View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ISSUES SHAPING THE U.S. ECONOMIC OUTLOOK IN 1989
(For Release: 3:00 P.M. EST, December 6, 1988)




ROBERT T. PARRY
PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO

GENERAL MEETING
TOWN HALL OF CALIFORNIA

LOS ANGELES, CALIFORNIA
DECEMBER 6, 1988

Good afternoon, ladies and gentlemen. It's a pleasure to share my views
on the outlook for the U.S. economy next year. As I see it, recession is not
an issue we'll have to face in the immediate future. Rather, the issues for 1989
are whether growth will be balanced, noninflationary, and conducive to the
longer-run health of the economy.
I'll begin with a brief review of the
economy's recent performance. This sets the stage for a discussion of the key
concerns I have as we stand on the threshold of a new year. Then I'll sum up
with my view of what this means for the economy and monetary policy in 1989.
Review

The past six years have seen a strong expansion in the U.S. economy -- the
longest peacetime expansion in U.S. history. More than 18 1/2 million jobs have
been created since the business cycle trough in 1982. The unemployment rate has
fallen to a fourteen-year low of 5 1/2 percent. At the same time, consumer price
inflation has been brought down from a peak of nearly 15 percent in 1980 to 4
percent over the past twelve months.
In 1987, real output grew by 5 percent, a remarkably robust performance
for an economy in its fifth year of expansion. The economy slowed modestly to
a 3 1/4 percent rate of growth in the first half of this year. This still is
surprisingly strong, considering that it followed the October 1987 stock-market
crash, and that second-quarter growth was held back by the drought.
Improvement in our foreign trade balance has been an engine for growth in
the past year and a half. Spending by businesses on equipment, and consumer
spending on services and durable goods also kept things moving along.
Since midyear, the economy has continued to grow at a robust pace. Output
grew at a 2.6 percent annual rate in the third quarter. That's down slightly
from the first ha 1f, mainly due to the temporary effects of the drought on
agricultural production. The effects of this decline in the agricultural sector
will be felt through the fourth quarter. However, we're also seeing signs of
considerable strength in the nonfarm sectors. If we abstract from the effects
of the drought, third-quarter growth registered a 3 1/4 percent annual rate,
and recent monthly numbers on employment, retail sales, and industrial production
were strong. Thus, overall, the slowdown in the economy compared with the first
half of the year probably is more apparent than real.
From my perspective as a central banker, a slowing trend actually would
be desirable. Recall that in the Summer of 1987, the Federal Reserve was
concerned that the economy was in serious danger of overheating."
The
unemployment rate was dropping and capacity utilization was rising --both into
ranges that signalled the economy was approaching its maximum capability to
produce goods and services. Long-term interest rates were rising, reflecting
the market's concern about future inflation. So, the Fed raised the discount
rate in September 1987 from 5 1/2 percent to six percent to make clear our
intention to cool things off a bit.
11

The stock-market crash in October required a detour in the course of
monetary policy. As fears of recession rose, the Fed quickly eased its reins
on credit and provided the liquidity needed by the financial and economic system.




1

By March of this year, however, the threat of recession largely had passed, and
the Fed returned to its anti-inflation course.
Since then, we have raised the discount rate another 1/2 percent to 6 1/2
percent. Interest rates have risen modestly partly as a result of a series of
tightening moves. Overall, financial markets have responded favorably to our
efforts: long-term interest rates have not risen as fast as short-term rates,
reflecting lower expectations of inflation.
Key Concerns
But the economy still is growing at a pace that cannot be sustained in the
long run without higher inflation. Worse, the pattern of growth, particularly
in the third quarter, also is of concern. Consumer spending remained strong at
the same time that business spending on plant and equipment tapered off sharply.
Likewise, our trade balance (adjusted for price changes) worsened for the first
time s i nee the end of 1986. And although fed era 1 government spending has
declined markedly over the course of this year, the federal budget deficit
remains massive.
These deve 1opments i 11 ustrate the persistent and dangerous structural
imbalances in our economy that have arisen in the current expansion.
By
11 Structural
imbalances, 11 I mean the federal-budget and trade deficits, and the
low personal saving rate. The combination of strong spending in the private
sector and unprecedented deficits in the federal government 1 s budget have
outstripped our nation 1 s saving and productive capacity. As a result, we have
had to rely on imports of foreign goods and fa reign funds to make up the
shortfall. As a nation, we simply have been (and still are) spending beyond our
means.
Fa reign financing has enab 1ed us to do this, but 1et 1 s be b1unt about
what s happening: we are mortgaging our future income, and the income of our
children, to pay for this spending spree. Of course, as every homeowner in
California knows, a big mortgage is not so onerous when we expect our incomes
and wealth to rise. But I worry when I look at how we 1 re spending the money.
The combination of continued strength in consumption and large budget deficits
is troublesome. And, although business investment in plant and equipment has
been robust in recent years, it has not been particularly strong compared to
previous expansions. We 1 re simply not investing enough in productive capacity
to boost our future income and cover the rising foreign debt service. This
situation spells trouble for future standards of living, and will only get worse
the longer the imbalances persist.
1

Another problem with these imbalances is that they have made U.S. economic
developments highly sensitive to changes in the foreign-exchange value of the
dollar. After falling sharply from early 1985 through 1987, the dollar has risen
on balance in 1988. In September, it was 10 percent (on a trade-weighted basis)
higher than at the end of 1987. Since then, the dollar has fallen, but its level
still is 2 percent higher now than at the end of last year. The dollar s higher
1eve 1 throughout much of the year has had, and cou 1d cant i nue to have, a
depressing effect on net exports and the economy generally. Of course, slower
growth in our export sector actually is beneficial in one respect: it is helping




1

2

to keep inflation under control and reducing upward pressure on interest rates.
But the higher dollar also is slowing the needed adjustment in our trade deficit
and increasing our foreign debts.
Conversely, a weaker dollar would help out on the foreign trade front,
also would have a downside: a lower dollar would increase inflationary
interest-rate pressures. In effect, the dollar has become a "catch-22" for
U.S. economy. If it falls, it creates inflation, and if it rises it delays
needed adjustment in our foreign deficit.

but
and
the
the

Some have embraced trade barriers as a way to reduce the trade deficit.
I want to emphasize that this approach would be disastrous. The kind of trade
protectionism embodied in the recent textile bill, for example, invites
retaliation, thereby threatening the world-wide economic expansion, and raises
prices in the U.S. without helping our overall trade situation. Freer trade,
along the lines of the pending U.S.-Canada Free Trade Agreement, is a much firmer
foundation for raising total U.S. exports.
In any event, there is one sure way out of the "catch-22" of the dollar:
reduce the federal budget deficit. Reducing the budget deficit would lower the
demand for foreign funds as well as the demands on the economy•s resources. This
would allow the dollar, the trade deficit, and interest rates to subside
simultaneously. It also would set the stage for more balanced and sustainable
economic growth over the long run, and thus enhance the chances of extending the
expansion well into the next decade.
Prospects for reducing the deficit are very difficult to assess. The
projections of the Administration and the Congressional Budget Office present
very different pictures. The Administration expects that Gramm-Rudman-Hollings
spending cuts will reduce the deficit by about $25 billion per year over the next
five years and bring the budget close to balance in 1993. The CBO sees
improvements of only $7 billion per year. These differences rest mainly on
alternative assumptions about economic developments over the next five years,
and my outlook is closer to that of the CBO.
But more important than differences in economic assumptions are the actions
the new Admi ni strati on wi 11 take to reduce the deficit. Unfortunately, the
gargantuan off-budget 1i ability of the Federa 1 Savings and Loan Insurance
Corporation won•t help matters. Estimates of the cost of dealing with all the
insolventS &Ls run as high as $100 billion! But despite the problems, it is
imperative that strong actions be taken -- and soon -- to set the deficit on a
decidedly downward course. And I don•t think r•m speaking just for myself: the
recent gyrations in the stock, credit, and foreign-exchange markets a 11 are
sending the same signal.
Price Stability

There is very little the Federal Reserve can do to correct the imbalances
I have described. We simply must deal with the situation as it is. Until
concrete progress is made in lowering the budget deficit, we are stuck with
structural imbalances that foster underlying inflationary pressures. Although
overall inflation has not accelerated this year compared to 1987, there have been




3

disquieting signs of a pick up in wages, salaries, and benefits. The most
comprehensive measure of labor compensation rose by 4 1/2 percent over the twelve
months ending last September, versus less than 3 1/2 percent over the prior
twelve months. Although part of this increase was due to special factors, the
figures do suggest that underlying wage pressures are rising in response to
today•s low unemployment rate. And the longer the economy continues to grow at
rates that strain capacity, the more these wage pressures will mount.
Now, I don•t want to give the impression that inflation is about to return
to double-digit levels. For one thing, the combination of a higher dollar and
lower oil prices so far this year provide some temporary relief. But we can•t
depend on factors beyond our control -- like the dollar and the price of oil
-- to solve our inflation problem for us. For example, developments at the
recent OPEC meeting raise the specter of higher oil prices, and threaten to put
upward pressure on inflation in the future.
We should not shy away from
corrective medicine while the inflation problem is still manageable. Even so,
it takes time for this medicine to work. The choices we make today will have
a larger impact on inflation in 1990 than in the coming year.
But some may wonder, "what•s wrong with a little inflation in the future
if reining it in means we have to accept s 1ower economic growth now?
The
problem is, a little inflation has a disturbing tendency to turn into a lot of
i nfl at ion. Inflation stunts economic growth and exacerbates business eye 1e
swings. And the experience of the early 1980s showed that once inflation gets
embedded in expectations, it•s difficult to root out. It took two back-to-back
recessions, soaring interest rates, and postwar-record unemp 1oyment to tame
inflation the last time around.
11

For this reason, we need to make steady progress towards price stability.
Now that we•re operating in the range of full employment, the economy can•t
afford to grow faster than the rate of growth in our long-run capability to
produce goods and services. This means the economy should expand next year (and
over the next several years) at less than a 2 1/2 percent pace. The economy•s
structura 1 imba 1ances may tend to push us higher than that, but the Fed must
resist these pressures.
Looking Ahead

Fortunately, the monetary tightening so far and the behavior of the dollar
this year should restrain economic growth somewhat in 1989. Whether these
factors alone will be sufficient to hold economic growth to a sustainable rate
of under 2 1/2 percent next year remains to be seen. I expect to see prices (as
measured by the fixed-weight GNP price index) rise at about the same rate next
year as this year; that is, in the 4 to 4 1/2 percent range. Inflation at this
pace next year is worrisome because luck has had a lot to do with keeping a lid
on prices recently. Movements in the dollar and the price of oil this year
should contribute to slightly lower inflation next year. And, assuming that
there is no drought next year, agricultural price increases should moderate from
their high drought-related levels this year. However, underlying inflationary
pressures, which are of primary concern to monetary policy, most likely will
continue to accelerate.




4

As I said at the outset, the key issue in 1989 will be whether growth next
year is balanced and conducive to the longer-run health of the economy.
Unfortunately, the prospects for more balanced growth in 1989 are not as bright
as I d like. The dollar•s rise since the end of 1987 dampens the outlook for
continued strong improvement in the trade balance. Investment spending also
seems likely to slow. Moreover, I expect the personal saving rate to remain
around its present low level through the end of next year. Finally, the federal
budget deficit will remain massive, by even the most optimistic projections.
1

As I have stressed, the Fed•s number one job is to promote price stability.
We can•t solve these structural imbalances in the economy, but we can and will
resist the inflationary pressures they create.
·




5