View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At the Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University, Nashville,
Tennessee
February 14, 2001

E-Commerce: Lessons Learned to Date
I am pleased to be here with you today at Vanderbilt University. Your e-Lab and
e-commerce programs make this a particularly appropriate place to talk about the lessons
that can be drawn from developments in electronic commerce over the past several years.
Governor Daane, thank you for inviting me to speak.
The recent past has provided an excellent opportunity to observe how businesses and
individuals respond to significant technological changes. But we should also be mindful that
Internet-based commerce, in particular, is still young and unquestionably evolving. Hence, I
must emphasize that these are only preliminary observations.
Today I will touch on three main topics. First, I will explore a few early observations about
the economics of electronic commerce based on the experiences of the past few years.
Second, I will talk about payments, a key part of the country's economic infrastructure, and
whether the current payment instruments can effectively support future electronic
commerce. Finally, I will briefly review some activities that the Federal Reserve is pursuing
to remove barriers to innovations in electronic payments and commerce.
A Few Early Lessons of E-Commerce
The terms "electronic commerce" and "e-commerce" generally refer to commercial activity
involving the Internet, although they can also describe any commerce that relies primarily on
electronic exchange of information. For many entrepreneurs, e--commerce is an entirely
new market opportunity, while others see it as a versatile new channel offering opportunities
to enhance existing markets. Whatever the business case for an application of new
technology, generally successful applications have the potential to improve the lives of
ultimate consumers by reducing transaction costs. Reduced transaction costs, in turn, can
broaden the array of choices, expand the size of markets, and ultimately, through
competition, improve the quality of existing goods and services.
An initial observation is that, despite the novelty of the Internet applications we see today,
electronics have been used for commercial purposes for well over a century. In the
nineteenth and twentieth centuries, installation of telegraph wires and then telephone
networks created a revolution in business communications not unlike the current
e-commerce revolution, broadening markets by easing communications between distant
trading partners and reducing risks associated with slow physical communication and
transportation. In the extreme, telephone networks enabled two distant parties to
communicate interactively and in real time. Of course, there are limits to the uses of voice
communications. The advent of computers and new communications technology introduced

the opportunity to transmit vast quantities of data, as well as voice, over existing telephone
networks.
The commercial prospects of combining new and existing communications technology with
new information management technology, both software and hardware, spawned the
investment boom that underpins, in part, the most recent revolution in e-commerce. But we
must be careful to recognize that the rapid evolution of modern e-commerce does not repeal
the laws of economics. In fact, we see now that economies with significant investments in
information and communications technology remain subject to occasional capital goods
overhangs, which may influence macroeconomic conditions. Over the last few months, data
on orders and shipments of nondefense capital goods have provided hard evidence of a
slowdown in business spending on high-tech capital goods. Our economy is clearly
undergoing a stock adjustment to bring the supply of and demand for capital goods in some
sectors into better alignment. Importantly, measures of growth of output per hour in the
second half of 2000 were sufficiently strong to suggest that the growth rate of structural
productivity remains robust. This in turn suggests that the rate of return on capital should be
sufficiently attractive to foster new investment once this stock adjustment is complete.
There are two key questions. First, when will the stock adjustment in high tech capital run its
course, and the supply and demand for capital goods return to balance? Second, when
balance is restored, what pace of investment in high tech capital goods will ensue?
Unfortunately, neither question is answerable with certainty at this stage. With respect to the
duration of the stock adjustment, those who think that the process will be protracted point to
both the length of the current investment boom and the historical experience with lengthy
stock adjustments in capital goods to suggest that the period of retrenchment will be a long
one. Those who are optimistic that this phase of rebalancing will be relatively short highlight
two facts. The adjustment in capital goods ordering and production has been relatively rapid
in this cycle and modern high tech capital goods are relatively short-lived--being depreciated
in many cases in three years or less as opposed to the seven years or more that characterizes
many types of traditional capital equipment. Which of these sets of factors predominates will
determine, in part, the shape of the recovery from this period of slowing.
Similarly, we cannot know with certainty the pace of investment in capital goods going
forward. As I will discuss below, it is certain that the pace of future demand for capital
goods will depend in part on the ability of providers of capital--banks, creditors in fixed
income markets, and purchasers of equity--to recognize the risks inherent in high tech
capital investment plans and to price the risk appropriately.
Let me now offer a few observations on cost, demand, and the microeconomics of
e-commerce. The cost structure of electronic networks tends to be characterized by high
fixed costs and very low marginal operating costs. This also appears to be true of the cost
structure of a number of firms engaged in e-commerce. Initially, purchasing or developing
software to support a competitive commercial enterprise on the Internet can be costly. But
once software that meets a market demand is built, it can be paired with scalable hardware
to handle significant additional volume for very little extra cost.
It appears, however, that the basic cost structure of e-commerce has different applicability
for different types of businesses in this sector. For example, the high fixed cost, low marginal
cost model may fairly accurately characterize the cost structure of companies that provide
on-line information services, such as information vendors, search engines, and electronic
communications networks. Those that produce their own information content clearly pay

some production costs, but those costs appear to be small compared with the cost of building
and operating a network. Interestingly, many information providers do not originate any
content at all and rely instead on markets, commercial partners, or even subscribers to
provide the content. For different reasons, information-based e-commerce companies seek
high sales volumes. They all wish to take advantage of the economies of scale that are
inherent in their cost structure, seeking large scale to reduce their average production costs
as volumes grow. As with other businesses that have this cost profile, e-commerce
businesses in this category often respond to their cost structure by charging a flat fee per
user, such as a subscription fee, with the price structure often transitioning to some form of
discounted fee for heavy volume accounts. Obviously for those information-based
e-commerce businesses for which advertising is the major source of revenue, scale is
important to keep advertisers happy. Overall, even with rapidly declining marginal costs, if
pricing does not cover the marginal costs and revenues in the long run do not recoup fixed
costs, this model of e-commerce can prove financially disappointing.
On the other hand, the cost structure for those e-commerce firms that use electronic means
to distribute tangible goods, such as books, apparel, and toys, appears to mirror more
conventional business models. The network costs for these firms reflect the well-understood
high fixed cost and low marginal cost model of the electronic world. However, the
economics of fulfillment--that is, providing and servicing the goods--still depend on these
businesses' ability to achieve efficiencies and low unit costs for materials, storage,
distribution, and after-sales service.
The story of the demise of one prominent Internet-only retailer may be instructive in this
regard. News reports indicate that the company had to build and maintain a web site costing
about $40 million annually, the high fixed cost element of e-commerce, which it thought was
required to achieve the desired revenue in the national market it hoped to serve. Besides this
new economy cost, this retailer decided to build a proprietary distribution network, an old
economy cost that, according to public sources, raised its investment in property and
equipment to more than $100 million, a fourfold increase in one year. Analysts indicate that
this equaled around 100 percent of the firm's 1999 revenues. As a benchmark, for
land-based retailers a comparable number would be 20 percent of annual revenue and for
catalogue retailers, who often subcontract distribution, the comparable number would be 12
percent to 13 percent.
Finally, because of low barriers to entry to the Internet market and the low cost to customers
of switching from one seller to another, Internet-only firms appear to face high costs to
obtain and retain customers. Again, published reports indicate that the retailer increased its
budget by 30 percent in one year as new competitors moved into its market.
Clearly, appropriately scaling the cost model to the market potential is another key lesson in
the world of e-commerce.
On the demand side, the so-called network effect is extremely important for some
e-commerce businesses because the value of some services increases as the number of
customers using them increases. The most obvious example is an on-line auction site, in
which the more buyers and sellers using an auction site, the deeper the liquidity--that is, the
greater the number of opportunities to trade and the greater the likelihood that trades will
occur. For these firms, which include those that support the "auction" of equities as well as
collectibles, high volume is critical to their success, and volume expectations appear to
influence investments in these firms. I have already referred to economies of scale. Auctions

and chat rooms provide an example of how network effects and scale economies can be
mutually reinforcing, making high transaction volumes critical to both the supply and the
demand sides of the market. Here let me also note that, for those for whom advertising is a
key source of revenue, there is a virtuous cycle as a large customer base attracts more
advertisers, which in turn finances more and better content and attracts even more users.
The need for scale or volume appears to create an advantage for the first business to achieve
critical mass in any market in which there are strong network effects. Understanding this
dynamic and taking advantage of it appears to be another lesson from the early experience
with e-commerce.
The evolution of investment in e-commerce firms, particularly web-only firms, continues to
receive attention in the press. Needless to say, rational economic behavior suggests that
investors would require a high return to invest in unproven but potentially profitable
endeavors. After all, some innovations struggle but succeed, while others arrive too soon for
the technology, arrive too soon for the market, or are not commercially successful for a wide
variety of other reasons. The rapid reassessment of the business prospects of some
e-commerce firms during the course of last year is a reflection of this reality.
Of course, the equity securities of these firms were revalued to reflect these changing
assessments. Are stocks today overvalued, correctly valued, or undervalued? I certainly do
not know, and I am not aware of anyone who does. As a result, I believe that it would be
unwise--and indeed impossible--for the Federal Reserve to target specific levels of
valuations in equity markets. However, valuation methods that are appropriately sensitive to
the obvious business risks of e-commerce, as opposed to being driven by the assumption of
the most optimistic outcomes for every concept, are key. In the long run such approaches
should provide a healthy base for maintaining a reasonable and sustainable pattern of growth
and investment in the e-commerce segment. Costs of capital that reflect risks accurately are
critical to a well-functioning economy.
Therefore, with respect to observations and lessons, it appears that the basic rules of
economics, commerce, and finance continue to apply. Though some macroeconomic
conditions have changed importantly because of the technology investments that underpin
e-commerce, the laws of economics have not been repealed. At the commercial level, any
company considering a substantial investment needs to understand the business case and
underlying market cost, competition, and demand structures. Companies and their investors
still need to assess the potential risks and returns based on that commercial reality.
Payments and E-Commerce
Now I would like to turn to the topic of payment systems and discuss whether the existing
arrangements support electronic commerce. In many ways the rapid growth of some
elements of e-commerce is built on the solid base of preexisting payment systems and
protocols.
Even with the apparent ups and downs of specific electronic commerce providers, many
purchases are being initiated through the Internet. The Census Bureau estimates that roughly
$20 billion worth of retail transactions flowed over the Internet during the year ending
September 2000, excluding large-dollar business-to-business transactions at least partly
initiated through the Internet. Some private calculations reach twice that amount. These
purchases are being paid for predominantly with traditional payment instruments that
predate the World Wide Web. Given the growing importance and apparent potential of
e-commerce, it is important that the older protocols of the payment system evolve to support

this new element of our economy.
To explore recent payment developments, it may help to distinguish among the markets for
different types of payment transactions. Although the consumer-to-business (C2B), personto-person, and business-to-business (B2B) categories likely break down when pushed too
far, they can provide a convenient organizing framework for identifying payment
transactions with some common characteristics.
For some types of commerce, existing electronic payment instruments were easily adapted
to the Internet. Most notably, small- to medium-sized C2B purchases are frequently made
using credit cards. Because credit cards were already widely used for retail telephone
transactions, these "card-not-present" transactions were easily accepted as part of commerce
on the World Wide Web. Moreover, unlike many other payment instruments, credit cards
could already support low-value international commerce, one of the historical barriers being
challenged by the Internet. One card network estimates that 95 percent of retail purchases
over the Internet in 1999 were made using debit, credit, and other payment cards.
Some entrepreneurs are adapting other payment instruments for C2B electronic commerce.
For example, debit card networks are exploring ways to enhance security and inter-network
arrangements so that PIN-based debit transactions will be widely accepted as an alternative
to credit cards for Internet-based sales. Similarly, vendors have developed pre-paid cards for
which value can be purchased in advance and used to pay for on-line purchases by
individuals who do not have access to credit cards or who prefer not to use them. In
addition, some service providers have begun to offer "electronic check" or "e-check"
products in which customers enter the information shown on the bottom line of a check and
authorize the electronic debit of their checking accounts through a mechanism called the
automated clearinghouse, or ACH.
But existing and evolving payment instruments do not yet satisfy all of the needs of C2B
e-commerce transactions. For instance, many firms provide bill payment services, and many
are exploring ways to present bills electronically as well. Despite the growth of electronic
bill payment applications, many of the bills for which payment instructions are initiated
on-line are still paid by check. Similarly, there is not yet an easy way to pay for transactions
such as on-line stock purchases, which have become popular. Instead, these purchases are
generally charged against pre-funded brokerage accounts, although they could also be paid
for by wire transfers through the purchaser's bank or by the prompt mailing of checks.
Devising new ways to pay for securities trades is becoming increasingly important as the
securities industry tries to reduce the time needed to settle trades from trade-date plus-three
days to trade-date plus one day.
For person-to-person commerce over the Internet, typically conducted through auction and
similar web sites, there are very few electronic payment alternatives that can be easily
transferred from physical commerce. Over the past few years, however, several service
providers have created Internet-based person-to-person transfer mechanisms based on the
credit card clearing mechanism but requiring transfer of funds through an intermediary.
Other service providers enable individuals to accept credit card payments, a function
previously available only to businesses.
Finally, a number of service providers are also trying to address the market for electronic
B2B transactions. Thus far, some companies have adopted corporate purchasing cards,
issued by traditional card-issuing companies, for their low- and medium-value on-line

purchases. The demand for improved payment instruments for B2B transactions, however,
may be even greater than for the C2B and person-to-person markets. Improving speed,
reducing risk, and ensuring appropriate levels of privacy are important in all three markets.
Also, to attract users, B2B payment mechanisms may need to provide additional
features--for example, tools that reduce credit and timing risks in domestic and international
markets. Other desirable features might enable data to flow seamlessly through the internal
systems of the purchaser, the seller, and perhaps intermediaries--all at a low cost, of course.
Because the products or services, scale, and complexity of business-to-business transactions
vary widely, satisfying the needs of this diverse market may be more difficult than satisfying
those of the other markets. I have heard reports, however, that many banks and other
organizations are aggressively seeking ways to provide services for this market.
The Federal Reserve in the Payment System
Now, turning to the role of the Federal Reserve, recall that one reason that the Congress
established the Federal Reserve was to improve the nation's payment system; the Federal
Reserve Act of 1913 provides the foundation for the Federal Reserve to establish a national
check-clearing system. Today, the Reserve Banks distribute cash, clear checks, and provide
electronic payment services to banks. In addition, the Federal Reserve System has had a
long-standing role in helping to formulate public policies that improve the overall efficiency
of the nation's payment system and reduce risks.
Recently, evolving technology and growth in alternatives to cash and check payments have
raised questions about the Federal Reserve's role in the payment system. In 1996 and 1997,
a committee headed by Alice Rivlin, then the Federal Reserve Vice Chair, studied the
Federal Reserve's operational role in the payment system. Ultimately, the study concluded
that the Federal Reserve should continue to provide all its existing payment services with the
explicit goal of enhancing efficiency, effectiveness, and convenience, while ensuring access
for all banks. The study also recommended that the Federal Reserve work actively, closely,
and collaboratively with providers and users of the payment system, both to enhance the
efficiency of check and ACH services and to help develop strategies for moving to the next
generation of payment instruments.
To follow up on the recommendations of that study, the Federal Reserve created the
Payments System Development Committee, which I co-chair with Cathy Minehan, President
of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. The Payments System Development Committee has
an explicit mission. In addition to identifying strategies for enhancing the long-term
efficiency of the retail payment systems, it also identifies barriers to innovation and works to
address those barriers where possible. The committee is active in monitoring developments
in payment markets and has sponsored workshops and forums that encourage focused
discussions with the private sector. Our current activities include efforts to reduce legal and
regulatory barriers to payment innovation, examine future clearing and settlement systems to
support electronic commerce, assess our role in helping to set standards, and find ways to
use new technologies to collect checks more efficiently.
Conclusion
The technological developments that enable us to engage in electronic commerce today have
created tremendous opportunities to improve the ways in which we do business. Even as
some businesses fail, they are contributing to our store of knowledge about what will and
will not work in e-commerce. But beyond just the success or failure of specific businesses,
electronic commerce has challenged the thinking of entrepreneurs and of those who lead
traditional businesses. The developments in e-commerce have reminded us that change, even

rapid change, is part of the normal evolution that we expect from market economies. They
have also shown, however, that no matter what delivery mechanism is used, successful
businesses must still follow good business practices, pay attention to basic economic
principles, and sell products and services that buyers want.
I believe this to be true for business generally and certainly for payments. A market-oriented
approach to payment system innovation promises to provide long-lasting benefits to the
consumers and businesses that use the U.S. payment system. We need to approach payment
system innovations with an open mind and a willingness to learn. This is particularly true in
the world of electronic commerce, where payments are being adapted to new technologies,
products, and methods of doing business. These innovations are important in themselves.
But they are also important because successful innovations to support electronic commerce
may, over the long term, have a broad influence on the payment systems we use throughout
our economy.
I commend Vanderbilt University and its Owen Graduate School of Management for moving
so forcefully to train the next generation of leaders in the e-commerce world. Not only are
you serving your students; you are serving the global economy.
Thank you for your attention.

Return to top
2001 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility
To comment on this site, please fill out our feedback form.
Last update: February 14, 2001