View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Community Leaders
Tacoma
For delivery August 5, 1994

THE ECONOMY OF THE U.S. AND THE PACIFIC NORTHWEST

I.

Good afternoon.
A.

As you know, since the beginning o f the year, the Fed has raised short-term
interest rates four tim es-for a total increase o f 1 lA percentage points.
1.

B.

II.

Not surprisingly, some o f the reaction to these moves has been pretty
negative.
a.

Two o f the strongest reactions have focused on the timing.

b.

The first complaint is, "Why is the Fed raising rates when states
like California and Hawaii are still in the doldrums?”

c.

The second is, "Why raise short-term rates now when there’s
little sign of inflation heating up?"

In my remarks today, I’ll try to address these questions and explain the
rationales for the short-term interest rate hikes.

Let me start with a little background.
A.

After the recession, the national economy didn’t boom as it so often has.
Instead, the recovery was pretty sluggish.
1.

B.

p:\parry\tacoma\tac8-2.1




The Fed did its part to keep things going by lowering short-term
interest rates substantially.
a.

By the end of last year, short-term rates were about a third of
what they were in early 1989.

b.

In fact, real short-term rates-that is, adjusted for inflation-were
around zero levels throughout the year.

These low short-term rates stimulated rapid growth in the interest-sensitive
sectors of the economy-consumer durables, housing, and business investment.

1

1.

C.

III.

And they led to average growth rates of anywhere from 3 to 3 3A
percent for ’92, ’93, and the first half of ’94.

This growth has brought us to the point where a good deal o f the excess
capacity that built up during the 1990 recession has evaporated:
1.

Both the unemployment rate and the rate o f unused industrial capacity
have fallen rather sharply over the past year and a half—

2.

--within range of levels that most economists think represent "full"
utilization.

D.

These circumstances suggest that continuing to stimulate the economy with
such low short-term rates would lead to higher inflation.

E.

Now, as I said at the beginning, not everyone agrees that it was the right time
to reduce the monetary stimulus.

So let me address the first question: Shouldn’t the Fed keep stimulating the economy
until the weaker regions gain more strength? Doesn’t the Fed care about regional
performance?
A.

Part of the answer is that the Fed places great importance on understanding
economic conditions in the various regions o f the country.
1.

a.

—our headquarters in San Francisco, and four branches,
including one just up the road in Seattle—

b.

each with its own set of directors.

2.

We rely on the directors to give us a good regional perspective on
economic conditions, which is often quite different from what we hear
from Wall Street or Washington, D.C.

3.

For example, back in the fall of 1987, a lot o f people thought the stock
market crash would reverberate throughout the country, and signal a
major downturn.

4.

But our directors told us it simply wasn’t having that big an effect on
their business or geographic areas.

p :\parry\tacoma\tac 8-2.1




In this Federal Reserve District-the largest both in terms o f geography
and population-we have five offices-

2

a.

And they were right.

b.

The economy didn’t come to a screeching halt.

B.

In addition to providing assessments of the region’s performance, the Directors
also vote on the discount rate recommendation, which is then forwarded to the
Board of Governors in Washington.

C.

Finally, the Research staff at each Bank uses the Directors’ input--as well as
survey responses from local people and regional data--to prepare a report on
regional conditions for the meetings o f the FOMC, the Fed’s monetary
policymaking body.
1.

Here in the Twelfth District, these reports cover a lot of territoryliterally and figuratively--and a wide variety of economic performance.
a.

2.

Washington isn’t at either extreme, but it is lagging the nation.
a.

3.

4.

p: \parry\tacoma\tac8-2.1




Right now, we have the nation’s three fastest growing statesUtah, Nevada, and Idaho— as well as its two poorest
performers—Hawaii and California.

During the past year, payroll employment in Washington grew
at less than a 2 percent rate, almost a full percentage point
behind the nation’s growth rate.

Much of the weakness in the state’s economy is right here in the Puget
Sound area, and it’s largely due to Boeing.
a.

Manufacturing employment in this area is down more than 5
percent from a year ago,

b.

and the pace of job growth in other sectors ranges from negative
to modestly positive.

But it looks like the worst is nearly over.
a.

With the Boeing layoffs nearly complete, the pace of growth
should pick up here in the Puget Sound area.

b.

And that bodes well for the state of Washington, since the rest
of the state is doing very well.

3

D.

IV.

(1)

In fact, on a statewide basis, manufacturing employment
would have grown during the past year if the aircraft
sector hadn’t lost any jobs.1

(2)

And most measures of statewide construction activity
show very strong growth during the past year.2

This kind of regional information plays an important role in determining the
course of monetary policy.
1.

In fact, it’s the subject of a good portion of each FOMC meeting.

2.

And we use it to fit together a picture of how the whole economy is
doing.

And that’s where the Fed’s emphasis has to be--on the nation as a whole. The Fed
can’t conduct monetary policy based mainly on helping out a particular state or
region.
A.

The reason is simple: monetary policy works through national credit markets.
1.

And, in the U .S ., credit markets are very efficient,
a.

B.

processing transactions from coast to coast in no more than a
split second.

2.

Therefore, monetary policy affects the economy as a whole.

3.

That’s why it’s sometimes called a "blunt" instrument.

Above and beyond the practical difficulties, there’s also a real danger in
focusing too much on any one region of the economy that’s having a hard
time.
1.

Often enough, some state or region is going through a recession of its
own while the national economy is humming along.

1 This does not include any "multiplier" effects.
2

Construction employment
Housing permits (3-mo. moving average)
Nonres construction awards (3-mo. average)
p:\parry\tacoma\tac8-2.1




6/93 to 6/94
5/93 to 5/94
5/93 to 5/94

4

+7.5%
+9.5%
+23.4%

a.

2.

If the Fed stimulated whenever any state had economic hard times,
w e’d be stimulating almost all the time.

3.

And the upshot of that would be a very pro-inflationary environment,
a.

V.

It’s simple arithmetic. If the nation is growing at, say, 3
percent, then some states are growing faster, and some are
growing slower.

and ultimately a deteriorating economy as well.

Now let me turn to the second reason some people think the Fed should have
maintained a stimulative policy: Inflation just doesn’t seem to be a problem now.
A.

The trouble with this view is that monetary policy is not only "blunt," as I’ve
already mentioned, but it’s also subject to "delayed reactions":
1.

It takes a long time for a policy action to produce results against
inflation—probably from IV2 to 2 years.

2.

This kind of time lag means that we can’t wait until the problems show
up in the data—
a.

3.

B.

Instead, we have to anticipate problems, and pay attention to the
warning signs.

The current situation is a good example. It’s true that we haven’t seen an
acceleration recently in the important inflation statistics, like the consumer
price index.
1.

C.

In fact, recent inflation news has been favorable.

But for a couple of reasons, some action was warranted to prevent an increase
in future inflation.
1.

First, short-term real interest rates were near zero from late 1992
through 1993.
a.

p:\parry\tacoma\tac8-2.1




—by then w e’re likely to be too late.

The last time these rates stayed at low levels for a long period
was in the 1970s, just before the run-up in inflation in the late
70s and early 80s.

5

b.

2.

Although the recent situation wasn’t nearly as dire as that one
was, we didn’t want to risk even a small part o f that kind of
problem again.

Second, there’s much less slack in labor and product markets.
a.

In fact, we can’t be certain that any slack remains
(1)

D.

because these things are notoriously hard to measure.

b.

This raises the chance that extra stimulus to the economy would
sow the seeds of inflation in the future.

c.

Historically, once the economy has moved beyond its potential
levels of production and employment, the result has been higher
inflation, with no long-run improvement in the unemployment
rate.

As a consequence, I think the steps w e’ve taken to raise rates are appropriate:
1.

They guard against getting into this "no-win" situation by fostering
stable, sustainable economic growth with low inflation.

2.

Such forward-looking monetary policy helps avoid the "go-stop"
economic environment o f the 1970s, and it’s much more likely to
produce a lasting economic expansion.

wc 1421

p:\parry\tacoma\tac 8-2.1




6