View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

POLICY IMPLICATIONS OF A CREDIT CRUNCH
Remarks by Robert P. Forrestal, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
For the Conference on "Credit Crunches—Causes and Cures"
Wellington, New Zealand
August 16, 1991

Good afternoon! I am pleased and honored to be here in Wellington and to have the
opportunity to speak to you about the policy implications of a credit crunch. Obviously, the
policy options central bankers apply to a particular situation will depend on our reading of the
extent and seriousness of the problem and, from a policy perspective, whether there really is a
problem. Thus my remarks today will begin with an overview of the indicators of a credit
crunch.

This is no easy task, as evidenced by the fact that it is difficult to agree on the

definition of a credit crunch. Perhaps that job would be easier if the term itself didn’t carry such
negative connotations. If the choice of wording had been left to economists, it might have been
called a "market rationalization," and perhaps nobody would have reacted. In fact, we might
not be meeting at this conference, lovely as it has been.

My point here is simply that it is not easy to diagnose a credit crunch, and this
uncertainty makes the application of appropriate policy options a profound challenge. This
challenge is further complicated by the intrinsic dilemma we monetary policy makers face: that
of helping the economy through the difficulties of a transition period, but in such a way that our
actions do not weaken the beneficial discipline that the markets bring.

Today, I would like to discuss the policy implications of a credit crunch from this
somewhat philosophical perspective.




I will not neglect the practical realm, however:

My

2
comments will cover measures that have been used in the current situation and some additional
measures I would like to see enacted legislatively. I believe this discussion is all the more
important as we face the possibility of a worldwide credit crunch in years to come. I plan to say
more about this later by way of concluding my remarks.

Leading Indicators of a Credit Crunch
Let me turn first to the topic of indicators. My remarks in this regard-and with respect
to policy options—will focus on the Federal Reserve System and largely on monetary, rather than
on regulatory, policy.

Nonetheless, I will touch briefly on some measures other major

industrialized countries have used. As I mentioned, many of the speakers before me, like the
U.S. business leaders, bankers and academics with whom I have discussed this issue over the last
year or so, find it difficult to agree on the definition of a credit crunch. Interpreting the specific
indicators of an imbalance between credit supply and demand is equally difficult.

I must say, to our credit, that many of us in the Federal Reserve System recognized
several years ago that potential problems were brewing as a result of the excesses in commercial
construction in the United States. Unfortunately, we were like the cardiologist who reminds
patients to cut down on the fat in their diets: no one seems to listen until after the heart attack.
Similarly, many of us at the Fed had warned about the fatness and overbuilding in the real estate
industry. But, sadly, all too few developers and their creditors listened to us. This, of course,
is the basis of the credit crunch we have been facing in the United States.




3
As the crunch itself began to develop, we were less prescient. That was because the
information we had available on which to base our diagnoses was, and continues to be, less
conclusive than we might like. In regard to credit markets, for example, we have statistics on
bank loans made, but a fall in--or deceleration in the growth of—these numbers per se cannot tell
us whether the supply of credit is being constrained or demand has slackened. In addition, we
know that we cannot look only at bank loans as a source of information about credit. We must
look at the credit markets as a whole. We all know that U.S. banks have been losing market
share, thanks to such trends as securitization and bigger corporations’ increased issuance of
commercial paper. So, softness in bank lending need not be a problem, so long as we see credit
growing elsewhere. On the other hand, these other suppliers are not a perfect substitute for
smaller and medium-sized businesses, which do, in fact, contribute mightily to the strength of
the U.S. economy. Firms in this "middle market," as bankers term it, have always had a close
relationship with their banks, because they have had to share so much proprietary information
in order to obtain a loan. Such companies do not have access to the commercial paper market.
Thus, to ascertain whether a credit crunch is taking place, we have to delve beneath the
aggregate statistics on lending.

To get past these problems of interpretation, we solicit anecdotes from many business
contacts, for example. These informal polls can provide insights. Unfortunately, it is very hard
to know how much weight to give them because, by their nature, they are narrow in scope and
speak more to private rather than public policy concerns. We also have a more formal vehicle,
namely, the Fed’s survey of senior loan officers, in which we often ask large banks essentially




4
whether they are tightening credit, loosening it, or holding steady. These surveys can be a good
indicator of how the credit situation is changing from one period to the next on a relative basis.
However, it seems that some healthy skepticism is useful when judging these surveys on an
absolute basis. Responses to surveys often have some bias, and, in the case of these respondents,
their bias is apparently against admitting to their regulatory agency that they have loosened
credit. In other words, they are prone to tell us what they think we want to hear.

Even if all the evidence seems to be pointing toward a tightening of credit, policymakers
must assess the underlying causes before we act. In the midst of reading our indicators and
gathering our intelligence, the Fed must ask whether the information reflects a credit crunch or
a phase of the normal business cycle. This question is easier to answer ex-post rather than exante, particularly because the symptoms are similar. It could be that markets are somehow not
allocating credit efficiently. On the other hand, a weakness in credit growth could well reflect
bankers’ appropriate assessment of risk, given the stage of the business cycle we are in. No
central banker should tell a bank to make a loan that the bank believes is bad.

Another even more basic cause of the current tightness involves the fiscal and monetary
policy mix. In the United States, as in many other industrialized nations, the central bank during
the late 1980s had begun to pursue a more restrictive approach toward monetary and credit
growth. The purpose of this strategy, of course, was to move the economy toward a more
sustainable pace of expansion and to achieve a lasting reduction in inflation. On the fiscal policy
side, however, this move was contemporaneous with the adjustments in tax law changes affecting




5
real estate investment. These laws had been altered in the early 1980s in a way that encouraged
excess building and were reversed with the 1986 Tax Reform Act, which sharply lowered rates
of return to construction. Thus, in gauging the early signs of credit tightness, we could not
avoid viewing the complaints we heard as part of the adjustment process that takes place in an
environment that was both disinflationary and reflective of a shift in fiscal policy.

Policy Options
As you can see, the indicators of a credit crunch pose serious interpretation problems that
are inextricably linked to policy options. But this sort of problem is common to policy makers.
We do not have the advantage of working out our solutions in a sterile laboratory setting where
we can conduct controlled experiments. And we do have a fundamental social mandate toward
action rather than analysis. Borrowing again from my earlier medical analogy of diagnosis and
treatment, we cannot afford to remember only part of the Hippocratic oath -- that of doing no
harm to the patient. At some point, we must take action—whether to correct imbalances when
they seem to have become self-perpetuating or to ease the period of transition.

In the United States, as you heard yesterday, the Fed has taken several actions over the
past 12 months that were intended to soften the impact of our credit crunch. To refresh your
memory, these included several monetary policy moves-open market operations, a change in the
discount rate, and a reduction in reserve requirements. In addition, we took several important
steps on the regulatory side. These were designed to clarify supervisory policies, particularly
in regard to problem loans and concentrations of real estate loans.




6
Other nations have taken different tacks with their tight credit situations. In Japan, the
banking system is closely tied to the stock exchange, because equities make up a large portion
of bank assets. Thus, the recent move by the central bank with the discount rate seemed to be
consistent with the idea that further declines in the Nikkei could adversely affect the credit
markets. The Bank of Japan has also sent a clear signal to bankers that they should not increase
the number of outstanding loans for property, given the concerns about bloated land values. It
has also been reported that some central banks have relied on a certain amount of moral suasion
or "jawboning," encouraging bankers to provide liquidity to borrowing firms that have been
reliable but were encountering liquidity problems.

In certain other countries—such as New Zealand, Australia, and Canada—credit is tight
largely due to a sustained tightening in monetary policy, which was designed to address domestic
inflation and other imbalances. The tightening in credit markets was thus part of the process of
disinflationary adjustment, as in the United States. Unlike the United States, though, these
countries did not face the complication of tax law changes and attendant dislocations in real estate
markets.

Given this nexus between monetary policy and the perceived credit crunch, their

options have been more limited.

As long as they remain committed to the longer run goal of

lowering inflation, the most they can do is to take a slower path toward lowering inflation.

How effective have these policy measures been? With regard to the Fed, it is really too
soon to pass judgment. On one hand, the regulatory clarifications were helpful, I believe, in
several ways. Clearly, their most immediate impact is at the microeconomic level, that is, on




7
the balance sheets of individual banking institutions and those of their customers.

There is no

way to measure how much these helped, but we can take some satisfaction in knowing that we
did what we could to prevent disruptions in the important relationship between banks and small
to medium-sized business. Given what we know about the limited credit options of small firms,
insofar as our actions helped preserve these relationships, they may have helped prevent a
significant loss to the economy. These measures also probably had a beneficial macroeconomic
effect, that of reducing uncertainty in credit markets.

These supervisory measures seem to have dovetailed with our monetary policy moves,
helping to lead us out of the recession into recovery. Certainly, some critics would say we
should have done more, sooner, but one can counter that we might never have entered a
recession were it not for Saddam Hussein. In addition, there are fundamental reasons why our
actions were incremental and marked by considerable restraint. That restraint is grounded in the
basic perspective of central banks and their policy tools, which are more macroeconomic and
long term in nature than those of other economic policy makers. As the central bank, we must
focus on the nation’s economic health, not one sector’s health, in spite of political pressure to
do so. It is not appropriate for us to try to ameliorate the plight of the banking industry--or
small business or agriculture—if this plight reflects the adjustment to a more sustainable pace of
growth and a reduction in inflationary expectations. Neither are we credit allocators. We cannot
urge bankers to help out one industry at the expense of another. Because we serve a public
purpose, we must refrain from interfering with private sector decisions.




8
In addition to keeping our focus on the economy as a whole, we must also try to keep
a longer-term perspective in mind. Indeed, in creating the U.S. central bank with a decentralized
structure and removing it from the political arena, Congress intended to keep the Fed from being
caught up in short-term political considerations. Taking the long-term view may sound like a
passive activity, but those who are known for their vision are far from passive.

Instead,

visionaries take actions now to arrange for better results later and then have the patience to await
the outcome.

In the United States, we are at a watershed point in preparing for a better future, because
the legislature is engaged in debating a number of measures to reform the banking industry. I
would hope that this new regulatory framework will also make credit crunches less likely in the
future, although I have my reservations about some aspects of these proposals. Many good ideas
and some bad ones will wend their way from committee meetings to the full Congress to the
President’s Oval Office. There are three ideas I would like to see incorporated into new banking
legislation or regulation that will help to prevent a credit crunch in the future.

First, we must continue pushing banks to build up their capital, so as to create a bigger
cushion when accidents happen. I acknowledge that, in the short term, banks will have a tough
time accomplishing this, given our still soft economy and banks’ low average profits. Because
banks are finding it expensive to sell stock in the equity markets, some are likely to constrain
their lending to achieve the new balance in the risk-based capital/assets ratios. I know small
business owners won’t like the loan tightness that will ensue and probably last for a while. Our




9
job as central bankers, however, is to support measures that work to make a stronger and safer
financial system and help the overall economy.

A second imperative, as I see it, is to encourage consolidation in the overpopulated
banking system. Our deposit insurance system acts in perverse ways, albeit unintentionally. For
problem banks, as we have seen with savings and loans, the asymmetry of rewards and penalties
encourages management to engage in very risky activities in the hopes of saving a sinking ship.
If the tactic fails, insurance picks up the bill. More generally, though, deposit insurance has
served as a subsidy, attracting too many entrants into the field. The resulting competition has
driven spreads down on average —not just in troubled banks —to levels that are not profitable
and that cannot be sustained in the long run.

A third reform we need is to enable regulators to obtain prompt resolution of troubled
banks. This will reduce risky behavior by banks, because they will fear being closed down.
Ultimately, it will also reduce the costs involved in taking over ailing banks.

If the United States banking system is reformed in these ways, I believe credit crunches
will be less likely in the future. But change, adjustment, and dislocation are an intrinsic part of
market economies. We cannot assume that we will have eliminated this problem completely.
And as we face new situations, the Fed will have to continue our complex balancing act of
progressing toward longer term goals while we also respond to shorter term adjustment problems.




10
Looking Ahead to a Possible Global Credit Crunch
Let (me turn then from today’s policy problems to those of tomorrow. My remarks so
far have been based on the present context we face in the United States, that of a credit squeeze
resulting largely from a swing in the pendulum on standards for real estate loans. The credit
crunches of the future could crop up in forms that have nothing to do with real estate, so we
must not fall into the habits of old generals who are always fighting the last war.

Another kind of credit squeeze that would be even more difficult to identify could well
arise globally. A shortfall in credit worldwide could surface for a variety of reasons. As we
all know, the integration of the financial markets on a global scale is proceeding much faster than
political efforts like GATT to facilitate trade flows. Over the next decade, the changes that have
taken place in Eastern Europe and Latin America could bring these developing nations into the
mainstream of the world economy. Consequently, potential rates of return to investment -- on
an inflation-adjusted basis -- could turn out well above those in the industrialized countries,
where many markets are saturated. In other words, there will be more competition worldwide
for credit. The United States has the additional problem of a relatively low savings rate. This
long-term phenomenon, which makes it difficult for us to finance our investment and credit
needs, was muted during the 1980s, because of the large amount of foreign investment in our
country. In the decade ahead, however, we may not have the luxury of the same amounts of
foreign investment to make up for our own shortfall of savings.

All of this points to a potential imbalance in the supply and demand of credit globally,




11
perhaps not in the next few years, given the extent of changes to be made in these developing
economies, but possibly toward the end of this decade. From a general point of view, I would
hope that we in the industrialized nations would respond by taking the mature attitude that the
richer countries in the world should be happy to see other countries doing better in the global
economy. We should also be preparing ourselves now to coordinate our responses to such a
global credit crunch, which would be more interconnected than the current essentially
coincidental credit crunches in a number of domestic markets.

Because each country has a different mix of fiscal and monetary policy, each would, of
course, have its own responses to this global credit crunch, and coordinating our responses would
not mean homogenizing our fiscal and monetary policies-no more than it did when the G-7
countries addressed their currency alignment problems in the mid-1980s.

In the United States, I believe the main policy response should be in the realm of fiscal
policy. I am certainly not talking about subsidies or restrictions on capital outflows, which,
unfortunately, could be proposed if foreign investment were to diminish drastically in the United
States. If such proposals were put forth, I am sure we at the Fed would try to use moral suasion
to prevent their use. Instead of such a protectionist response, U.S. legislators should use tax and
spending policies to increase the productivity of the country’s resources and, thus, the domestic
rates of return. More might need to be done on behalf of investment in infrastructure and
education, for example. In addition, fiscal policymakers would, I hope, maintain the resolve to
lower the federal budget deficit.




12
But our central bank role should not be limited to a solely educational one. We must bear
in mind how difficult it is to reverse some legislative measures compared with how relatively
easy it is to reverse monetary policy -- should a move turn out to be inappropriate.

As I

mentioned in the context of the current credit crunch, the Fed and other regulators took steps to
facilitate the workout of problem loans to ease the credit tightness in an incremental way. In
contrast, during the early 1980s, thrift institutions were given an artificial subsidy by legislative
decree in the form of net-worth certificates, which boosted their "regulatory capital." We could
see that this got us past the problem in the short run, but it is one of the factors that has left us
with a huge bill for the savings and loan bailouts. That is a long-term effect of legislation that
all Americans would rather be without. For this reason, I believe that bringing monetary tools
into play might be preferable to seeing legislative bodies enact measures that are difficult and
expensive to deal with and that are hard to repeal once they become law. Such actions would
not be caving in to political pressure, as I see it, but a move that serves the overall economy
better in the long run.

Conclusion
This overview of policy options —specific measures and broader principles -- highlights
the complexities of addressing problems like a credit crunch, bringing me to the philosophical
dilemma of monetary authorities I mentioned at the outset. Central banks must balance long­
term, macroeconomic objectives with the need for easing a present economic problem. On the
one hand, if we hold too purely to the long view, our policy will tend to exacerbate the
adjustment problems not only for the banking industry but also for many businesses. On the




13
other hand, to ease their plight might also induce unnecessary inflation and prevent a necessary
market correction. What’s more, we must make this tough decision in a context of uncertainty—
that is, on the basis of elusive economic indicators.

And our decisions are not completely

immune from political pressure.

It would be easier for us to hide behind our macroeconomic views and insist that there
is no credit crunch unless the situation fits our narrow definition. That would mean we would
not take any action and could rationalize our inaction with economic theory. But, in my view,
in the present circumstance, that would be wrong. As policy-making bodies, central banks
bridge the ideal world of economists, who theorize using stylized models, and the real world of
business people, who deal in the practical realm. Economists are good at explaining how things
work and the dynamics involved, but they cannot take into account political considerations —not
only of issues themselves but also of time schedules for reform.

Central bankers are the ones who make the hard choices in policy that may not be a
perfect —or swift — solution, but will at least keep us moving in the right direction. We know
what our goals are, but we are not starting from zero or even the best place, as theoreticians do.
Thus, we must from time to time make decisions that seem suboptimal or second-best —as when
credit crunches occur or when we have to accept slower progress on inflation than we might like,
because society and its political leaders find more rapid adjustment too painful to bear. But in
exercising this flexibility, we also demonstrate that we are a product of society and, therefore,
ultimately accountable to it.