View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by Vice Chairman Roger W. Ferguson, Jr.
At the New Economy Forum, Haas School of Business, University of California,
Berkeley, Portola Valley, CA
May 9, 2000

Conversation with Leaders of the "New Economy"
Thank you for inviting me here today to discuss with you the "new" economy and its
implications. As always, the views I will be expressing are my own and are not necessarily
shared by other members of the Board of Governors or the FOMC.
With my normal disclaimer out of the way, I'd like to turn to a brief review of the
extraordinary performance of the U.S. economy over the past five years. Since 1995, real
gross domestic product has grown, on average, more than 4-1/4 percent per year. This is
significantly above the pace in the previous five years, and you have to go back to the
decade of the 1960s to find even closely comparable periods of consistently robust
economic expansion. In this environment, the unemployment rate has fallen to 4 percent,
and the underlying rate of price inflation has slowed, on net, despite very high rates of
resource utilization. Even the most optimistic of forecasters could not have anticipated such
a favorable confluence of economic events.
Productivity Growth and Cost Reductions
So, what happened? As a policymaker, I'd like to think that well-executed monetary and
fiscal policies played some role in creating an economic environment that was conducive to
non-inflationary economic growth. Our economy has also benefited from past actions by the
government to deregulate industries. The removal of unnecessary government regulation
started more than twenty years ago, during the administration of President Ford, and
gathered momentum during the Carter years. It has altered the business landscape.
Deregulation allowed, indeed forced, businesses to focus more clearly on a marketplace that
has become more competitive, with fewer constraints and increased flexibility.
But the dominant force of late appears to have been a significant upshift in the rate of
productivity growth. After increasing 1.6 percent per year from 1990 to 1995, output per
hour in the nonfarm business sector--a conventional measure of productivity--has increased
at an annual pace of about 2.6 percent since 1995. Cyclical forces--such as the inability of
businesses to add to their payrolls as rapidly as they would have liked in response to the rise
in demand--have probably played some role in these efficiency gains. But I suspect that
longer-term, structural changes, reflecting the boom in capital spending and the revolution
in information technology, probably have been more important. I will return to the evidence
of this point shortly.
Why are the growth rate of productivity and the sources of that growth so important to
policymakers? Very simply, economic theory indicates that, over the long run, faster growth

of labor productivity allows faster growth of real wages--that is, wages adjusted for
inflation. Without faster growth in productivity, businesses faced with a nominal wage bill
that is increasing faster than productivity would be tempted to pass those increased labor
costs to consumers in the form of higher prices for goods and services in order to protect
profit margins. Adding the growth rate of labor productivity, or output per hour, to the
growth rate of the number of labor hours gives an approximation of the rate of increase in
the economy's ability to create goods and services. Since labor hours tend to be determined
in the long run by increases in the working-age population, growth in productivity is the
focal point. Why then are the sources of productivity growth important? If that growth in
productivity is due to a change that outlasts the business cycle, then economists and
policymakers can have confidence that the productive potential of the economy has
changed. Economists speak of that as "trend" productivity and the resulting growth rate as
the "trend" growth rate.
The structural changes that I mentioned above have had effects beyond increasing the rate of
productivity growth. They have also enhanced the ability of businesses to reduce their
operating expenses. In many industries, investments in information technologies have
helped firms to cut back on the volume of inventories that they hold as a precaution against
glitches in their supply chain or as a hedge against unexpected increases in aggregate
demand. In fact, we have seen that the ratio of inventory to sales and inventory to shipments
have both trended down since 1995. Product development costs have probably also been
reduced through the use of better computer hardware and software, and new
communications technologies have increased the speed with which firms can share
information--both internally and with their customers and suppliers. This intense focus on
cost reduction has been an important element in helping to head off the development of
inflationary pressures in this expansion. Moreover, given intense competition and the
resultant lack of pricing "leverage," ongoing programs to reduce costs have become a key
part of corporate strategies to maintain or improve profit margins.
Technology Change and Productivity Growth
Bob Solow--the MIT economist who won the Nobel Prize in economics for his work on the
theory of economic growth--once quipped that you can see computers everywhere except in
the productivity statistics! That situation has recently begun to change, and we now have
strong evidence that the productivity growth that our economy has experienced is in fact due
in part to newer technologies.
Research by two economists on the Board staff--Steve Oliner and Dan Sichel--sheds some
light on the sources of this faster productivity growth. About one-half of the 1 percentage
point increase in productivity growth over the 1995-1999 period can be attributed to socalled "capital deepening." As everyone here is well aware, providing your workers with
more equipment improves his or her efficiency. Likewise, at the aggregate level, the high
(and rising) levels of business investment raised the amount of capital per worker and
thereby boosted productivity. It is also interesting to note that most of the capital deepening
reflected greater spending by businesses on high-tech equipment: computers, software, and
communications equipment. Another 1/2 percentage point of the pickup in productivity
growth reflected technological innovations in the actual production of computer hardware
and semiconductors as well as better management--perhaps assisted by these high-tech
investments--of the nation's capital and labor resources. Oliner and Sichel estimate that, if
one consolidates all the influences of high-tech investments, they account for about twothirds of the acceleration in productivity since 1995. This research supports the view that

fundamental changes are under way in our economy.
But technological waves ebb and flow, and it is natural to ask whether we can count on such
rapid productivity growth in the future. On this score, I am cautiously optimistic. But, as an
economist, I need to see hard evidence of actual ongoing productivity gains or cost
reductions in the economic statistics to truly believe that the world is continuing to change
in a fundamental way. I am confident that the efficiency gains that have already been
achieved are permanent: The investments have been made, the technologies are in place and
are being disseminated, and production is proceeding apace. But I think that it is wise to get
support for the assertions that all of the new technologies and business practices now
coming to the fore will prove to be as revolutionary as some of their marketing materials
suggest. Clearly, there is great potential to improve efficiency using Internet-based ecommerce strategies such as electronic marketplaces and business-to-business supply chain
management. But no one really knows how big those productivity gains will be, how long
they will take to be realized, and who will be the ultimate beneficiaries. Have not other
technologies emerged over the past fifty years--such as the television, the jet engine, or even
air conditioning--that were equally revolutionary? Indeed the transatlantic cable and
telephone probably revolutionized communications as much as any other technology. The
Internet has attracted the most media and public attention as a symbol of the new economy.
It clearly improves communication, collapsing time and space, but are we overstating the
potential benefits of this one, admittedly stunning, innovation? Does the Internet have the
potential to continuously improve business processes, as some enthusiasts argue, and if it
does, what conditions are required to achieve that? I hope that, given the expertise of the
participants at this symposium, we can return to these and related questions in the discussion
period.
The Macroeconomic Implications of Faster Productivity Growth
A step-up in the growth rate of technological change certainly would have important
implications for economic activity and inflation. As I indicated above, the main reason
policymakers and economists are interested in the growth rate of productivity is that
understanding that rate gives a clear understanding of the economy's potential to supply
goods and services. Where would we look for corroborating evidence of this improved
growth rate in technological change? The most immediate effects would be on capital
investment. A more rapid pace of technological change raises the real rate of return on new
investments--perhaps significantly. Put another way, a more rapid pace of technological
change makes investments in capital goods embodying the new technology more profitable.
When businesses recognize the new technological possibilities, capital spending accelerates
to take advantage of the new profit opportunities. Businesses can better produce more output
with the same labor input. While supply-side effects are clear, a new higher level of
productivity growth would also affect the demand side of the economy. The employment
and income generated by business spending on capital goods boosts consumer spending and
sets off another round of investment spending. Typically referred to by economists as
"multiplier-accelerator" effects, such processes would continue as long as the real rate of
return on a new capital project exceeded the real cost for capital for that project. This is the
process through which an innovation on the supply side of the economy generates a
comparable increase in aggregate demand.
Theory also teaches that the increase in the rate of return on capital--even if generated by a
rise in the growth rate of technical change--ultimately requires an increase in real market
interest rates. Market interest rates must rise in order to maintain equilibrium between the

demand for investment funds, which increases, and the supply of investment funds. And,
indeed, we have seen that market interest rates, particularly for corporate issuers, have risen
steadily for the last year or so.
This somewhat abstract description of the effects of a step-up in the growth rate of technical
change bears a striking resemblance to the developments in labor markets, prices of goods
and services, capital investments, and fixed-income markets of recent years. But there's still
an element missing. How does the performance of the stock market in recent years fit into
this picture? A higher rate of technical change that raises the productivity and hence the
profitability of capital should elevate the valuation of equities. But how much should stock
values rise under those circumstances? Are stocks today overvalued, correctly valued, or
undervalued? I certainly do not know, and I am not aware of anyone who does. As a result, I
believe that it would be unwise--and indeed impossible--for the Federal Reserve to target
specific levels of valuations in equity markets.
However, equity markets obviously do have spillover effects on the real economy and, thus,
need to be considered in assessing the aggregate balance of supply and demand. Given the
efficiency and forward-looking nature of financial markets, even future technical
innovations will have an immediate effect on equity valuations. Equity valuations in turn
can influence consumer behavior. As you know, economists often speak of the "wealth
effect," and econometric modeling indicates that consumers tend to raise the level of their
spending between 2 and 5 cents for every incremental dollar of wealth over a period of two
to three years. As a consequence, equity valuations can have a noticeable effect on
consumption and on macroeconomic performance. Additionally, equity markets are a source
of investment capital, and valuations in the stock market are one determinant of the cost of
capital for businesses. To put a rough number on these influences, simulations by the Board
staff using our econometric model of the economy suggest that wealth generated in the
equity markets over the last four years added about 1 percentage point to the growth rate of
real GDP.
Some particularly enthusiastic observers of the "new" economy argue that inflationary
pressures are no longer a risk. I firmly believe that we should recognize that, even in a highproductivity economy, stresses and imbalances might emerge. In the present context, the
most obvious indication of an imbalance is the current account deficit, which is both large
and growing. This means that we are financing investment with savings from overseas. The
other indicator of an imbalance between demand and supply growth is the gradual decline in
the unemployment rate over the last few years. It may be that this imbalance has served only
to bring the unemployment rate to a new and lower sustainable rate, but it is also true that
the wedge between demand and supply growth cannot continue indefinitely because, once
pressures on limited resources rise sufficiently, inflation will start to pick up.
Monetary Policy and the "New" Economy
As I have said many times before, uncertainty about productivity trends is a major challenge
in the design and implementation of monetary policy. As you can imagine, it is very difficult
to infer the true structure of the economy through the interpretation of the twists and turns of
incoming economic data. How do we know, for example, if unexpected developments are
just temporary movements away from stable longer-run relationships or are manifestations
of changes in the underlying economic structure? In many cases, this judgment is difficult to
make with much confidence even considerably after the fact. In the meantime, we must bear
in mind that the statistical relationships we work with, embodied in our econometric models,

are only loose approximations of the underlying reality. The considerable uncertainty
regarding statistical constructs such as the "natural" rate of unemployment or the
"sustainable" rate of growth of the economy suggest, in my judgment, the need to downplay
forecasts of inflation based solely on those variables. Some fog always obstructs our vision,
but when the structure of the economy is changing, the fog is considerably denser than at
other times.
What should be done when such uncertainties seem particularly acute? When we suspect
that our understanding of the macroeconomic environment has deteriorated, as evidenced by
strings of surprises difficult to reconcile with our earlier beliefs, I think that the appropriate
response is to rely less upon the future predicted by the increasingly unreliable old models
and more upon inferences from the more recent past. That means we should weight
incoming data more heavily than data from decades past in trying to make judgments about
the new economy and, of course, act appropriately when trends become clear.
But, even for those of us who take this more pragmatic approach, there are many serious
challenges. Economic data are notoriously volatile, are easily affected by a variety of special
factors, and are subject to revision as more reliable or more complete sources become
available. For example, there are several estimates of the growth in real GDP in any
particular quarter. The so-called "advance" estimate contains numerous assumptions about
missing source data. One month later, the "preliminary" estimate is produced with a more
complete information set. And, one month after that, the "final" estimate is generated. But
that's not the end of the story. Once a year the GDP data are revised again to incorporate the
results of source data that are only available annually. Thus, over this revision window, the
picture painted by the GDP data can change significantly, and policymakers obviously need
to be aware of this to avoid attaching too much significance to any one piece of data.
Moreover, it is at uncertain times such as these that the wisdom underlying the institutional
structure of the FOMC becomes most apparent. A committee with broad representation can
bring a variety of perspectives and analyses to bear on difficult economic problems. In
addition, the anecdotal reports that the presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks bring from
their Districts are especially valuable in the decisionmaking process because they afford a
"real-time" sense of what is going on in the economy. Such diversity of information sources
becomes particularly useful when our earlier assessment of the economy's structure has been
drawn into question by surprises, even pleasant ones.
Even in a period of some uncertainty, monetary policy authorities have an important
responsibility to remain vigilant with regard to inflationary pressures. Since in the long run
there is no tradeoff between unemployment and inflation, we know that keeping inflation
low and stable and maintaining an obvious stance of vigilance vis a vis inflation, so that
inflation expectations are also relatively low, is the main value that a central bank can add to
this equation.
Besides the issue of how monetary policy should respond to a productivity shock, questions
have recently resurfaced about the effectiveness of any actions that the Federal Reserve
might take. Some analysts note that economic growth has not slowed even though the
FOMC has raised the federal funds rate five times over the past year, and they draw the
conclusion that the central bank has lost its effectiveness. I do not share that view. There
have always been lags between the initiation of a monetary policy action and its effect on
the economy. And, as Milton Friedman pointed out many years ago, these lags are "long and

variable."
Unanswered Questions
As I promised, I will now pose several questions about the new economy to this gathering. I
can assure you that this will not be a multiple-choice test, and it will ultimately be up to your
shareholders and the American people to grade all of our answers.
First, what has been so special about the technological developments since 1995? How
quickly have the innovations to computing and communications technology diffused
throughout the economy? How much diffusion of the current technologies remains to be
accomplished?
Second, what makes the Internet unique in its potential to improve productivity, and is the
potential greater than that of other recent technological developments? What are the
potential benefits--and costs--of the adoption of the commercial and communication
strategies required to fully use the Internet? Does the Internet have the potential to
continuously improve business processes, as some enthusiasts argue, and if it does, what
conditions are required to achieve that?
Third, how have you used information technology or the Internet to improve productivity or
reduce costs in your own businesses? How far along are you in this process? How important
is spending on research and development to the long-run competitive position of your own
business and the pace of innovation in your industry? Are new technologies emerging from
R&D that have the realistic potential to increase productivity growth in the economy even
further?
Fourth, do the methods used to value the so-called dot-coms differ from those used to value
"old economy" companies, and should they differ? How should gross margins be considered
in valuing dot-coms? Do tools used to value direct-mail companies apply to dot-coms?
Given recent volatility in equity prices and the IPO market, are venture capital funds less
forthcoming? Will new ventures still emerge at the same pace in a period of equity market
volatility?
Concluding Remarks
In conclusion, let me remind you that, while these are challenging times for monetary
policymakers and financial market participants, the U.S. economy is enjoying a period of
unprecedented prosperity. Technological developments associated with the information
revolution are truly transforming the way we work and play. Our job at the Federal Reserve
is to do our utmost to produce a stable economic environment without inflation so that these
trends can continue. I look forward to discussing these issues with you.
Return to top
2000 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: May 9, 2000, 4:00 PM