View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

California Savings and Loan League
for delivery September 14. 1990
San Francisco, CA

Deposit Insurance Reform:
A Personal View
tne ~&L and banking industries have
(~·~ijlough Saddam Hussein's invasion

fespi te.)

been in the headlines a lot lately.
of Kuwait has provided a small

The enormity of the crisis of insolvent thrift institutions is
absolutely staggering.
1.

II.

B.

There's no denying that all these factors have contributed to the
crisis.

C.

But one of the major causes of the problem hasn't received nearly
enough attention. That is, our flawed system of deposit
insurance.

D.

Indeed, the key to avoiding crises like this in the future is to
reform the deposit insurance system.

E.

So, today, I'd like to discuss briefly the problems with the
current system.

F.

And then I'd like to put a reform proposal on the table to get
your comments and reactions.
1.

This proposal addresses the key flaws in the current system.

2.

Importantly, it also addresses some of your concerns about
other proposals that are being circulated; namely, what we
do about the insurance ceiling.

3.

In this sense, I think this proposal offers a solution to
the problem that is fair to depositors and all institutions,
regardless of size.

Turning first to the problem and its background,
A.

The basic problem is one that has been there since deposit
insurance was introduced in 1934.
1.




And tales of fraud and mismanagement at failed institutions,
coupled with allegations of regulatory permissiveness, have
made attention-grabbing news copy.

Insured institutions have incentives to take on more risk
than they would if they weren't insured because they don't
have to pay higher premiums for higher risk.




2

2.

B.

Moreover, the less capital, or net worth, an institution
has, the greater is its incentive to "bet the bank• on risky
ventures. This is a big problem since a large number of
institutions are thinly capitalized.
a.

If a private insurer were to offer a flat rate premium
for all levels of risk, it wouldn't be in business
very long.

b.

Come to think of it, there are striking examples of
state government-sponsored insurance funds that have
foundered for the same reason.

c.

And, of course, the insolvency of FSLIC is the most
recent consequence of such a faulty approach.

But if these perverse incentives have been there all along, why
has the problem become so serious only in recent years?
1.

2.

Adverse economic conditions and increased competitive
pressures were the catalysts, depressing market value net
worth.
a.

The interest-rate spike in 1980-81 sharply reduced the
market-value net worth of much of the S&l industry.

b.

And the downturn in the farm-belt and the oil patch
impaired the capital of a good number of banks as well
as thrifts.

At the same time, increased competition in the financial
services industry has reduced bank and thrift franchise
values.
a.

3.

With diminished franchise value, less was at risk when
institutions encountered difficulties. So, bet-thebank gambles became more enticing.

However, the most important contributor to the magnitude of
the problem was the regulators' mistaken policy of
forbearance when capital positions deteriorated.
a.

The policy rested on the false hope of a spontaneous
recovery in asset values.

b.

It also accommodated politicians' reluctance to
recognize the budgetary realities of closing insolvent
institutions.

c.

But it underestimated the strength of the "go-forbroke• incentive I mentioned a moment ago.

3

C.

FIRREA addresses this problem of inadequate capital to a certain
extent. And it restricts the opportunities for regulatory
forbearance. So, we're likely to see fewer bet-the-bank gambles
in the future.

D.

But by itself, FIRREA cannot solve the problem.

III. So, let me now sketch out for you the broad contours of a permanent
reform proposal.

IV.




A.

This proposal deals with the problem of insufficient net worth and
at same time addresses two vexing problems (the insurance limit
and "too-big-to-fail") in a way that I think is fair to all
institutions.

B.

My approach to deposit reform is based upon several assumptions.
1.

The need to prevent destabilizing runs is the primary
rationale for deposit insurance. -

2.

Market discipline is the most effective means of controlling
risk taking ...

3.

. .. And equity and subordinated debt holders are the best
sources of market discipline.
a.

Small depositors cannot be expected to monitor the
performance of depository institutions and be a source
of market discipline.

b.

This means they should be insured to guarantee that
they don't precipitate runs.

These assumptions lead to a deposit insurance reform proposal that has
several key elements:
A.

The first is a prompt resolution rule; this rule must be
consistent, and firmly applied.
1.

We must abandon forbearance.

2.

This is the key, both to limiting the liability of the
insurance fund, and to encouraging the development of market
discipline.

3.

To make this workable, we need to specify clearly some riskadjusted minimum level of capital. Below this, an
institution would be closed or reorganized.
a.

At the end of this year, the new international, riskbased capital standards will begin to be phased in.

4

(1)

4.

5.

B.

b.

I'm pleased that many institutions already meet the
fully phased-in international requirements.

c.

But quite frankly, I think we need higher capital in
the bank and thrift industries. Probably higher even
than the fully phased-in standards will require.

Now, I'll be the first to admit that raising more capital
won't be easy or cheap.
a.

ROE isn't exactly what one might call stellar -- in
either the bank or the thrift industry.

b.

And I've heard it said many times that because of
this, the only way to raise additional capital is to
increase risk so that the return to investors won't
fall.

c.

But let me stress that the regulators can't allow this
to happen; higher risk would defeat the purpose of
higher capital standards.

d.

The point is, we need to eliminate the deposit
insurance subsidy that currently is capitalized into
bank and thrift equity values.

e.

Then, and only then, will investors put a premium on
well-capitalized institutions -- just the way they did
before deposit insurance was put in place, and the
average equity capital ratio was around 20 to 25%!

The transition, of course, may be painful. For example,
it's likely that higher capital requirements will accelerate
the trend towards consolidation.
a.

In fact, in the thrift industry, we may find that the
problem isn't really capital adequacy at all.

b.

Instead, the problem may be that there are simply too
many institutions in the industry.

In any event, to enforce higher capital requirements, it would be
useful to have a kind of "progressive discipline," in addition to
the ultimate threat of prompt reorganization.
1.




These standards apply to banks, but because
FIRREA requires that bank and thrift standards
be comparable over time, they will affect your
industry, too.

The first step would be to require institutions whose
capital approached the minimum to raise additional equity




5

capital.
a.

If they couldn't do that, they would be subjected to
increasingly stringent regulatory limits on their
behavior.

b.

For example, as Chairman Greenspan suggested in recent
congressional testimony on deposit insurance reform,
we could require an institution to:
(1)

cut dividends;

(2)

restrict its use of brokered deposits.

(3)

slow asset growth or even downsize; and/or

(4)

divest affiliates.

2.

But I'd also take Chairman Greenspan's proposal one step
further, and base capital requirements on market valuation
wherever possible. Market value, not book value, determines
the liability of the insurance fund.

3.

Certain components of the balance sheet lend themselves well
to this approach.
a.

4.

5.

For example, traded securities, whether they are held
for investment or in a trading account, can be easily
valued using market data.

On the other hand, valuing loans will always be difficult
because loans are not regularly trade in the open market.
But even here, we can be more realistic.
a.

We know that the book value of a loan overstates its
market value whenever the market rate on a comparable
new loan is above the older loan's contractual rate.

b.

Likewise, it's obvious that classified loans are not
worth what their book values imply they're worth.

c.

Let's put this information to use.

There may be legal problems with enforcing a market-value
closure rule, but we have to overcome them.
a.

After all, if we can't close institutions that are
insolvent (or perilously close to insolvency), we
can't limit the liability of the insurance fund.

b.

Moreover, if we can't close insolvent institutions, we
won't have market discipline, either.




6

(1)
C.

I believe market discipline is desirable, not only from equity
holders, but from certain classes of liability holders, as well.
1.

In theory, prompt closure of near-insolvent institutions
would eliminate the need for debt-holder discipline and even
for a deposit insurance fund.

2.

But regulators can and do make mistakes regarding the
valuation of a portfolio.

3.

So, we need investors with the same incentives as the
regulators.
a.

D.

E.

F.

Investors must know their funds are at risk.

In fact, investors ideally ought to have even stronger
incentives than regulators to monitor institutions and
force the closure of insolvent ones.

I might note that subordinated debt-holders also should be
considered an important source of market discipline, particularly
on the large institutions that have access to such debt markets.
1.

These liability-holders can't run the way depositors can, so
their funds provide the same buffer against losses as
equity.

2.

Moreover, subordinated debt-holders have the same incentives
as an insurer to monitor an institution and even to close it
when it becomes insolvent. This means they can augment the
discipline imposed by shareholders.

The final element of this proposal is to limit deposit insurance
to $100,000, preferably on a per capita basis, if a practical way
could be found to do this.
1.

Unlike some in Congress and elsewhere who advocate rolling
back the statutory limit, I just don't think a lower limit
is necessary or even helpful.

2.

I would leave the "small depositor• insured, and hence
eliminate this potential source of runs.

3.

Such an approach doesn't sacrifice much market discipline.

4.

And it leaves large depositors as a source of discipline.

In summary, the keys to reforming deposit insurance are: prompt
resolution, maintenance of adequate capital, and strict
application of a $100,000 insurance ceiling.
1.

Reducing the insurance ceiling further and/or adopting co-

7

insurance, as some have advocated, are unlikely to produce
much in terms of market discipline and probably are
politically infeasible, anyway.

v.

VI.




Now let me say a few words about TOO big to fail.
11

II

A.

With the reforms I've outlined, no bank or S&L will be too big to
fail.

B.

The TBTF policy has been part of the problem.
1.

It has produced virtually

2.

It also has greatly limited depositor and other liabilityholder discipline.

3.

The TBTF policy has amplified the risk of systemic failure
of the payments system. (That is, one institution's failure
causing other institutions to fail.) Under TBTF, there is
little incentive for one institution to scrutinize the
condition of the larger institutions through which it
conducts its payments business.

10~

coverage of all liabilities.

C.

If all institutions, regardless of size, were subject to the same
rules regarding closure or reorganization, interbank lending would
be subject to market discipline, and the risk of systemic failure
would be reduced.

D.

Eliminating the TBTF policy may require a phase-in period, but
this policy must go if we are to keep big institutions from
turning into financial "welfare dependents" and enjoying a
competitive advantage over smaller institutions.

In conclusion,
A.

Failure to reform deposit insurance and diminish the incentives it
creates for excessive risk taking will lead to additional
insurance fund crises.

B.

It will also make it more difficult for financial institutions to
obtain expanded powers from regulators and legislators.

C.

Proapt resolution of near-insolvent institutions and greater
reliance on market discipline are essential to true deposit
insurance reform.
1.

With an approach along the lines I've presented, I think we
can get rid of TBTF and keep the level of insurance
protection at $100,000.

2.

This will help constrain undue risk taking in our financial
system. At the same time, it will maintain protection of

8

small depositors and the protection against runs that we
have come to expect.
3.
D.




Best of all, it will mean that we shouldn't ever have to
bail out the insurance funds again.

Now, I'm interested in hearing your comments ...