View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Los Angeles Bond Club
For delivery on October 5, 1994, 1:00 PM PDT

Shifting to Another Gear: Monetary Policy in 1994
I.

Good afternoon.
A.

This year monetary policy began shifting into another gear.
1.

After four years of gradually lowering short-term interest rates to
stimulate the economy’s recovery from recession, the Fed began raising
rates in February.
a.

All told, this year, there have been five rate increases,

b.

taking the federal funds rate from 3 percent to 4% percent.

B.

The Fed took these actions to contain the buildup of inflationary pressures,
which is key to fostering sustainable economic growth

C.

Our moves have been met with controversy in some quarters.
1.

For example, here in California, the economy is still pretty weak.
a.

2.

Others argue that we moved too soon, before there was much evidence
of increases in the inflation statistics.
a.

3.

II.

They ask, "Why not wait until we clearly see the problem
before trying to solve it?"

Finally, some think a little more inflation might not be so bad anyway.
a.

D.

This has led some critics to ask, "Why not help the weak parts
of the country before worrying about inflationary pressures?"

In other words, they ask, "If the benefit from a little more
inflation is higher employment, then what’s wrong it?"

Today, I’ll tackle these questions and explain the rationale for Fed policy this
year.

Okay, question number one. Shouldn’t the Fed help the weak areas of the economy
before worrying about inflationary pressures?

p:\parry\labond\labond. 105




1

A.

The answer is that the Fed’s emphasis has to be on the nation as a whole, and
not on any particular state or region. And there are two reasons for this.

B.

First, as you know, U.S. credit markets are very efficient, so they quickly
channel funds to the most productive uses.

C.

D.

1.

Therefore, the Fed has no way to direct stimulus to any particular part
of the country that needs help.

2.

That’s why the effects of monetary policy are often referred to as
"blunt."

Second, beyond this practical difficulty, there’s a real danger in focusing too
much on any one region of the economy that’s having a hard time.
1.

Often enough, some state or region is going through a recession of its
own while the national economy is humming along.

2.

If the Fed stimulated whenever any state had economic hard times,
we’d be stimulating most of the time.

3.

And the upshot of that would be a very pro-inflationary environment.

Does this focus on the well-being of the national economy mean that the Fed
ignores regional economic conditions?
1.

Not by a long shot.
a.

2.

We do this by analyzing regional data and by talking with people who
have insights on current economic developments in their areas of the
country.

3.

This information is the subject of a good portion of each FOMC
meeting,
a.

E.

and we use it to fit together a picture of how the whole
economy is doing.

Let me take a minute to talk about how the Twelfth Federal Reserve District
fits into this picture.

p:\parry\labond\labond. 105




The Fed places great importance on understanding regional
economies.

2

1.

The District covers a lot of territory—literally and figuratively—and
economic performance varies quite a lot.
a.

F.

We in California have suffered through an unusually prolonged period of
economic weakness.
1.

For example, the unemployment rate has been stuck at around 9
percent for most of 1993 and 1994—
a.

G.

—but the improvement has been slow, sporadic, and uneven across
both sectors and regions.
a.

For example, retail sales grew modestly in California during the
first quarter, but that growth was partially offset by a drop
during the second quarter.

b.

Furthermore, while business services are seeing healthy growth,
the aerospace industry continues to lose jobs.

c.

And regionally, while the Bay Area’s unemployment rate isn’t
much different from the national average, southern California’s
continues to hover around 9 percent.

The sheer size of California’s economy and the severity of its difficulties are a
significant drag on the nation’s economy.
1.

III.

—quite a bit higher than the national rate.

There are some signs that conditions started to improve by the middle of
19931.

H.

Right now, we have the nation’s three fastest growing
states—Utah, Nevada, and Idaho—as well as two of its weaker
performers—Hawaii and California.

When California is excluded from the calculations, the unemployment
rate in the remainder of the nation country is 5.8 percent instead of the
6.1 percent national figure.

Now to the second question about the Fed’s rate increases in 1994:
A.

Back in February, the overall economy was growing at a robust pace, without
clear signs of rising inflation. So, what was the problem?

p:\pariy\labond\labond. 105




3

B.

The problem was—and is—that monetary policy effects aren’t just
"blunt"—they also involve "delayed reactions":
1.

It takes a long time for a policy action to produce results on
inflation—probably from 1xh to 2 years.

2.

This kind of time lag means that it’s dangerous to wait until the
problems show up in the inflation data—
a.

3.
C.

—and while that doesn’t make a trend, these data are troubling.

Now we come to the third question. "What’s wrong with a little more inflation if the
benefit we get is more employment?"
A.

V.

Instead, we have to anticipate problems.

Let me say that we actually haw seen higher numbers for the CPI and PPI in
the last couple of months—
1.

IV.

—by then we’d be too late.

Well, what’s wrong is that a little more inflation may get us more
employment, but it would only be temporary.
1.

The Fed simply doesn’t have the power to push the economy beyond its
capacity to produce goods and services for very long.

2.

And if it tried, the inevitable result would be accelerating inflation and
financial instability—without either more production of goods and
services or a lower unemployment rate.

Let me make my point by taking a look at the recent past.
A.

B.

After the 1990 recession, the national economy needed some stimulus, and the
Fed delivered it by cutting short-term interest rates substantially.
1.

The federal funds rate fell from just under 10 percent in 1989 to 3
percent at the end of 1993.

2.

In fact, the real rate—that is, adjusted for inflation—was around zero
throughout 1993.

These low interest rates stimulated robust growth in the economy.

p:\parry\labond\labond. 105




4

1.

Over the past two and a half years, the growth rate for GDP has
averaged about 3'A percent.

2.

As a result, much of the unused capacity that had built up in the 1990
recession was employed.
a.

In the last two years, the unemployment rate has fallen by VA
percentage points.

b.

Furthermore, industrial capacity utilization rates have risen from
under 79 percent to over 84 percent.

C.

Now, the Fed likes to see strong growth just as much as anybody else does.

D.

But what gets the Fed concerned is a strain on capacity.
1.

And that’s what we started seeing early this year.
a.

It became apparent that the economy was moving rapidly into
the range of "full utilization" of labor and capital markets.

2.

Now, I don’t want to suggest that the Fed has some magic number
labeled "full utilization."

3.

On the contrary, precise estimates simply aren’t available.
a.

For example, just about everybody accepts the concept of a socalled "natural rate of unemployment"—
(1)

b.

But not everybody agrees on precisely what that rate is in the
U.S. economy today.

4.

Even though economists don’t agree on precisely what that rate is, most
do agree that the current figure is in the ballpark.

5.

I should point out that these estimates are not the Fed’s idea of what
the rate ought to be, or what any of us would like it to be.

p:\parry\labond\labond. 105




—that is, the rate that’s consistent with current
technology, labor market size and composition, and so
forth, in today’s economy.

5

VI.

To sum up, our actions this year have been warranted to guard against an increase in
future inflation. Maintaining low inflation is important in providing a firm foundation
for sustainable economic growth.
A.

Since there’s much less slack in labor and product markets, it would have been
a mistake to keep real short-term interest rates at the stimulative levels of late
1992 through 1993.
1.

The last time these rates stayed at low levels for a long period was in
the 1970s.

2.

It made the economy "go" for a while, but eventually it led to the run­
up in inflation in the late 70s and early 80s.

3.

As you know, putting on the "economic brakes" to fight that inflation
flare-up led to a major recession.

B.

Although the recent situation wasn’t as dire as that one was, we didn’t want to
risk even a small part of that kind of problem again.

C.

As a consequence, I think the steps we’ve taken this year to raise rates are
appropriate:
1.

They should help to foster stable, sustainable economic growth with
low inflation.

2.

Such forward-looking monetary policy helps avoid the "go-stop"
economic environment of the late 70s and early 80s, and it’s much
more likely to produce a lasting economic expansion.

wc 1458

p: \parry\Iabond\labond. 105




6