View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At the ICBI Risk Management 2003 Conference, Geneva, Switzerland
December 2, 2003

Concerns and Considerations for the Practical Implementation of the New
Basel Accord
I am pleased to participate in this conference on such an important subject as the proposed
new Basel Accord. Your topical agenda and the expertise of your speakers are impressive,
and I am sure that the discussions will provide new insights.
I have been asked to talk today about some of the issues associated with the practical
implementation of Basel II. Before I start, let me reiterate that I remain optimistic that a new
accord will emerge from the Basel Committee in a timely fashion, so that national review
procedures can go forward. Although I will discuss concerns and considerations, these will
not, in my judgment, threaten the basic momentum of the process.
Basel I
There is no better place to begin a discussion of some of the practical concerns and
considerations of the new accord than at the beginning--with Basel I. Many have forgotten
that the first accord had its origins in complaints that the globalization of banking had
distorted competitive balance. Banks domiciled in jurisdictions whose supervisors required a
more prudent level of capital perceived that they were disadvantaged, certainly in their
home markets, by banks whose home supervisors were less aggressive in their minimum
capital standards. Basel I was intended to level the playing field for banks that operated
across national boundaries by establishing consistent standards on how minimum regulatory
capital was to be determined in individual countries and what was to constitute capital.
We should not lose sight of the continuing imperative, both economic and political, to ensure
that a revised accord is perceived by all to maintain a level playing field for banks operating
not only across national boundaries but also domestically. I will return to this issue later.
Basel I--on which the world's regulatory capital regime has been based for more than ten
years--was a genuine step forward for most countries' capital rules and a watershed for
international cooperation among the world's supervisors. But it is certainly clear to those of
you at this meeting that globalization, technology, and innovation have accelerated so
dramatically that Basel I cannot provide the industrial world's largest and most-complex
banking organizations with a regulatory capital requirement that reflects their underlying risk
exposures. Basel I, with its modest risk sensitivity, treats most loans as if they come from
one quality category. It ignores techniques that the largest banks have adopted to mitigate
risk. It erroneously treats some transactions that only appear to reduce risk as if they in fact
do. Its overly simple risk weights induce large banks to game the rules by shifting to the
market those exposures that the market judges require less capital than the regulations do

and by retaining exposures with a regulatory capital charge that is lower than the market
perceives is necessary. Such capital arbitrage has greatly reduced the usefulness of
regulatory capital ratios at the largest banks and provides little useful information to the
public or the supervisor. For these institutions, the regulatory rules must be changed. This is
the practical reality that bank supervisors face.
Change and Complexity, Flexibility and Comparability
This audience is well aware of the reality that I have just described. But a second practical
problem is that no one likes change, at least change imposed on them. Change can be
expensive and, worse, requires new constructs that have the potential for unintended
implications. For this reason, more than any other, the development of Basel II has taken a
long time. Not only are the issues complicated, but also the banks and their supervisors have
engaged in a continuing conversation about this complexity and its implications. Both parties
have shared a common goal of trying to develop a cost-efficient and workable system. On
occasion they have differed on the tradeoffs between cost and complexity and between
comparability and flexibility.
Another practical problem is that the world's supervisors are trying to do more than develop
a better risk-based capital standard. They are also trying to harness modern
risk-measurement and risk-management techniques to the regulatory system, and they are
trying to construct a framework that can evolve as the science and the art of risk
measurement and management evolve. I have previously called this evolutionary potential of
Basel II its "evergreen" element, and I believe it is one of the many attractive features of the
proposal.
Modern asset-pricing theory may have begun in academia, but its growth and application
have quickly taken root in money, capital, and banking markets in new ways of thinking
about risk, ways that essentially meant measuring risk in quantifiable ways. The largest
banks, operating in multiple product and geographic markets, simply could not operate
without applying the new evolving principles in measuring, shifting, and managing their
risks.
Several implications follow. Harnessing large banks' internal practices to the supervisory
process implies that supervisors could use such cutting-edge risk measures to evaluate bank
risk profiles and relate them to a truly risk-sensitive capital standard. It also suggests that a
bank's adoption of best-practice risk measurement and management could be used as a
supervisor-imposed prerequisite for the application of the new capital standard; setting such
a prerequisite would accelerate the development and adoption of these new techniques,
which counterparties are increasingly demanding in any event. Stating the point more
directly: Basel II is designed to harness the best new techniques but also to ensure their
application by those banks that have been less aggressive in adopting them. That is, Basel II,
at least in its more advanced form, is as much a proposal for strengthening risk management
as it is a proposal for improving capital standards; these considerations are, as they should
be, inseparable. That inseparability, in turn, as I will discuss later, is an important factor
leading to the bifurcated application of Basel II proposed in the United States.
The use of the more advanced techniques does not go far enough for those sophisticated
organizations that want to use their own models to estimate their own risk functions,
particularly their estimates of portfolio correlation effects. Some are also concerned that the
hard-wired risk functions and correlation parameters will prohibit better practices when they
are available.

In my view, a full models regime could not, over the planning period for Basel II, produce
capital charges that would be sufficiently comparable for a regulatory capital standard.
Specifically, determinations of portfolio correlation effects tend to be as much art as science;
and their subjectivity makes them difficult, if not impossible, to validate credibly. To ensure
broad comparability of regulatory capital ratios across banks, therefore, the risk functions
embedded in the internal risk-based (IRB) framework employ correlation parameters that
are specified by the Basel Committee. In effect, we have sacrificed some flexibility and
potential risk sensitivity for greater comparability. We have faced similar tradeoffs
repeatedly during the development of the Basel II proposals, and in many ways one of the
Basel Committee's greatest challenges has been reaching consensus on the right balance
between flexibility and comparability.
In addition, there is evidence that credit risk models at many large, complex banking
organizations have not attained the sophistication and robustness that would be consistent
with their use for regulatory capital. Although the state of the art is progressing rapidly,
many banks still must resolve some fundamental questions and finish compiling sufficient
data before they can adopt their own full credit models that produce reliable and accurate
results.
Ultimately, Basel II proposes a capital standard that implies the need for reasonable
comparability across banks and across boundaries to ensure the competitive balance to
which I referred earlier. Nonetheless, looking beyond the current proposals, I believe that
over time the regulatory capital functions we have hard-wired into Basel II, along with their
embedded correlation assumptions, will give way to individual bank-developed models that
are verifiable by supervisors. That development will probably be a central part of the
evergreen process. But the time for individual bank models is not now, and I see no reason to
hold up improving the regulatory capital regime until the state of the art permits that
innovation. Until then, I think we have developed a workable balance between flexibility
and comparability. As the old saying goes, the perfect should not be the enemy of the good.
Level Playing Fields: Treating Comparable Banks Comparably
Basel II, as I noted, tries to develop a standard so that banks' risk exposures can be treated
comparably. Such a standard is central to the required level playing field. But comparability
requires not that all banks be treated the same but rather that comparable banks be treated
comparably, raising practical issues of definition, of unintended consequences in competitive
markets, and of unavoidable differences in national regimes.
General Issues. As you know, Basel II proposes three options from which banks in national
jurisdictions may choose--the standardized, the foundation, and the advanced internal
risk-based (A-IRB) approaches. The increasing risk sensitivity of the three options has the
potential for the application of different capital charges across banks for the same exposures
and implies that banks with a more or less average mix of corporate and retail exposures
may have reductions in their overall minimum regulatory capital requirements as they move
across the three options. Any differences in regulatory capital charges have the potential to
distort both national competitive positions, an issue for domestic authorities, and
international competition, an issue for both national authorities and the Basel Committee.
In considering all of these issues, one must, of course, make a distinction among minimum
regulatory capital based on regulatory rules; economic capital based on the bank's own
assessment of risk and capital needs; and actual capital held, which includes buffers above

both the other capital measures for reasons varying from reduced cost of funding to
counterparty demands and to desired contingency flexibility. Minimum regulatory capital is
the lowest of the three capital "requirements," and thus the degree to which it may or may
not affect competition across banks is an important conceptual and practical issue involving,
at bottom, the way the price of credit gets determined.
When all is said and done, the nations participating in the Basel Committee are now
developing a proposal to establish a revised capital standard for banking organizations that
compete across national boundaries. Basel I was negotiated on the same basis. After Basel I,
all the participating nations nevertheless chose to apply the new standard to all the banking
organizations under their jurisdiction. The Europeans and the Japanese apparently have
made the same decision for the proposed Basel II. In contrast to Basel I, however, all
banking organizations will be subject to Basel II, but each organization will choose among
the three variants.
Application in the United States. The U.S. authorities have made a somewhat different
decision. Consistent with the letter and the spirit of the Basel II proposal, the latest U.S.
proposal states that all U.S. banking organizations with meaningful cross-border
exposures--at least $10 billion--will be required to adopt Basel II. In addition, any banking
organization with consolidated assets of at least $250 billion will similarly be required to
adopt Basel II. If these criteria were applied today, about ten or so U.S. entities would meet
one or both of these criteria and hence would be among the "core" group of U.S. banking
organizations required to adopt Basel II. To be sure, the actual number of mandatory U.S.
banks may change before actual implementation--and among them could be U.S. subsidiaries
of foreign banking organizations that meet the core bank standards. In addition, we initially
assumed that about ten other large entities might choose to opt in to Basel II; we now
believe that number may well be an underestimate, but we are still in the process of
surveying our larger banks to determine their plans.
Even the twenty banks counted currently as mandatory and opt-in would account, we
estimate, for more than 99 percent of the foreign exposure of U.S. chartered banks and more
than two-thirds of the domestic assets of these entities.
Any non-mandatory bank in the United States that can estimate the internal risk parameters
for its credit exposures--that is, measure and manage its risk exposure to the satisfaction of
the supervisor--may opt in to Basel II in the United States. But if a bank chooses not to meet
this test or not to adopt Basel II, it will remain under the current, unchanged, capital regime.
Banks that are required or that choose to adopt the Basel II rules in the United States will
have only one option: the A-IRB approach for credit risk and the advanced measurement
approach (AMA) for operational risk. Neither the standardized and foundation approaches
for credit risk nor the basic indicator and standardized approaches for operational risk will
be available in the United States.
The authorities in the United States proposed the bifurcated application of Basel II (with one
group under Basel II and most banks remaining under the current capital requirements) and
rejected the trifurcated approach (with banks choosing for themselves among the three Basel
II variants for credit risk, as well as three variants for operational risk), which looks to be
preferred in other countries, for three basic reasons. First, Basel II, as I noted, requires that
those adopting it apply it to their internationally active banks. The data to which I referred
are evidence that the U.S. framework for applying Basel II would meet that test. Second, as I

also noted earlier, Basel II capital requirements are intended not only to be more sensitive to
risk but also to link that risk-sensitivity to a significant increase in the standards for risk
measurement and management at larger banks. Only the A-IRB and the AMA approaches
fully impose that prerequisite on the large entities. The U.S. authorities believe that the
largest U.S. banking organizations should adopt best-practice risk measurement and
management for reasons of safety and soundness. Third, Basel II is not without cost. Most of
the thousands of U.S. banks that are neither in the core set nor in the likely opt-in set have
operations that, in the U.S. authorities' view, would not require the dramatic changes in
credit risk measurement and management associated with either the A-IRB or the
foundation approach. Additionally, the increased risk sensitivity of the standardized version
seemed modest to us relative to the additional costs of system changes. Regarding
operational risk, the arguments are even stronger that the AMA would impose undue burden
on smaller banks. In short, Basel II does not seem to have a favorable cost-benefit ratio for
most American banks.
The decision that most banks would remain under the current regime in the United States
was also conditioned on some institutional facts that were perhaps not well known
elsewhere. Minimum Basel I requirements are not the only capital regulations in the United
States. They are supplemented by benefits established by statute for banks with higher tier 1
and tier 2 capital ratios and by legislatively imposed minimum tier 1 leverage ratios. In
addition, statutory prompt corrective action has induced banks to carry buffer capital to
avoid losing regulatory benefits that come with holding capital above regulatory minimums.
Moreover, the market demands that our thousands of smaller banks hold substantial equity
capital, an amount significantly above the minimum standards. Nearly 95 percent of U.S.
small and medium-sized banks have capital ratios in excess of 10 percent and most likely
would not be required to hold more under Basel II. U.S. supervision of these banks already
includes substantial Pillar 2 elements, and of course, these banks operate almost totally
within the United States.
The arguments that banks other than core banks, and especially the small and medium-sized
banks, ought to be free to choose between Basel II and their current regulatory requirements
seemed overwhelmingly convincing to us. That is, banks should be free to choose to bear the
costs of implementation for the benefits of greater capital risk-sensitivity. Neither for
international agreement nor for domestic supervisory reasons did imposing Basel II on all
U.S. banks seem reasonable. But for international agreements and for domestic supervisory
reasons it seems only reasonable for us to require nothing less than A-IRB and AMA for
those banks that adopt Basel II.
Unintended Consequences and Competitive Distortions. Having made our bifurcated
proposal in the United States, public comments and congressional oversight have made clear
the purely domestic concern that banks remaining under the current regime, even though
they avoid the costs of adoption, may be disadvantaged relative to Basel II banks.
Specifically, the argument goes, Basel II will give the largest banks, if not a lower overall
capital requirement, then lower capital charges on certain credits with which banks not
adopting Basel II will have to compete. Focus has been placed on residential mortgages,
small business loans, and credit cards. Concern has also been voiced that Basel II banks will
use any newly created excess regulatory capital to acquire smaller banks, whose capital can
be used more efficiently by the larger Basel II banks. In short, creating international
competitive balance under Basel II carries the potential that domestic competitive balance
will become distorted.

At bottom, these concerns raise empirical questions about how credit is priced, about the
locus of competition, about the determinants of actual capital held, and about other matters.
Questions have been raised in the comment and oversight process and these questions will
have to be addressed. We are still reviewing the evidence presented to us, and Federal
Reserve staff members are conducting empirical research on the issues that will be made
public in the months ahead. We will need to review the available options for addressing any
of these concerns that are supported by the evidence. These options include changes in U.S.
Basel II rules, where national discretion is allowed; modifications to the proposed bifurcated
application; and changes in the current capital regime in the United States. We will look
seriously at each and all of these steps and will not be precluded from proposing any
measure that we believe is necessary to ensure a level playing field in our domestic banking
market. But first, as I noted, we must examine the evidence, just as other nations are
undoubtedly reviewing the unintended consequences of a trifurcated application in their own
markets.
Even though the objective is a level playing field internationally, the practical problem that
differing supervisory regimes and procedures may distort international competitive positions
remains. Frankly, the U.S. authorities hear arguments that some foreign supervisors have
neither the resources nor the experience to apply the rules as rigorously as they anticipate
will be the case in the United States. And foreign authorities have heard complaints from
their banks about the competitive implications that will be created by U.S. insistence on
A-IRB and AMA treatment for their large U.S. subsidiaries that meet the cross-border or
scale criteria to be core banks.
Real and perceived differential treatment existed under Basel I, and it will remain under
Basel II. However, the Accord Implementation Group (AIG) in Basel, made up of line
supervisors from member countries, has already had some success in trying to ensure
similar--or at least consistent--treatments across national boundaries under the new proposal.
Tensions in applications by different national authorities are a fact of life that we have to
address when we can. The test is whether we will be better off and whether competition will
be fairer under Basel II even though it is not perfect.
Level Playing Fields: Home and Host Issues
As I just said, treating comparable banks comparably within a national jurisdiction may have
unintended consequences for foreign banks. U.S. subsidiary banks owned by foreign parent
organizations will be subject to the same criteria as those for mandatory A-IRB banks in the
United States. Others may feel it desirable to opt in to such versions for their U.S. operations.
Such national treatment in the host country--treating comparable banks comparably--is
reasonable, but it may create genuine operational complexities if these banks plan to use one
of the other Basel II options in their home or in third countries.
For their part, the U.S. authorities have clearly stated that they will be flexible during a
transition period so that the relevant foreign banks can more easily meet the required
standards, but national treatment policies will apply. Discussions within the AIG on this
issue--as well as bilateral discussions with affected banks and their supervisors--have been
productive, and I think the associated problems will be addressed.
However, one issue appears to be particularly difficult in more than one jurisdiction: the
allocation of capital for operational risk among the legal entities within and across
jurisdictions. Problems do not come more practical than this. Operational risk is generally

measured on a consolidated basis, often by business line. That diversification benefits exist
on a consolidated basis suggests that operational risk estimated from the bottom up--by, say,
legal entity--would not only be more difficult but might well add up to more than the total
from the top down. The problem is only made more complicated by the understandable
focus of supervisors in each jurisdiction on ensuring that the entities under their supervision
are sufficiently capitalized to absorb risk. We have come a long way in global banking, with
deference to home consolidated supervisors, but the legal entity supervisor still needs the
assurance that capital is protecting risk in the individual unit.
Basel II is not going to succeed or fail on this practical problem or on similar problems--and
this will certainly not be the last. Through the AIG a compromise will be developed on the
issue of operational risk capital to ensure that capital is sufficient and is allocated in a
reasonable way. Other issues, including home-host tensions, will be resolved in similar ways
as the member countries hear comments, conduct analysis, and then seek out a viable
compromise solution.
The Process
The practical give and take of discussions is exactly how the first and now the second capital
accord have been and will be developed. We are at a critical stage of that process with
changes in significant provisions being studied and modified. Examples are the shift in
standard to unexpected loss only and the review of securitization, credit card, and credit risk
mitigation, all of which are now being actively studied.
It may seem strange that this far into the process--approaching year six--that such changes
are being made. These changes, however, show how seriously the Basel Committee and its
participating national authorities regard the public comment process and benefit from the
analysis of bankers and other interested parties. When analysis and evidence were put
forward, the committee responded.
The United States is considerably through its review of public comments on its own
advanced notice of proposed rulemaking (ANPR), and other countries are going through
their own process of translating a consensus proposal into rules. The processes in the United
States and in other nations may well bring up further proposals for change, provided that
supportable arguments are forthcoming.
In the United States, after this next round of committee discussions, additional procedural
steps still are required, with opportunity for comment at each stage, before a final rule is in
place. To be clear, the need for more procedural steps in the United States should not be
taken as an indication of a lack of commitment to the Basel process. Rather, it is a sign of
our attempt to develop these proposals on as transparent a basis as possible and to hear a
wide range of comments. The Congress of the United States has also held hearings on the
development of the new accord. The interest and oversight by our Congress in these
discussions is appropriate and welcome, particularly for an undertaking as extensive as Basel
II. The U.S. regulators appreciate the fact that we are able to operate as independent
agencies but also realize that we have an obligation to keep the elected representatives
informed of our progress in this major effort. Of course, it is expected that other countries
and the European Union will be following their own procedures as well.
Overall, I have been impressed by the efficacy of the comment process and believe it offers
an open forum for all parties to voice their opinions. Debate and discussion on such an
important undertaking are essential, and they provide an opportunity for enhancements to

the final product. The current proposal is better because the comments have elicited good
ideas that have been seriously considered.
At the same time, we do need to ensure that momentum is maintained. In October, the
committee members committed to work promptly to resolve outstanding issues by mid-2004.
In January, the Basel Committee will meet to address further analysis of outstanding issues
and review the timetable for completing and implementing the committee's work on the
accord. Using the agreement reached in the committee as a template, U.S. supervisors then
plan to conduct another Quantitative Impact Study (QIS) to gauge more clearly the effect of
the Basel proposals. We believe that we must carefully test the new proposal to determine its
effects on individual institutions and to ascertain the need to fine-tune the proposal further, a
process that could include recalibrating some of the risk-weight functions. Our sense is that
other countries will be doing the same. Because timing is a function of the degree of changes
required by the QIS, the U.S. agencies will then conduct a full notice of proposed rulemaking
once again to seek and then evaluate public comments before adopting a final rule.
Conclusions
Basel I is no longer a viable supervisory tool for the large, complex banking organizations of
the industrial world and needs to be replaced as soon as feasible by a new capital accord.
The proposal being developed at Basel builds on best-practice risk- measurement and
risk-management techniques and, at least in its advanced versions, is as much about ensuring
that banks use such techniques as it is about a more risk-sensitive capital approach. Indeed,
these considerations are two sides of the same coin.
Any complex change will induce opposition and concern, in part because of fear of change
and comfort with the known rules, in part because of preference for other alternatives by
those affected, and in part because of anxiety that it may upset current competitive
positions. But Basel II builds upon modern techniques and is entirely consistent with the
directions that both large banks and their counterparties are now moving. And it can use
future advances to evolve into an even more flexible and sophisticated supervisory tool.
Basel I and the proposed Basel II are designed to provide a level competitive playing field
for banking organizations meeting in international competition. And though proposed
application procedures--both the bifurcated approach in the United States and the trifurcated
approach in other countries--by and large maintain that objective, they may have the
unintended consequence of distorting domestic competitive equity. The empirical analysis on
whether they will, especially when banks maintain capital well in excess of regulatory
minimums, is yet to be completed, but the authorities are required to investigate these
concerns and adjust the proposal if the analysis requires it.
Tensions in cross-border applications exist and cannot be avoided in a world of national
regulatory authorities, especially where separate legal entities exist within national
jurisdictions that apply national treatment. The AIG has been successful so far in smoothing
differences that may develop in cross-border application, but these will inevitably involve
compromises on difficult issues.
Return to top
2003 Speeches
Home | News and events

Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: December 2, 2003