View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Expansion of Bank Securities
Powers: A Personal View
Presented
by
Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

to

American Bankers' Association
Investment and Funds Management Conference
San Diego, California
February 17,1988




Good morning ladies and gentlemen. It really is a pleasure to come to the
warmth of southern California to discuss an even hotter topic: the expansion of
commercial bank powers.
It seems likely that this year will see significant changes in banks' securities
powers. Last year's moratorium on the expansion of powers was a stop-gap measure
that was satisfactory to no one -- bankers, regulators, the competing interests in the
securities industry, or, most importantly, consumers of financial services. Yet there
is little agreement on the shape that reform should take. New legislative proposals
seem to appear almost daily and differ significantly in their features.

The issue of expanded bank powers is a conceptually tough one and it deserves
careful deliberation. But I also feel that it is important to move ahead on expanded
powers. The financial world is changing rapidly, and we cannot always wait for
perfect answers to all of our complex questions before accepting change.
·
I am convinced that we can move ahead safely with full securities powers for
banks. Banking organizations should be allowed to provide underwriting services,
operate investment funds, and provide full brokerage services-- all of the products of
an investment bank. My proviso is that expanded powers should be accompanied by
significantly greater reliance on capital in banking organizations. Institutions
unwilling to rely more heavily on capital should not be permitted to expand their
activities.
Let me share with you some of the observations that have led me to this point
of view.

The Market Wants Banks with Securities Powers
First of all, I believe that important economic benefits are being lost by
excluding banking organizations from securities activities. Many of the functions
that banks perform are used in underwriting, investment fund management, and
other securities services. It is logical and more efficient for one firm to provide both
types of service. Most importantly, consumers of financial services would benefit
from lower costs and greater convenience.
Current restrictions on banks' securities activities clearly run_counter to
market forces. Banks have been involved in the securities markets from the earliest
days of our nation's history. And when theN ational Bank Act restricted the right of
national banks to underwrite securities in,1864, the banks sought a way to avoid the
restriction by establishing state-chartered securities affiliates. By the late 1920s,
these affiliates participated in the underwriting of over 35 percent 'of all'new
corporate issues. In 1927, because of a change permitted by a feature of the
McFadden Act, national banks themselves were once again underwriting securities
and continued to do so until the passage of the Glass-Steagall Act during the reforms
of the Great Depression.
We also observe banking combined with securities activities in other
countries, mostly in the so-called ltuniversal banking" systems of Europe. In




-1-

Germany, banking powers are particularly broad. Banks can underwrite securities,
operate investment funds, control (or be controlled by) commercial enterprises, and
provide general lines of insurance, brokerage, and virtually every other financial
service. Such broad powers admittedly are the exception in world banking circles.
The universal banking experience does suggest, however, that placing banking and
nonbanking activities in the same organization can be successful and does not cause
draconian problems for the banking system or the economy.

Expanded Powers and Conflicts of Interest
Let me also say that I find the case against expanding banks powers less than
compelling. The case against expanded powers seems to turn on two issues -- first,
the problems of conflicts of interest and, secondly, exploitation of the banking safety
net. Let me address these in turn.
Critics of expanded powers claim that combining commercial banking and
investment banking would create broad opportunities for conflicts of interest.
Banking organizations, it is argued, would not behave prudently if they owned or
underwrote corporate securities. It is alleged that self-dealing, insider trading, and
other abuses would occur as the bank exploited its relationship to one set of
customers to the benefit of another. Proliferation of such conflicts of interest could
even lead to a loss of confidence in the banking system as· a whole and, therefore, be a
source of instability for the banking system. This is a variation of the arguments
made before the Senate Banking and Currency Committee in the early 1930s.
Instances of stock price manipulation by bankers and other actions involving
conflicts of interest did occur in financial markets during the Great Crash. Recent
examination of these events, however, finds them to have been quantitatively trivial
and assigns them no blame for the instability of the banking system that ensued.
More importantly, much has changed to make conflicts of interest much less of
an issue today. Important gaps in securities regulation were filled in the 1930s, such
as those that grew out of the Securities Act of 1934. And existing securities
regulations could be bolstered, if it is deemed necessary, by additional legislation.
The Proxmire~ Garn proposal, for example, contains special prohibitions against
conflicts of interest and self-dealing.
Just as importantly, however, conditions in the marketplace have changed to
provide an increasing degree of self-discipline. The ability to collect and disseminate
financial information, for example, is considerably improved today. The result is
that conflicts of interest can be more easily detected and the reputation of an
offending firm is more difficult to shield. This fact discourages undesirable behavior
from occurring in the first place.
A high level of competition in the investment banking services industry also
is important to controlling conflicts. The more competitive the industry, the greater
are the market's sanctions against abuse of customers. A discontented customer
simply can leave and use an alternative provider of the services. Indeed, one of the
positive features of allowing banks to enter the investment banking business is that



-2-

it may increase effective levels of competition. Given their opposition to the
expansion ofbank securities powers, the securities industry obviously also feels that
this would be the case.

Expanded Powers and the Bank Safety Net
The more serious objection to expanded bank powers is that broader powers
will lead to exploitation of the bank safety net. I believe that our current system of
deposit insurance and our behavior toward insolvent financial institutions does pose
serious problems that should be addressed immediately. It gives managers of
insured institutions an incentive when their capital is low to ..bet the bank" on risky
ventures. This is because they have a chance of some gain, and very little to lose.
After all, the insurance fund picks up the pieces in the event of bankruptcy.
The concern, of course, is that expanding bank powers into the securities area
will provide additional opportunities for expanding risk. Critics of expanded powers
cite, for example, that the income of securities firms is more volatile than banks'
income and thus that securities activity is riskier than banking. This line of
reasoning misses the point, however. First, the riskiness of securities activity per se
does not mean necessarily that it would add to overall bank risk. These activities
may offer diversification opportunities, with the result that a bank with securities
powers is less risky than either a pure bank or a pure securities firm.
More importantly, however, any activity can prQvide opportunities for risk
taking if a bank has an incentive to seek them out. For a bank in a weak capital
position, any expansion opportunity-- a new activity or even a new loan-- can be an
opportunity for increased risk taking. More important than the specific powers
offered by bank reform proposals, therefore, is the regulatory mechanism used to
contain risk taking.

Corporate Separateness
Looking over the various banking reform proposals, it is clear that the
primary mechanism proposed for controlling risk taking is to "separate" bank from
nonbank activities in different corporate entities. The idea is to allow. expansion of
bank powers without expanding risk by building ((firewalls" around the securities
activities of banking enterprises. These firewalls theoretically would protect the
bank and its depositors and insurers from any risks generated by nonbank activities.
To construct such firewalls, most proposals would isolate the nonbank
activities in nonbank affiliates, rather than allowing the bank to perform them
directly. In addition, transactions between the bank and nonbank affiliates would be
restricted.
The Proxmire-Garn bill, for example, would allow a securities subsidiary of a
bank holding company to engage in securities underwriting. But it would prohibit
virtually all credit transactions between the bank and securities affiliate. It even
would restrict indirect transactions, such as bank lending to buyers of securities



- 3-

underwritten by the affiliate. The Graham-Wirth, Cranston-D'Amato and DreierRoth bills would permit transactions between affiliates, but only under restrictive
conditions.
I see two problems with reliance on corporate separation to address the bank
risk issue. First, I wonder if it is possible to achieve meaningful corporate separation
without losing most of the advantages of the affiliation. If financial transactions
between bank and nonbank affiliates are severely restricted, so too may be the
advantages of combining these activities within a single organization.
Second, reliance on corporate separation may lull us into a false sense of
security about the insulation of the bank from risk. There are many ways for two
organizations to exchange resources and share risk. Ways will be found to breach
the firewall if the incentives are strong enough to do so.

Managing Banking Organization Risk
I do not believe that the answer to the problem of controlling bank risk is
simply to build a better firewall or to allow only ''low risk" nonbanking activities.
Rather, much of the answer lies in reducing the incentive of a banking organization
to take on risk in the first place. And this is best achieved by greater reliance on
capital in banking organizations.
As I have said already, the incentives to exploit the bank safety net increase
as capital positions deteriorate. Conversely, organizations with strong capital
positions will be less inclined to use their nonbanking activities to increase risk.
Therefore, if capital regulations can be strengthened, there is considerably less risk
in expanding banks' powers into securities or other activities. It also means that if
less restrictive firewalls can be used, then more of the advantages resulting from
combining banking and securities activities can be realized.
Capital regulation, of course, poses its own regulatory challenges. The
measurement and monitoring of capital positions is no easy task. And banking
organizations see capital as a very expensive source of funds. Also, some would
argue that the stringent regulation of the capital of a banking organization would
put it at a competitive disadvantage in the securities business.
But not relying on capital has disadvantages as well, for then the only
alternative to controlling risk is to build thick firewalls. These firewalls may
require such stringent regulation on interaffiliate transactions that any potentially
profitable combinations would be crippled. The advantages of a combined banking
and securities firm could be significant enough that it could compete effectively. with
pure securities firms despite capital requirements.
I am convinced, moreover, that even imperfect capital regulation is superior to
attempts to restrict transactions or regulate risk directly. With enough of its own
capital at risk, a bank becomes its own monitor, and market forces-- instead of being
at odds with the public interest-- can be a source ofs~ability.




- 4-

A Proposal
My proposal to you regarding expanded securities powers thus is quite simple.
Banking organizations willing to maintain strong capital positions should be
granted broad securities powers. Since it is capital, rather than corporate
separation, that provides the main protection against excessive risk taking,
transactions between bank and nonbank affiliates need not be restricted severely.
Regulatory and monitoring considerations probably do dictate that securities
activity be placed outside the bank in a separate affiliate. However, experience may
eventually indicate that -- with sufficient capital -- there is no need for complete
financial isolation of the affiliate. The organization then could enjoy the benefits of
truly integrated banking and securities activity.
Banking organizations in a weak or insolvent condition on a market value
basis should not be candidates for the right to expand their powers. This principle
would serve, first, to avoid placing expanded risk taking opportunities in the hands
of those most likely to abuse them. But it also would give these institutions an
incentive to repair their capital positions in order to acquire the powers of their
competitors.
It is interesting to note that all of the pending bills on Glass-Steagall reform
rely primarily on corporate separation, giving little attention to the role of capital in
controlling risk taking. The Proxmire-Garn bill contains a capital ''bear-down"
provision that would allow the Fed to intervene if a bank were being operated in an
unsafe and unsound manner as part of a larger, financial services holding company.
The Cranston-D'Amato proposal permits regulators to require greater bank capital
in a Depository Institution Holding Company if it has securities activities. The
sentiment of these provisions is correct, but they are a far cry from a call for greater
reliance on capital as a quid pro quo for greater powers.

How Far to Expand Powers?
I have spoken today mainly about expanded securities powers. But the public
discussion of bank powers -- and some of the bills before Congress -- looks to
expansion of insurance, real estate, and commercial powers as well. The WirthGraham proposal, for example, would permit expansion into virtually-any financial
business, while the Cranston-D'Amato proposal would allow affiliation with nonfinancial enterprises as well.
Much of the debate over the limits on expansion of bank powers is a fight over
turf. But there is also debate over whether a particular activity is "too risky" or
offers "too little synergy" to be associated with banking. From my vantage point, the
debate should focus instead on whether the levels of capital in the conglomerate
banking organization can be measured, can be monitored, and are adequate.
In this respect, securities and some insurance activities probably pose the
fewest problems from a capital regulation standpoint. Integration of commercial
firms and banks, on the other hand, poses a more significant surveillance challenge.




- 5-

Bankers Beware
It should be apparent that my sentiments lie with those who feel that an important
affinity exists between banking and securities activity. I would like to conclude my
remarks, however, with a cautionary note to my friends in the banking community.
It is easy to blame deteriorating earnings performance and market share on
limited powers. But expanded securities powers will not be a panacea. The problems
of low ROA and ROE, and loss of customers to direct placement markets and
investment funds can also be found in countries with universal banking.

The time has come to eliminate the bulk of the restrictions against bank
participation in securities activities. But it should not be seen as the long-sought
opportunity to shore up weak banks. On the contrary, to extend the opportunity to
poorly capitalized and poorly run banks would be a public policy blunder. Broad
powers to expand into the securities area should be reserved for banks willing to put
their own capital at risk.




-6-