View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOLD FOR RELEAST AT 11:45 A.M. PST THURSDAY. DECEMBER 1, 1994
Intermountain Banking Seminar
Logan, Utah
For delivery on December 1, 1994(Luncheon),

Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

RECENT MONETARY POLICY: A FEW QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS
I.

Good afternoon.
A.

II.

I’d like to start with a quick look at the economy in the intermountain states,
and then I’ll turn to the national picture and monetary policy.

Utah, Nevada, and Idaho have been among the nation’s top performers since m i d 1993,
A.

B.

and the growth has been broad-based:
1.

Construction and real estate activity have been especially strong,
accompanied by substantia] increases in home values,

2.

and manufacturing activity has grown much more rapidly in this region
than it has nationally.

Two sectors deserve individual attention.
1.

One is technology-related industries
a.

2.

C.

The second is the visitor industry.
a.

Obviously, it's important in Nevada, with the proliferation of
huge new entertainment complexes,

b.

but it’s also become increasingly prominent in Idaho and Utah.

With generally strong economic conditions like these, it’s no surprise that the
banking sector is sharing in this strength.
1.

D.

Software has been a prominent growth industry in Utah, and
computer hardware production has grown very strongly in Idaho.

The region’s bank loan growth, return on assets, and asset quality all
are at or better than the national average.

So, overall, the economic news from the intermountain region has been very
good during the past couple of years.


p:\parry\logan\ll-28-94.1


1

A.

When the Fed began shifting gears back in February, the overall economy was
growing at a robust pace, without clear signs of rising inflation. So, what was
the problem9

B.

The problem was.and /iihat it takes a long time for a monetary policy action
to produce results on inflation.probably from 1*4 to 2 years.
1.

This kind of time lag means that it’s dangerous to wait until the
problems show up in the inflation data.
a.

2.

.by then we'd be too late.

Instead, we have to anticipate\>T<M<im$>.

And this year, we’ve had good reasons to think that inflation would be a problem in

Now let me turn to the national picture. 1 want to focus mainly on the course of
monetary policy over the past year.
A.

As you know, monetary policy shifted gears this year, and it made the
headlines.
1.

After four years of gradually lowering s h o r t-t e rm interest rates to
stimulate the econom y’s recovery from recession, the Fed began raising
rates in February.
a.

Altogether there have been six rate increases,

b.

taking the federal funds rate from 3 percent to 5*4 percent.

c.

The most recent action came in mid-November, when we raised
both the federal funds and discount rates by 3/4 of a
percentage point.

B.

The Fed took these actions to contain the buildup of inflationary pressures,
which is key to fostering sustainsb/ewonomfc growth.

C.

We've gotten some criticism over these moves. So today, I’m going to take a
look at three of the main points our critics make.




1.

First, some argue that we moved too soon, before there was much
evidence of increases in the inflation statistics.
a.

They ask, "Why not wait until we clearly see the problem before
trying to solve it?"

2.

3,
VI.

Although not everybody agrees on exactly what that rate is in today’s
economy,
a.

most economists tffragree that the current unemployment rate
is at or below the natural rate,

b.

which means that capacity has been used up.

If the past is any guide to the future, then inflation will be on the rise
unless things slow down a bit.

The second criticism startsmih the idea that the past isn't a good guide to the
future in this case.
A.

These critics question our moves because of the rise in global competition.
1.

B.

They ask, "Isn’t it the amount of worldwide c a p a c i t y - - n o t just U.S.
c a p a c i t y - - t h a t determines our inflation rate?"

The answer largely is "no", for a couple of reasons.
1.

First, a large proportion of what we consume in the U.S. isn’t affected
by foreign trade at all.
a.

For example, health care isn’t traded internationally, and it
amounts to about 14 percent of GDP.

b.

There are plenty of other examples, as well, like most services,
construction, and so on.

2.

Second, even when we consider goods that are traded internationally,
the effecl on U.S. prices is offset to a large extent by flexible exchange
rates,

3.

Let me explain this in a very simplified way.

4.

Suppose the price of steel, or some other good, is lower in Japan than
in the U.S.

5.

When U.S. manufacturers buy Japanese steel, they have to pay for it in
yen,
a.

p:\parry\logan\l 1-28-94.1




which they buy on the foreign exchange market.

4

C.

6.

Since that will mean additional bidders for yen, its value will climb
relative to the dollar.

7.

As the yen appreciates, the cost of Japanese steel to U.S. firms goes
up.even though the Japanese have not changed the (yen) price they
charge!

Of course, in the real world, a few of our trading partners doln their
exchange rates to the dollar, and some others don’t let their currencies float
with complete freedom. In addition, it may take time for exchange rates to
adjust.
1.

D.

VII.

This helps explain why the historical relationship between domestic capacity in
labor and product markets and inflation has held up throughout the 1980s and
so far in the 1990s.

Now to the third question. "What’s wrong with a little more inflation if the benefit is
more employment?"
A.

Well, what’s wrong is that a little more inflation may get us more employment,
but only temporarily.
1.

VIII.

However, that doesn’t change the basic point that we ca n ’t depend on
foreign capacity to keep U.S. inflation in check.

The Fed simply doesn’t have the power to push the economy beyond its
capacity to produce goods and services for very long.
a.

As 1 said before, output and employment depend on things that
are well beyond the Fed’s control.

b.

.things like the current technology, labor market size and
composition, and so forth.

2.

If the Fed triedto push the economy beyond its capacity, we mightget
a s h o r t- te rm rise in output and employment.

3.

But in the long run, output and employment would return to their
natural rates, and w e’d be left with accelerating inflation and financial
instability.

To sum up, our actions this year have been warranted to guard against an increase
in future inflation. Maintaining low inflation is important in providing a firm
foundation for sustainable economic growth.

p:\parry\logan\l 1-28-94.1




5

A.

Since th ere’s little or no slack in labor and product markets, it ’s clear that it
would have been a mistake to keep real s h o r t- te rm interest rates at the
stimulative levels of late 1992 through 1993.
1.

The last time these rates stayed at low levels for a long period was in
the 1970s.

2.

It made the economy "go" for a while, but eventually it led to the run­
up in inflation in the lale 70s and early 80s.

3.

And putting on the "economic brakes" to fight that inflation fla re-u p
led to a major recession.

B.

Although the recent situation wasn’t nearly as dire as that one was, we didn’t
want to risk even a small part of that kind of problem again.

C.

As a consequence, 1 think the steps w e’ve taken this year to raise rates are
appropriate:
1.

They should help to foster stable, sustainable economic growth with low
inflation.

2.

Such forward-looking monetary policy helps avoid the " g o - s t o p "
economic environment of the late 70s and early 80s, and it's much
more likely to produce a lasting economic expansion.

wc 1486

p:\parry\logan\l 1-28-94.1




6