View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
,JQF SAN FRANCISCO

OFFICE OF
THE PRESIDENT

W




THE BANK CAPITAL DILEMMA

ROBERT T. PARRY
PRESIDENT
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO

EIGHTEENTH ANNUAL PRESIDENTS SEMINAR
CALIFORNIA BANKERS ASSOCIATION

LAGUNA NIGUEL, CALIFORNIA
JANUARY 16, 1987




I am pleased to be here to discuss bank capital and its regulation -a very important issue in banking.
In this area, as in other aspects of
banking regulation, we find market forces at odds with regulatory
constraints.
Often, when such tensions mount, regulatory change occurs.
We certainly saw this in the case of interest rate ceilings on deposits,
which now have been almost completely eliminated.
We also see many of the
current barriers separating banking and nonbanking activities giving way.
In contrast, much of the change in the regulation of bank capital over
the past several years has been toward strengthening capital standards.
We
see this in the increased minimum capital requirements for large banks and
for thifts, the proposals for "risk-based" capital r e q u i r e m e n t s , and the
wider recognition of the shortcomings associated with traditional bookvalue accounting measures of capital.
In my comments I would like to take up three issues:
1.
The public policy role of bank capital;
2.
The renewed emphasis on bank capital regulation; and
3.
The dilemma presented by capital regulation.
PUBLIC POLICY ROLE OF BANK CAPITAL
Regulation of bank capital comes into play in part because we have
embraced a public policy goal of stability in banking.
To this end, the
Congress established the Federal Reserve as lender of last resort in 1913
and subsequently the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) in 1933.
In the 1930s, the deposit guarantee also was extended to thrifts through
the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC).
This federal
safety net has been credited with maintaining confidence in the banking
system, even in the face of hundreds of bank failures over the past six
years.
However, the presence of the federal guarantee in banking increases
the importance of capital regulation because bank depositors have less
incentive to monitor the level of bank capital --and if they are 100
percent insured, have no incentive to do so. This, in turn, enables banks
(and thrifts) to operate with less capital than otherwise would be the
case.
In short, deposit insurance is seen as encouraging lower capital
ratios.
I n d e e d , we need only to look back to a period before the
establishment of the Federal Reserve and the FDIC to find banks with much
higher capital ratios than today.
Fundamentals of capital determination
If we had no deposit insurance or federal deposit guarantees of any
kind, the amount of capital a bank chose to hold would be influenced by a
number of the same factors considered by an unregulated firm. While
finance theorists do not all agree, many argue that because of business
uncertainties, bankruptcy costs, and taxes, a bank would seek out an
optimal capital ratio that would be part of its profit maximizing business
strategy.
Either too much or too little equity relative to deposits and
other liabilities would impair the value of a bank's stock.
Under this view,
it is commonly accepted that one factor that tends
to limit the use of debt by an unregulated firm is the risk premium




-

2

-

demanded by the market to compensate debt holders for the possibility a
firm would not be able to repay full interest and principal.
As you know,
one of the main factors considered by the private rating agencies is the
capital of a firm, or its inverse, capital leverage -- the lower the
capital (or the higher the leverage), the lower the firm's rating and the
higher its cost of borrowed funds.
The same would be true for bank deposit costs except that the federal
safety net "short circuits" the link between capital leverage and the
interest rate on insured deposits.
This occurs also for "uninsured"
deposits and other borrowed funds because deposit insurance often has been
administered in a way that it covers all bank liabilities.
As a
consequence, banks (and of course, thrifts as well) need less capital in
order to attract deposits and other funding at given interest rates.
Capital regulation
How does capital regulation fit in? One way of thinking about capital
regulation is that it attempts to redress the downward bias in capital
caused by the existence of deposit insurance.
In other words, it seeks to
"rewire" the incentive system by bolstering the financial stake of bank
capital holders.
It starts with the principle that any losses that might
occur in banking must be borne by market participants.
Which market participants are candidates? One possible group would be
depositors.
However, I think it is safe to say that federal insurance of
deposits of under $100,000 will not be abandoned, although some observers
have suggested lowering the $100,000 limit. What about deposits of over
$100,000? There is some evidence that rates on CDs of over $100,000
denomination are responsive to bank leverage, particularly if leverage gets
precariously high.
However, large-denomination bank CDs generally are
short-term obligations, and holders of large CDs usually expect to have a
chance to withdraw funds before a bank really gets into trouble and is
closed.
Therefore, holders of large deposits that are fairly liquid are
not likely to view themselves as being completely at risk, even if the FDIC
were to follow closure policies that protected only deposits of $100,000 or
less.
This leaves long-term debt liabilities and equity, both of which are
included in regulatory capital.
Speaking broadly, we have two kinds of
capital: primary capital and total capital.
Shortly, I will mention some
possible changes in the definition of regulatory capital.
But for now,
primary capital consists mainly of shareholder equity, reserves for loan
losses, and certain permanent or convertible instruments.
Total capital
adds in other long-term debt and preferred stock that have maturity dates.
The rationale for allowing long-term debt to count as capital is
straightforward.
Providers of such debt, if truly at risk, can be
expected to demand higher premiums of issuers that have relatively low
stockholder equity or riskier assets.
In addition, providers of long-term
debt have an interest (protected by contractual covenants) in not allowing
a bank to increase its leverage or asset risk. To be effective, however,
the debt has to be long-term so that debt holders cannot "run" if there are
problems.




-

3

-

With regard to equity, experience suggests that the tendency to "bet
the bank" is more of a problem when institutions have little or no capital.
They have everything to gain and nothing to lose.
However, with a
sufficiently high level of equity capital, excessive risk taking would not
be in the interest of bank stockholders.
With more to lose, any risky
investment will be less attractive to bank stockholders and managers.
With more capital, all else the same, regulators have a better chance
of preventing a bank (or a thrift) from accumulating losses in excess of
true net worth, thereby ensuring that potential losses are borne primarily
by capital holders.
Indeed, by rectifying the problems of a bank or if
necessary closing the institution promptly -- that is, before the market
values of the items included in regulatory capital reached zero --the
insurance funds (and depositors) would be protected and the shareholders
and managers would not stand to gain from excessive risk-taking.
Does capital matter?
What this says is that, for public policy purposes, capital matters.
Yet, regulators often are criticized for being preoccupied with capital.
The argument is that other factors such as earnings and the quality of
management affect the financial well-being of a bank and that liquidity
problems tend to be of more immediate concern to a firm in trouble than is
capital inadequacy.
The response here is that earnings and management both translate into
the strength of a bank's capital position when judged on a market-value
basis.
In fact, financial theory says that the market value of a firm's
equity (that is, its true capital) is nothing more than the present value
of its discounted net earnings out into the future.
Thus, future earnings
problems translate into current capital problems when capital is judged on
a market-value basis.
Similarly, liquidity problems are closely related to (market-value)
capital problems.
In fact, a liquidity crisis is unlikely to arise in the
absence of market concern over the true capital position (that is, the
solvency or market value) of an institution.
Misconceptions on this point
are fostered by the fact that the relation between liquidity and solvency
problems tends to be clouded by the deposit guarantee and closure policies,
which often allow even insolvent institutions to operate and attract funds.
Were it not for the deposit guarantee and the failure of the chartering
agencies to close institutions on time, any institution suspected of being
insolvent (i.e., having a negative markr>+
lue of capital) would have an
immediate liquidity crisis, probably i
form of a run on deposits.
RENEWED EMPHASIS ON CAPITAL
The close connection between deposit guarantees and capital regulation
also is related to the second issue I want to discuss -- the renewed
emphasis on bank capital regulation.
Until fairly recently, the FDIC operated with minimal losses.
FDICinsured banks that got into trouble generally were closed on time, thus
limiting the liability of the FDIC as well as keeping risk-taking in check
by confining losses mostly to ’
.ank capital holders.
However, expenses of
the FDIC rose sharply in tlr * . •ly 1980s, as the number and size of failed




-

4

-

banks jumped and the chartering agencies failed to close institutions on
time. Whereas annual FDIC losses and expenses in the 1970s ranged between
$50 million and $200 million, by 1981 they had jumped to over $800 million
and climbed further to about $2 billion in 1984 and 1985 (Chart 1).
Despite the rise in expenses, stated reserves of the fund still were
growing fairly steadily through 1985, reaching almost $18 billion.
But we
cannot be too complacent, given the uncertainty over possible future claims
stemming from problem agriculture, energy, and LDC loans in portfolios of
troubled banks -- as well as in some portfolios already taken over by the
FDIC.
Certainly, the experience of the thrifts' insuring agency, the
FSLIC, gives fair warning that deposit insurance provided to institutions
that have little or no capital can affect the institutions' behavior and
lead to heavy losses for the insurance fund.
Besides the immediate concern of insurance expenses, there is the
longer-run concern caused by the decline in capital at large banks
throughout the 1970s (Chart 2). My staff has calculated equity ratios for
20 of the very largest U.S. banks and bank holding companies.
On a bookvalue basis, common equity capital at these large organizations averaged
around 6 percent in the late 1960s.
By 1980, this ratio had fallen to
about 4 percent, although subsequently it has risen to over 4^ percent.
It
should be emphasized that these figures are based on common equity.
When
all of the components of regulatory capital are included, the large banks
currently meet the minimum standards for primary and total capital.
The deterioration in the capital positions of the large banks is even
more striking when we use common stock prices to measure equity capital on
a market-value basis.
By this measure, the largest banking organizations
had common equity capital of about ten percent of assets in the late 1960s,
falling to just above three percent by 1980 before rising again to about 4%
percent as of September 1986.
It is interesting to note that for these large banking organizations,
the market value of common equity exceeded the book value until the mid1970s.
(This generally was true also for publicly traded banks and bank
holding companies other than just the largest ones.)
Since the mid-1970s,
however, market value generally has remained below book value.
The
implication here is that reliance on book-value capital may be more risky
now than previously was the case, particularly for some institutions.
For
example, a comparison of the market-value common equity to book-value
equity for a sample of 36 of the largest holding companies shows that
almost on e- h a lf had ratios below one as of September 1986 (Chart 3).
Higher capital requirements
Primarily because of the decline in capital at large banks, several
actions were taken by the bank regulatory agencies to raise capital
standards, resulting in a minimum primary capital-to-asset ratio for all
banks and bank holding companies of 5% percent and total capital ratio of
6 percent.
The rise in book-value capital at large banks over the past few
years that I mentioned earlier generally is a result of these efforts.




-

5

-

Risk-based capital requirements
A more recent development is the serious consideration being given to
a new risk-based capital framework.
Only a week ago, the U.S. banking
agencies submitted for public comment a second proposal for risk-based
capital adequacy guidelines, which supercedes their earlier proposal of
January 1986.
One reason the new plan is notable is that it was developed
jointly with the Bank of England.
While the objective of this
international effort is to establish comparable guidelines for U.S. and
British banks that are active in international banking, the guidelines are
intended to be applied to all banks.
Basic to this international coordination of capital adequacy policies
is a common definition of primary capital.
Under the proposed agreement,
primary capital of U.S. banking organizations would include, as it does
now, common stockholders' equity, general reserves for loan losses, and
outside minority interest in equity of consolidated subsidiaries.
(The
proposal calls for public comment as to whether loan loss reserves should
be deleted from primary capital altogether.)
In addition to the above "base components," primary capital would
include the following elements up to a limit of 50 percent of the base
components less intangible assets:
perpetual preferred stock, long-term
limited-life preferred stock with maturity of 25 years or more, and debt
instruments that represent permanent funds and can absorb losses, including
perpetual debt already approved by the Federal Reserve Board.
(Debt
instruments that currently are included in primary capital, but that do not
meet these conditions, such as certain mandatory convertible securities,
would be gr an df a t h e r e d .)
Like the earlier risk-based capital plan, the new proposal establishes
major risk categories for classes of assets and off-balance sheet
activities.
With the focus on credit risk, the proposed agreement sets up
five risk categories for the purpose of calculating weighted "risk assets,"
against which primary capital would be held.
Each category of balance
sheet items would be multiplied by its appropriate risk category weight (0,
10, 25, 50, or 100 percent) to determine the fraction of the face amount to
be included in "risk assets."
(The earlier proposal had only four risk
classes:
0, 30, 60, and 100 percent.)
For example, under the new
proposal, cash and reserves would receive a zero weight, while 10 percent
of the volume of short-term Treasury securities would be included in risk
assets, 25 percent of long-term Treasury securities, 50 percent of general
obligation municipal securities, and 100 percent of consumer and business
1o a n s .
The treatment of the off-balance sheet items is more involved, as it
requires a two-stage procedure.
The face value of each category of offbalance sheet activity first would be adjusted by a "conversion factor"
according to its perceived risk-equivalence to a comparable balance sheet
asset.
For example, the conversion factor for direct credit substitutes,
such as standby letters of credit backing financial commitments, would be
100 percent because their credit risk is fully equivalent to that of a loan
on the balance sheet.
The conversion factor for loan commitments, on the
other hand, would be 10, 25 or 50 percent, depending on the length of the
agreement.
After applying the conversion factors, the adjusted off-balance




-

6

-

sheet items would then be placed into their appropriate balance sheet risk
classes before determining the risk-adjusted asset base against which
capital is to be held.
After all of these adjustments to balance sheet and off-balance sheet
items are determined, the capital ratio for a bank or bank holding company
would be calculated by dividing the newly defined primary capital by the
adjusted risk assets.
The current proposal does not specify a minimum
standard for primary capital.
However, the agencies have indicated that
the minimum acceptable ratio will be determined later, and likely will be
higher than the current 5% percent.
Also, the Federal Reserve has
indicated that even if risk-based guidelines are adopted, it will retain
the current mi nimum ratios for primary and total capital, at least until it
acquires some experience with the new capital adequacy standards.
Applying different capital standards for different activities is not
a particularly radical concept in the regulatory framework.
In fact, riskbased capital standards have been employed by the Federal Reserve in the
past.
Even now the capital of a bank is supposed to reflect the risk of
the institution.
Nevertheless, risk-adjusted capital is a complex concept,
and some criticisms can be made of the proposals.
For example, they are
based on book-value rather than market-value measures.
Moreover, they do
not take interest-rate risk into account, and they do not treat the risk of
an asset in the context of a bank's overall portfolio, thereby possibly
overlooking potential risk reduction stemming from portfolio
diversi fication.
Perhaps the most common concern expressed regarding differential
capital requirements for individual activities is the possible effect on
the allocation of credit and resources devoted to various financial
activities.
The real issue from the perspective of the banking industry,
however, is how banks as providers of financial services would be affected.
After all, economically justifiable services will be provided by the
market, whe ther or not banks themselves are able to do so.
BANK CAPITAL DILEMMA
This takes us to the heart of the capital dilemma: By raising the
stake of equity holders and long-term debt holders in banking, does capital
regulation (whether in the form of minimum capital standards or risk-based
standards) limit the ability of banks to compete with financial firms not
subject to such strict capital standards.
One test of whether capital standards are too stringent is the extent
to which entry into banking remains attractive relative to other forms of
financial intermediation.
Currently, the use of this test is complicated
by adjustments going on. in banking related to deposit deregulation and by
the effects other regulations such as the restrictions on activities
permissible to banks.
Still, I doubt that capital requirements in banking
up to this point have had an appreciable impact on banks' ability to
compete with domestic nondepository financial institutions.
This judgment gains support if we examine the amount of capital held
by many institutions that compete with banks.
At one extreme, mutual funds
operate with 100 percent equity financing, although this is not a very
fair comparison given the limited functions of mutual funds.
A more useful




-

7

-

comparison is with finance companies that hold consumer and industrial
loans similar to those in bank portfolios.
For finance companies, capitalto-asset ratios generally are higher than for banks.
For the larger
finance companies, the ratios of common equity to assets on a book-value
basis generally are around 10 percent to 15 percent or more, and are even
higher when measured on a market-value basis.
Investment companies, on the other hand, tend to be more levered than
banks.
However, even in this group, some firms have shown ratios of
market-value common equity to assets approaching 8 percent.
Such ratios
compare favorably with those for the larger commercial banking
organizations.
S&Ls and foreign banks
Commercial banks also must compete with foreign banks and thrifts,
which benefit from explicit or implicit government deposit guarantees.
Capital standards for these competitors, however, often are less stringent
than those for U.S. commercial banks.
The agreement between the Bank of
England and the U.S. banking authorities on risk-based capital is an
important first step toward international coordination of capital
standards.
As far as the thrifts are concerned, some progress also has been made
to raise capital standards.
Most recently, the Federal Home Loan Bank
Board has initiated new, higher capital requirements -- now 6 percent of
deposits, up from an earlier requirement of 3 percent , although the Bank
Board does not enforce the subtraction of "goodwill" from capital.
The new
requirement will be phased in over a 6 to 12 year period, although thrifts
will have to meet the full requirement on any net increase in deposits.
CONCLUSION
Capital regulation comes into play because of a public policy concern
over stability in banking and the federal deposit guarantee.
That
guarantee tends to mute the market forces that otherwise could be expected
to balance the need for equity against the cost of financing, through the
use of deposits and other liabilities in banking.
If we are to maintain
the advantages of free enterprise in banking while still insuring deposits,
we must have the proper incentives.
To accomplish this, the stake of
stockholders and debt holders has to be large enough so that they view
themselves as bearing the potential losses in banking, rather than possibly
passing some of the losses to the government insurance agency.
This does not mean that capital standards can be pushed higher and
higher.
Capital requirements that are too strict would affect the ability
of banks to compete with institutions not subject to the same regulations.
As I said earlier, however, it does not appear that we have reached that
point -- nor do we ever want to.
Like it or not, in an environment of deposit guarantees, financial
deregulation and innovation, capital regulation in banking is likely to
grow in prominence.
As banks adjust to this environment, we will continue
to see changes in the administration of capital standards.
Risk-based
capital requirements are but one step.
In time, we also will see more
attention paid to the true- or market-value of bank (and thrift) capital




-

8

-

and less to book-value capital, for it is the market-value of capital that
is relevant to the decisions made by bankers and hence to the risk borne by
the insurance funds.




Chart 1
Millions




FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE FUND

Millions

Chart 2
P e rce n t

COMMON EQUITY TO ASSETS

P e rcen t

11
10

7

6
5

Data are unw eighted averages fo r the ratios of comm on e qu ity to a s s e ts fo r the
tw e n ty la rg e st U.S. banking o rganizations based on a s s e ts as o f S eptem ber 1986.
Data are ye ar end figures e x c e p t fo r 1986 w hich is a third q ua rte r figure.




Chart 3
DISTRIBUTION OF MARKET EQUITY TO BOOK EQUITY RATIOS
Frequency

(September 30, 1986)

nr
>5'

&
Ratio of Market Equity to Book Equity
Data Are Common Equity For A Sample Of 36 Of The Largest U.S. Banking Organizations