervisors, to discuss a range of issues, including market
practices with regard to assignments of trades and operational issues associated with
confirmation backlogs. The result was an industry commitment to take concrete steps to
address issues of concern.
A fourth dimension of my proposed middle path is the ongoing monitoring of key markets
and institutions. Policymakers should be aware of any emerging stresses in the financial
system, including those related to new instruments and institutions. Indeed, some central
banks have created "financial stability" staff groups to oversee such monitoring and, in some
cases, to publish regular financial stability reports. In the event that such monitoring suggests
that the operations of some institutions or markets are under significant strain and,
importantly, that the resulting pressures on businesses and households could have a material
adverse effect on the real economy, the central bank may want to respond by adjusting the
stance of monetary policy.
Finally, financial innovations may on occasion warrant new regulations because financial
institutions either cannot or will not manage the associated risks appropriately. Indeed,
regulation should be seen as part of the broader "infrastructure" that supports both financial
stability and innovation, and like other more traditional infrastructure, regulatory regimes

have to keep up. For example, developments in financial markets and advances in the ability
of banks to measure and manage their risks have increasingly made the existing capital
regulation of the largest banks, the 1988 Basel Accord, look antiquated. Basel II is a more
flexible framework than Basel I and is intended to better permit capital regulation to keep up
with financial market innovations in the future.
To conclude, I wish to emphasize that policymakers should have a bias toward trusting
financial markets to manage the introduction of new products and the development of new
institutions smoothly and without undue stress to the financial system. However, we cannot
take such an outcome for granted: Financial firms may not consider the effects of their
decisions on the stability of other firms or on the broader financial markets, and some may
lack the incentives and ability to learn about and manage the risks induced by financial
innovations. In such cases, policymakers may need to work with markets and their
participants, and on occasion regulate them, to achieve the desired outcomes. However,
policymakers should, wherever possible, avoid premature regulation that could stifle
innovation. I would note that a significant number of substantial shocks to financial markets
have occurred in recent years--including, for example, the difficulties at Long-Term Capital
Management and the unexpected and massive fraud at some high-profile companies--and
yet the broader effects on the real economy have ultimately been quite small. Our financial
markets are flexible and resilient, and they can absorb shocks surprisingly well. As a result,
most risks caused by new developments in financial markets should be manageable without
heavy-handed regulation. This meeting is a good example of what my middle course suggests
we should be doing: working hard to understand innovations and their possible implications.
Alertness and knowledge on the part of policymakers would go a long way toward ensuring
that our positive recent track record will carry on amid what I am sure will continue to be a
rapidly changing financial landscape.
Return to top
2005 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: November 28, 2005