View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

San Francisco Rotary Club
New Kensington Hotel, 450 Post St.
To be delivered on April 12, 1994, 1:00 PM PDT

The U.S. Economic Outlook: A Monetary Policymaker’s Perspective
I.

Good afternoon. Today my topic is the national outlook for the economy and
inflation and their implications for monetary policy.
A.

As you know, the Fed nudged up short-term interest rates in February and
again in March.
1.

B.
II.

I’m wholeheartedly in favor of these moves, because they’ll reduce the
risk of a problem with inflation "down the road."

Today, I’d like to explain why.

But before I get into these issues, let me say a few words about the economy in
California. I’ll start with four positives.
A.

First, some indicators that dropped sharply earlier in the recession have
stabilized.
1.

B.

For example, state tax revenues have been relatively stable for the last
year or two.

Second, residential real estate activity has picked up nicely during the past six
months or so.
1.

It looks like the number of housing permits bottomed out last summer,
after a decline that was much larger and longer-lasting than most of us
had expected.

2.

And the number of existing homes sold has been trending up for
several months now.

C.

Third, in the past couple of months we’ve finally started to see some growth in
employment.

D.

Finally, the recent strengthening in the national economy bodes well for
improved sales by producers here.

c: \parry\sfrot\rotaiy. fin




1

E.

F.

III.

So, for a change, not all the California news is negative. But I do think we’ll
probably continue to "bump along the bottom" for a while before we see
sustained growth.
1.

For one thing, it’s too early to tell whether the employment growth
we’ve seen so far represents the beginning of an upward trend.

2.

And the recent increases in long-term interest rates could dampen the
housing recovery.

3.

Moreover, we still face a number of problems that will constrain our
economy for the next few years.
a.

Defense cutbacks are nowhere near complete, in terms of either
contract defense activity or the closure of military bases.

b.

And the state government’s "red ink" to date means that the
fiscal situation will be tight for a few years, even after the
state’s economy improves.

Finally, while many are arguing that the rebuilding effort after January’s
earthquake will pull Southern California out of the doldrums, I ’d expect much
of that stimulus to be offset by losses from the quake: lost business, reduced
spending capacity, and the like.

Now let me turn to the national outlook.
A.

I ’ll begin with a brief look backward—on the theory that "what’s past is
prologue."

B.

This expansion so far has been blunted by two major contractionary forces.
1.

First is fiscal policy.
a.

The federal government apparently has gotten serious about
trimming the deficit, and we’ve seen cutbacks at all levels of
government.

b.

Now, I should point out that although this is contractionary
now, it will be good for growth in the long run.
(1)

c:\pany\s frot\rotaiy. fin




Cutting the deficit will mean that the government will
absorb less private saving,

2

(2)

2.

The second contractionary force is the slow growth among many of our
major trading partners.
a.

C.

c:\pariy\sfrot\rotaiy.fin




Last year the other G-7 countries—Canada, France, Germany,
Italy, Japan, and the UK—saw output grow on average by only
about 1% percent.

In the face of these contractionary forces, the Fed lowered short-term interest
rates substantially.
1.

Though the drop was substantial, we moved cautiously because we
were concerned that moving too fast could be inflationary.

2.

By the end of last year, short-term rates were about a third of what
they were in early 1989.
a.

D.

and that would make more available for private capital
formation, which is a key to long-term growth.

In fact, real short-term rates—that is, adjusted for
inflation—were around zero levels throughout the year.

3.

These low short-term rates stimulated rapid growth in the interestsensitive sectors of the economy—consumer durables, housing, and
business investment.

4.

The net result of these offsetting forces is that we’ve had eleven
consecutive quarters of growth.

Now, it’s important to emphasize that for the last two years, the rate of growth
has been faster than the economy can sustain in the long run.
1.

Current estimates of sustainable growth are about 2 xh percent.

2.

But
a.

in 1992 growth averaged nearly 4 percent,

b.

in 1993 it averaged just above 3 percent,

c.

and in the fourth quarter, the economy really surged, achieving
a growth rate of 7 percent.

3

3.

4.

As a result, a good deal of the excess capacity that built up in the 1990
recession has evaporated:
a.

Both the unemployment rate and the rate of unused industrial
capacity have fallen rather sharply over the past year and a
half—

b.

—near to levels that most economists think represent "full"
utilization.

At the same time, inflation last year edged down only very slightly,
a.

IV.

and in the case of core consumer inflation averaged about 3
percent.

For the rest of 1994, fiscal policy, the world economy, and monetary policy will
continue to play important roles.
A.

Fiscal policy, of course, will remain contractionary, as the deficit-trimming
continues.

B.

In terms of the world economy, the picture is starting to get a little brighter.

C.

1.

Exports to developing countries in Asia and Latin America have been
booming, and this situation certainly won’t be hurt by NAFTA.

2.

And we do expect the overall performance of our industrialized trading
partners to improve modestly this year.

Turning to monetary policy, as you know, the Fed raised short-term interest
rates slightly in February and March.
1.

This has had some effect on long-term rates, but it’s probably not the
only reason why long-term rates rose so much in recent months—far
more than short-term rates did.
a.

One important factor may be the signs of continuing strength in
the economy.
(1)

c: \parry\sfrot\rotaiy. fin




These may contribute to expectations that cyclical
pressures on credit demands and inflation will be strong
in the future.

4

b.

D.

2.

Regardless of the cause of the rise in long-term rates, they’re still well
below the levels that prevailed in recent years.

3.

Furthermore, short-term real rates—that is, adjusted for
inflation—remain only slightly above zero.

4.

Therefore, interest rates should continue to provide stimulus to interestsensitive sectors.

So, putting all these factors together,
1.

the most likely outlook is that the economy won’t keep up the very fast
pace we saw at the end of 1993.

2.

But it probably will continue to grow somewhat above its long-run
potential growth rate.

3.

I wouldn’t be surprised to see the growth rate come in at around 3
percent this year,
a.

V.

Another factor may be the recent declines in the dollar and
increases in foreign interest rates.

with some further declines in the unemployment rate and in
unused industrial capacity.

Now let me turn to the outlook for inflation.
A.

The Fed’s goal—like that of many other central banks—is to get inflation
down—to near zero.

B.

And there are good reasons for this goal.
1.

c :\parry\sfrot\rotary. fin




For one thing, low inflation often is associated with less uncertainty
about future inflation, and this promotes growth in the long run in a
couple of ways:
a.

it fosters lower long-term real interest rates,

b.

and it simplifies the planning and contracting by business that’s
so essential to capital formation.

5

C.

D.

2.

Low inflation also reduces the distortionary effects of most tax systems,
so people don’t waste time, energy, and money trying to hedge against
inflation.

3.

Finally, as we learned in the early 1980s, once inflation creeps up, it
can get out of control, and it can cost many jobs to stop it.

But the process of reducing inflation has its pitfalls.
1.

For one thing, it takes a long time for a policy action to produce
inflation results—probably from IV2 to 2 years.

2.

This kind of time lag means that if we wait for problems to show up in
the data before we act, then we’re likely to be too late.

3.

Instead, we have to anticipate problems, and pay attention to the
warning signs.

The current situation is a good example. We have not seen an increase
recently in the important inflation statistics, like the consumer price index.
1.

Still, I am concerned about inflation in the future, primarily because of
two warning signs. I’ve already mentioned them, but they’re worth
emphasizing.

2.

First, slack in labor and product markets has all but evaporated.
a.

3.

E.

c:\pariy\sfrot\rotary.fin




This means that we have little or no leeway to give extra
stimulus to the economy without sowing the seeds of inflation in
the future.

Second, short-term real interest rates were near zero for over a year.
a.

The last time short-term real rates stayed at low levels for a
long period of time was in the 1970s, just before the run-up in
inflation in the late 70s and early 80s.

b.

Although the current situation isn’t nearly as dire as that one
was, we don’t want to risk even a small part of that kind of
problem again.

Because of these warning signs, I think the steps we’ve taken to nudge up rates
are appropriate.

6

F.

1.

Whether or not additional action is required is difficult to say at this
point.

2.

That will depend, in part, upon an ongoing assessment of current and
prospective developments in the economy.

We have made progress in achieving our long-term goal of providing the U.S.
economy with a low-inflation environment.
1.

But we still have a way to go.

2.

It’s important that we continue to strive for it, since it’s the main
contribution that monetary policy can make to maximizing standards of
living in our economy.

wc 1572

c: \parry\sfrot\rotaiy. fin




7