View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

13th Annual Santa Barabra County Economic Forecast Seminar
Red Lion Inn, Santa Barbara > CA
To be delivered on April 19, 1994, 10:00 AM PDT
The U.S. Economic Outlook: A Monetary Policymaker’s Perspective
I.

Good morning. Today my topic is the national outlook for the economy and inflation
and their implications for monetary policy.
A.

As you know, the Fed nudged up short-term interest rates on Monday.
1.

B.
II.

This is the third increase in the past three months.

Today, I’d like to explain why.

I’ll begin with a brief look backward.
A.

This expansion so far has been blunted by two major contractionary forces.
1.

2.

First, the federal government apparently has gotten serious about
trimming the deficit.
a.

And that has led to a contractionary fiscal policy with cutbacks
at all levels of government.

b.

Cutting the deficit will be good for long-run growth,
(1)

because the government would absorb less private
saving,

(2)

so more would be available for private capital formation,
which is a key to long-term growth.

Second, many of our major trading partners have—for various reasons—
been battling down inflationary pressures, and this has been associated
with slow growth or recession in those countries.
a.

In fact, last year, the other G-7 countries—Canada, France,
Germany, Italy, the UK, and Japan(1)

c:\parry\sbarb\4-18-94.1




saw output grow, on average, by less than 1 percent.

1

b.

In Japan, after years of strong expansion and phenomenal
growth in asset values, in 1989 the central bank put on the
brakes to head off inflation.
(1)

c.

3.

and the central bank has been insistent about keeping
inflation under control.

(2)

The result is that in 1993, the German economy fell into
a recession, and took much of the rest of Europe with it.

—though, in the long run, it lays the groundwork for healthier
economic growth.

1.

Though the drop was substantial, we moved cautiously because we
were concerned that lowering rates too fast could be inflationary.

2.

By the end of last year, short-term rates were about a third of what
they were in early 1989.
In fact, real short-term rates-that is, adjusted for inflation-were
around zero levels throughout the year.

3.

These low short-term rates stimulated rapid growth in the interestsensitive sectors of the economy-consumer durables, housing, and
business investment.

4.

The net result of these offsetting forces is that we’ve had eleven
consecutive quarters of growth.

Now, it’s important to emphasize that for the last two years, the rate of growth
has been faster than the economy can sustain in the long run.

c: \pariy\sbarb\4-18-94.1




(1)

In the face of these contractionary forces, the Fed lowered short-term interest
rates substantially.

a.

C.

In Germany, the high costs of reunification begun in 1990
created inflationary pressures,

This weakness abroad has limited foreign demand for our products, and
acted as another contractionary force in the short run—
a.

B.

The result was a collapse in money growth, which led to
a big dive in asset values and sent the economy into
recession.

2

1.

Current estimates of sustainable growth are about 2xh percent.

2.

But

3.

4.

a.

in 1992 growth averaged nearly 4 percent,

b.

in 1993 it averaged just above 3 percent,

c.

and in the fourth quarter, the economy really surged, achieving
a growth rate of 7 percent.

As a result, a good deal of the excess capacity that built up in the 1990
recession has evaporated:
a.

Both the unemployment rate and the rate of unused industrial
capacity have fallen rather sharply over the past year and a half

b.

—near to levels that most economists think represent "full"
utilization.

At the same time, inflation last year edged down only very slightly,
a.

III.

and in the case of core consumer inflation averaged about 3
percent.

For the rest of 1994, fiscal policy, the world economy, and monetary policy will
continue to play important roles.
A.

Fiscal policy, of course, will remain contractionary, as the deficit-trimming
continues.

B.

In terms of the world economy, the picture is starting to get a little brighter.

C.

1.

Exports to developing countries in Asia and Latin America have been
booming, and this situation certainly won’t be hurt by NAFTA.

2.

And we do expect the overall performance of our industrialized trading
partners to improve modestly this year.

Turning to monetary policy, as you know, the Fed raised short-term interest
rates slightly in February and March, and again yesterday.
1.

c:\parry\sbarb\4-18-94.1




This still leaves short-term real rates-that is, adjusted for inflation—low
enough to provide some stimulus to the economy.

3

2.

Long-term rates have risen, too—in fact, more than short-term rates
did.
a.

An important factor behind the big increase in long-term rates is
the continuing strength in the economy.
(1)

b.

D.

Another factor may be the recent declines in the dollar and
increases in foreign interest rates.

So, overall,
1.

the most likely outlook is that the economy won't keep up the very fast
pace we saw at the end of 1993.

2.

But it probably will continue to grow somewhat above its long-run
potential growth rate.

3.

I wouldn’t be surprised to see the growth rate come in at around 3
percent this year,
a.

IV.

This contributes to expectations that cyclical pressures on
credit demands and inflation will be strong in the future.

with some further declines in the unemployment rate and in
unused industrial capacity.

Now let me turn to the outlook for inflation.
A.

The Fed’s goal-like that of many other central banks-is to get inflation down-to near zero.

B.

And there are good reasons for this goal.
1.

c: \pany\sbarb\4-l 8-94.1




For one thing, low inflation often is associated with less uncertainty
about future inflation, and this promotes growth in the long run in a
couple of ways:
a.

it fosters lower long-term real interest rates,

b.

and it simplifies the planning and contracting by business that’s
so essential to capital formation.

4

C.

D.

2.

Low inflation also reduces the distortionary effects of most tax systems,
so people don’t waste time, energy, and money trying to hedge against
inflation.

3.

Finally, as we learned in the early 1980s, once inflation creeps up, it
can get out of control, and it can cost many jobs to stop it.

But the process of reducing inflation has its pitfalls.
1.

For one thing, it takes a long time for a policy action to produce
inflation results-probably from IV2 to 2 years.

2.

This kind of time lag means that if we wait for problems to show up in
the data before we act, then we’re likely to be too late.

3.

Instead, we have to anticipate problems, and pay attention to the
warning signs.

The current situation is a good example. We have not seen an increase
recently in the important inflation statistics, like the consumer price index.
1.

Still, I am concerned about inflation in the future, primarily because of
two warning signs. I’ve already mentioned them, but they’re worth
emphasizing.

2.

First, slack in labor and product markets has all but evaporated.
a.

3.

E.

Second, short-term real interest rates were near zero for over a year.
a.

The last time short-term real rates stayed at low levels for a
long period of time was in the 1970s, just before the run-up in
inflation in the late 70s and early 80s.

b.

Although the current situation isn’t nearly as dire as that one
was, we don’t want to risk even a small part of that kind of
problem again.

Because of these warning signs, I think the steps we’ve taken to raise rates are
appropriate.

c: \pany\sbarb\4-l 8-94.1




This means that we have little or no leeway to give extra
stimulus to the economy without sowing the seeds of inflation in
the future.

5

1.

F.

c:\pany\sbarb\4-18-94.1




Whether or not we’ll need to take additional action -will depend on an
ongoing assessment of current and prospective developments in the
economy.

We have made progress in achieving our long-term goal of providing the U.S.
economy with a low-inflation environment.
1.

But we still have a way to go.

2.

It’s important that we continue to strive for it, since it’s the main
contribution that monetary policy can make to maximizing standards of
living in our economy.

6