View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

•*ia

ERAL RESERVE RANK
SAN FRANCISCO

OFFICE OF
THE PRESIDENT

“Challenges in Deposit Insurance Reform”
Presentation before the
Conference of Business Economists
Washington, D.C.




Robert T. Parry, President
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

November 6-7, 1986




-

1

-

Public policy debate over the federal deposit insurance system has
come to the fore only in recent years.
How the deposit insurance system is
affected by —
and also affects —
bank and thrift behavior was not
debated in 1980 when the Congress increased deposit insurance coverage and
passed legislation that paved the way for the removal of deposit-rate
ceilings and provided new powers for thrifts.
What has happened since 1980 so that we now have a session on
"Depository Insurance in Crisis?"
The answer, of course, is that failures
among depositories have jumped sharply, and the problem lists for banks and
thrifts
have
ballooned.
These
developments
have meant
a
dramatic
escalation in the expenses of the deposit insurance funds.
The situation
for
the
Federal
Savings
and
Loan
Insurance
Corporation
(FSLIC)
is
particularly critical, as its reserves have fallen appreciably.
Moreover,
it is reported that there are hundreds of insolvent thrifts, and the
resolution of those cases would be beyond the capacity of the FSLIC's
current reserves.

Deposit Insurance and Risk
The losses to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and the
depleted reserves of the FSLIC have put the spotlight on the deposit
insurance
system.
However,
these
losses
are
symptoms.
The more
fundamental problem with the deposit insurance system (or any government
guarantee) is that it subsidizes and encourages risk-taking.
The connection between deposit insurance and risk-taking is a simple
one.
With federal insurance, depositors and other creditors of a bank or
thrift generally have less incentive to monitor the soundness of the
institution.
This point is particularly relevant in a system with
virtually 100 percent deposit coverage.
Thus, with extensive insurance
coverage, there is only limited feedback from the cost of liabilities when
a bank or thrift takes on additional risk.
Without the feedback from the
cost of deposits, risky investments appear to be more lucrative to a bank
or thrift, and they are more likely to be undertaken than would be the case
if there were no insurance.

Connection with Innovation
The distorted risk-return tradeoff for depositories shifts to the
regulators much of the task of keeping risk-taking in check.
One
avenue
used by regulators is not to allow institutions or their holding companies
to engage in certain activities.
Such limits in part are justified as
being necessary to isolate the distortions to risk-taking introduced by
deposit insurance.
It would be naive, however,
to think that this is the
only reason we have laws limiting the provision of financial services by
banks.
But the interest of banks in new activities and the desire of other
institutions to own banks are motivated in part by the attraction of
federal deposit insurance.




-

2

-

There is much more to financial innovation, however, than the desire
to take advantage of the deposit insurance system.
Innovation, in part,
reflects the responses of banks and other financial institutions to changes
in the demand and supply conditions for financial services.
I could cite
many examples.
One is the increased demand for the
management of risk
that has come with the economic uncertainty of the 1980s.
Another is the
rapidly increasing supply of low-cost financial services that has resulted
from improvements in computing and communications technologies.
Many new powers sought by banks may actually lead to a reduction in
risk through greater diversification.
This does not contradict my earlier
assertion that deposit insurance encourages risk-taking.
With or without
deposit insurance, banks as well as thrifts will diversify where it is
economical to do so in an attempt to minimize their risk relative to their
expected return.
However, the large number of banks specializing in
agricultural
lending
and
thrifts
in mortgage
lending
indicates
that
diversification may be costly and often curtailed by regulation.
Much of
the specialization we still observe stems from such things as limits on
branching and interstate banking, or special tax incentives for thrifts to
invest in mortgage-related assets.
Without these obstacles, we would see
more risk reduction through diversification.
Similarly, expanded powers
for banks could reduce "needless" (non-profitable) risk exposure for them
and, thus, for the FDIC.
This seems to have been recognized to some extent
in the regulation of thrifts, which have been granted relatively broad
powers.

The Challenge to Deposit Insurance
Although I favor expanding bank powers, I am aware that there is
legislative and regulatory concern that such expansion could broaden the
scope
for
risk-taking,
possibly nullifying the
potential
gains
from
diversification.
In replying to this concern, it has been suggested that
new powers be allowed primarily through holding company subsidiaries and
corporate separability be enforced between the bank and the holding
company.
In principle, this approach would insulate the deposit insurance
guarantee, which applies to bank deposits, from the broader powers afforded
holding companies.
There is considerable question, however, as to whether
effective separation is possible.
And, if it were, it is likely that the
synergies of organization, marketing, and brand name identification that
now exist between bank and nonbank subsidiaries within a holding company
would be lost.
Given
doubts
about
the
effectiveness
of
enforcing
corporate
separateness, the regulatory goal of isolating the influence of deposit
insurance will continue to dampen progress toward allowing innovation in
the provision of financial services by banks and to some extent by thrifts.
The challenge in deposit insurance reform is to protect depositors and to
maintain
stability
among
banks
and
thrifts,
while
minimizing
the
distortions to risk-taking and thereby limiting the need to restrict the
ability of depositories to engage in profitable activities.




-

3

-

The Appeal of Market Discipline
If we were to focus only on minimizing the distortions that deposit
insurance has on risk incentives, the ideal would be to reduce the
intrusion of federal deposit insurance and to maximize reliance on the
incentives in the market to bring about the optimal allocation of resources
and risk.
This is precisely why a move in the direction of greater market
discipline is so appealing.
Key proposals in this regard are those that
would increase the risk to depositors and hence rely more heavily on
depositor surveillance to check bank risk.
The usefulness of many of the
other approaches for tapping the incentives in the market, such as greater
disclosure of information to depositors and private deposit insurance,
rests on the feasibility of shifting greater risk to depositors.

The Feasibility of Reliance on Depositors
The question is whether it is possible to increase depositor risk
while still protecting depositors and maintaining stability in banking.
In
this regard, the continued insurance of "small" deposits does not seem
controversial.
While some persons have pondered the possibility of
abolishing federal deposit insurance altogether, most serious proposals for
reform would retain some minimal amount of coverage.
The more substantive debate revolves around whether we can provide
insurance only on some deposits and still maintain an acceptable degree of
stability among banks and thrifts.
The critical question is whether
holders of 1 iquid deposits (those that can be withdrawn freely on short
notice) can be placed at greater risk without exposing the payments system
and credit markets to possible disruptions from system-wide runs on banks
and thrifts.
In principle, we could eliminate deposit insurance and still prevent
bank runs,
but only by changing
the fundamental
nature of deposit
contracts.
Without federal deposit insurance, holders of liquid deposits
might "run" because, by withdrawing funds before anyone else, they can
avoid bearing their share of the losses of an institution thought to be
insolvent.
Depositors could be prevented from escaping their liability,
for example, if the liability connected with liquid deposits could be
imposed retroactively for some period after the time of withdrawal.
If
such an approach were taken, which I do not think is at all likely, there
would be greater depositor surveillance and a meaningful risk premium paid
even for liquid deposits.
Without the protection of federal deposit insurance, depositors also
could be expected to seek out market options for reducing risk.
For
example, depositors would have more incentive to divide their funds among a
larger number of financial institutions.
Moreover, if runs were not a
concern, we could rely on private deposit insurance.
Private insurers,
however, would not provide general indemnification against the insolvency
of a bank or a thrift and probably would retain the right to cancel
coverage on relatively short notice.
Nevertheless, the private market
still might find it profitable to insure against events such as fraud,



-

4

-

insider abuse, or isolated economic events like the closing of a factory in
a community.
Private insurance itself, however, would not eliminate the incentives
for
runs
that
stem
from
the
nature
of
liquid
deposit
accounts.
Consequently, with the prevailing belief among policy makers that runs are
a concern because of the large volume of liquid deposits at banks and
thrifts, an acceptable approach to reforming deposit insurance in the near
term is not likely to be one that relies on a significant increase in risk
to liquid deposits.

The Alternatives to Increasing the Risk to Liquid Deposits
Longer-term d e b t . Putting bank and thrift longer-term, and therefore
less liquid, liabilities at greater risk is one alternative for generating
more market discipline without exacerbating the run problem.
However, if
deposit insurance were subsidized and short-term accounts covered, banks
and thrifts would have little incentive to attract uninsured longer-term
funds.
They would have to be given a reason to hold such liabilities.
We
already have something along these lines in that total capital requirements
can be satisfied partly by subordinated debt.
Risk-related insurance premiums. In order to increase the discipline
imposed on individual
institutions, the FDIC and the FSLIC have been
pressing for authority to charge risk-related insurance premiums.
This
option may be adopted by the Congress at some point, but probably not with
much bite.
For example, the bills introduced this year call for premiums,
currently at 1/12th of a percent of deposits for banks, to rise at most to
1/6th of a percent.
That difference is not large enough to differentiate
between institutions
that pose a large and immediate threat to the
insurance funds and those that do not.
The small added premium would
suffice neither to cover the funds' added risk nor to dissuade weak
institutions from taking on additional risks.
Besides the operational
difficulty
the
insurance
agencies
would
encounter
in
appropriately
measuring and pricing risk, the practical
problem of charging a rate
sufficient to cover the full risk posed by problem institutions could be
insurmountable.
Capital
requirements.
The
imposition
of
"risk-related
capital
requirements" is another option currently being pursued by the federal bank
regulatory agencies and the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.
This option has
many of the operational problems of accurate ex ante risk assessment that
imposing risk-related premiums would have.
Unlike variable insurance
premiums, however, the regulatory agencies do not need new legislation to
implement risk-related capital requirements.
In fact, the Federal Home
Loan Bank Board recently announced new variable capital requirements for
savings and loans and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the
FDIC,
and
the
Federal
Reserve
are
reviewing
proposals
for capital
requirements that explicitly take into account, among other things, certain
off-balance-sheet activities.
Regulatory standards for additional capital
in relation to the ex ante risk assessment of an institution would help in
resolving the insurance dilemma.



-

5

-

Closure Policy and Market Valuation
Risk-related capital is not really a radical concept in the regulatory
framework.
In principle, required capital is supposed to reflect the risk
of an institution.
The experience over the past several years, however,
makes it clear that this has not always been the case.
Many institutions
have been allowed to operate without capital, let alone risk-related
capital.
Indeed,
the
tendency
for
the
regulatory
process
to
permit
undercapitalized banks and thrifts to continue operating with the hope that
they can regain financial well-being has been criticized (and correctly so)
as being at the root of the problems facing the deposit insurance funds.
This has prompted what could be the most promising proposals for deposit
insurance reform:
1) The adoption of a longer-term strategy for more
prompt closures to resolve problems before they impact heavily on the
insurance funds; and 2) greater reliance on market-value rather than bookvalue accounting measures.
Looking
at
these
proposals
in
the context
of the
traditional
approaches to bank and thrift regulation, all that is being suggested is
that capital requirements be enforced more stringently and the measure of
capital used be more relevant to the losses that will be borne by the
deposit insurance funds.
When a bank or thrift fails and has to be
liquidated or merged, it is the market values of the assets and liabilities
that count.
And, since losses measured on a book-value basis generally lag
those realized on a market-value basis, banks and thrifts are not closed
until it is too late.

Tough Issues for Implementation
The
potential
gains
from
using
market
valuation
and
closing
institutions on time are striking.
As has been pointed out in numerous
articles on deposit insurance reform, if a bank or thrift could be closed
before the market value of its capital fell to zero, then the FDIC and
FSLIC would be completely protected.
(The insurance funds still would have
to cover administrative costs and losses resulting from measurement errors,
however.)
It is of interest to note that if regulators really were successful in
closing problem institutions in time, all liability holders would be
protected from risk.
Although "uninsured" depositors conceptually would
provide surveillance and market discipline, in fact, they would be "free
riders" and rely on the regulators to monitor banks and thrifts.
Bank and
thrift regulators would serve the functions of monitoring institutions,
requiring capital, and closing institutions if the market value of capital
approached zero.




-

6

-

In practice, however, we can expect to fall short of the ideal.
First, measurement errors in determining the market values of assets and
liabilities might be large.
In addition, banks and thrifts could not be
monitored continuously, and the value of an institution's capital could
decline below zero between examinations.
To guard against the second problem, regulatory actions often would
have to be taken even before an institution's net worth reached zero.
Some
institutions estimated to have a positive but low level of capital might
have to be forced to liquidate or to merge with another institution (if the
shareholders were unwilling or unable to raise new capital quickly).
In
such cases, since the market valuation of an institution by the insurance
fund or other regulatory agency would have to be largely subjective, the
regulatory agencies would be vulnerable to lawsuits, especially where
action is forced.
Although the legal costs could be large, they probably
would be preferable to the potentially much larger losses sustained because
institutions systematically were closed too late.
Moreover, allowing
institutions to operate only if they have positive market-value capital
removes one of the most serious distortions that arises from deposit
insurance -- the incentive of managers of negative net worth institutions
to "bet the bank."
Even if the regulatory agencies had the power and incentives to close
depository institutions promptly, it is likely that some failed banks and
thrifts would have negative net worth.
In those cases, the federal deposit
insurance funds could be protected further if bank and thrift equity
holders were liable for losses exceeding their original . investment.
In
fact, something similar to this approach was actually in effect prior to
the early 1930s, when stockholders of nationally chartered banks could be
held liable for more than the amount of paid-in capital.
However, the
chance that such a policy would be resurrected for banks and thrifts is
probabl y slim.

Conclusion
The central issue facing deposit insurance reform is how to balance
the distortions resulting from deposit insurance against the instability of
banking that might result from not having deposit insurance.
Although we
could devise ideal structures that would allow both full market discipline
and protection against bank runs, practical considerations in the near term
limit placing substantially increased risk on holders of liquid deposits.
Given this fact, if we are to maintain the advantages of free enterprise in
banking and to encourage institutions to expand their activities, the
incentives
for
the
stockholders
and
long-term
debtholders
must
be
appropriate.
In short, this means that there must be adequate capital and
capital holders must bear the burden of losses in the banking and thrift
industry.