View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F o r release on deli v e r y
Wednesday, October 24, 1973
10:30 a.m. M.S.T. (1:30 p.m. E.D.T.)




LESSONS F R O M CREDIT RES T R A I N T

Remarks by
Robert C. Holland
Member, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System

before the

59th Annual Fall Conference of
T he Robert Morris Associates
Phoenix, Arizona

October 24, 1973

I a m very glad to be here and to be a part of your
conference.

I say so partly because, as a Ro b e r t Mor r i s a l u m n u s

myself, it is p l e a s a n t to be back rubbing elbows w i t h lending
officers and hea r i n g stories of the latest additions to the legends
of fabulous loans.

I a m glad, too, to be able to p a y my resp e c t s

to your outgoing President, who has been a close pe r s o n a l friend
of mine since the days he and I first began to learn about such
things as the p r i m e rate.
But I a m also glad to join you in d i s c u s s i o n for another
reason.

All of us here have been living through another episode

of painful credit restraint, and it behooves us to help e a c h other
learn the most we can from that experience.
been "just another" per i o d of tight money.

Indeed, this has not
It has had its own

p e culiarities a n d distinctions, the most obvious of w h i c h is that
it generated histo r i c highs in most interest rates, p u s h i n g them to
levels that w o u l d have been unthinkable only a few years ago.
In recent weeks, of course, some rates have m o v e d ba c k
down somewhat.

I believe a p e r s o n w o u l d be both rash and premature,

however, to regard that movement as a sure harbinger of a swel l i n g
flood of easy credit to follow.

What can be concluded, I think,

is that w e are far enough through the current interlude of credit
restraint to dr a w some instructive lessons from its course.




-

2

-

W h y did interest rates climb so high?
forces s e e m to have been at work.

Thr e e fundamental

First and foremost, we have an

e x t r a ordinarily strong inflation on our hands.

It expanded credit

demands markedly, and its erosion of the value of the dollar led
borrowers, savers, and investors alike to add an inflationary
p r e m i u m to the interest rates at whi c h they were w i l l i n g to do
business.

The stronger the inflationary outlook, the bigger that

p r e m i u m became, and the higher interest rates escalated.
Second, in the struggle of governmental policies to hold
down that inflation, a disproportionate share of the burden has
b een left to monetary policy.

Fiscal policy, instead of reining

in demands in timely fashion, in fact prod u c e d inflation-fueling
deficits during the formative stages of the boom.

Price and wage

controls, while slowing up some of the symptomatic w a ge-price
spiral, have done little to correct the causative excesses of demands
over supplies, and sometimes these controls have b e e n downright
counterproductive in their side effects.

In the end, the bulk of

the task of squeezing out excess demand has once a g a i n been left
to m o n e t a r y restraint.

Given one of the biggest p e acetime inflationary

excesses in our history, it should be no wonder that the countering
credit restraint has had to go to extreme lengths.
But there has bee n a third force pe r v a s i v e l y at w o r k
increasing the size of interest rate swings.




This is the tendency




-

3

-

for a growing share of credit restraint to be a c h i e v e d via price
deterrents - higher interest rates - w i t h a d e c r e a s i n g share being
e f f e c t u a t e d by

nonprice

restraints on credit a v a ilability -

e.g., rationing, loan ceilings and the like.

Part l y this reflects

en h a n c e d governmental efforts to cushion sectors hardest hit by
credit restraint - par ticularly housing - by bo r r o w i n g in the
central money markets and channeling the funds directly or indirectly
to users.

Partly this reflects a continuing secular improvement in

pr i v a t e institutions and marketing practices, freeing up old
financial bottlenecks and inhibiting conventions an d increasing the
general fluidity of supplies of and demands for credit.
Finally, this rate behavior also reflects a deliberate
change of policy emphasis by the Federal Reserve.

In the previous

cycle of tight money, the Fed supplemented its general monetary
restraint by various devices to hold down bank credit availability
dire c t l y - most importantly, by holding interest rate ceilings on
big CD's well below the rates on competing market instruments.
Circumventions of that approach developed quickly, both inside the
banking system and outside.

This time the Federal Reserve suspended

rate ceilings on big CD's entirely, and adjusted upwa r d ceilings on
consumer-size time and savings deposits.

These actions were

designed to enable institutions to better compete w i t h the marketplace
for funds, wi t h i n the limits of their earning capacity and to the

-

4

-

extent called for in their own business judgment.

T h e reafter, w h e n

big CD's seemed to bulge large this spring and summer, f i nancing an
u nduly sharp loan expansion, the Federal R e serve dealt w i t h this
development not by reimposing relatively low rate ceilings, but by
introducing higher reserve requirements on increases in large CD's,
thereby absor b i n g reserves and increasing the internal cost of funds
to banks.

This w a s market-type deterrence, and I think it w o r k e d

reasonably well.

To be sure, the course of events this time has not

be e n entirely smooth--witness the bumpy experience w i t h the 4-year
time certificate--but on balance the contrast w i t h other recent
periods of restraint - both here and ab r o a d - is a marked one.
I regard this tendency toward a greater dependence u p o n
p r i c e as against nonprice rationing in credit restraint to be
desirable on balance.

It seems to me to hold the p r o m i s e of

wo r k i n g both more fairly and more efficiently over the long run and this should apply whether you are m o netarist or n o n m o netarist
in your monetary theory. But w h ether or not you agree it is desirable,
I w o u l d argue that it is inevitable:

the evolution of m a r k e t forces

is in this direction, powered by attractive incentives generated by
our essentially p r ivate enterprise system.

Like it or not, I

believe you and I have to adapt to this trend.
If it is true that we face a future w i t h r e l a t i v e l y large
interest rate fluctuations, you may be tempted to ask, "How h i g h




-

5

-

will interest rates g o ? 11 There is a brief and simple answer high enough to make some borrowers flinch.

To p e r f o r m their

stabilizing function in time of inflation, interest rates will need
to go high enough so that some borrowers are led to defer spending
in order to avoid pay i n g those rates.

It could be that the interest

burden will exceed their capacity to pay; it could be that the high
rates will simply irritate them beyond their poi n t of tolerance, or
it could be that rates will seem so high relative to w h e r e they
might fall w i t h i n a few months that it will prove a good business
gamble to wait.

W h a tever the reasons, some discouragement of

borrowing is necessary.
W h a t are the implications of all this for bank lending
policies?

I w o u l d not presume to give you a definitive list, but

several logical consequences seem quite clear to me.

For one thing,

banks and other lending institutions can best transmit such m o n etary
restraint by avoiding arrangements w i t h customers w h i c h insulate
them from higher costs on new borrowings in times of tight money.
This is p a r t icularly true w i t h respect to cyclical borrowers - those
whose credit demands bulge most in a boom - and pro m i n e n t a m o n g these
are a variety of larger businesses.
W e must tread cautiously here in d i scussing lending rates,
in order not to run afoul of the anti-trust statutes or the Committee
on Interest and Dividends.




But I want to p o int out to you that w h e n




-

6

-

the Committee came up w i t h its so-called "dual p r i m e rate" concept,
it wa s effectively furthering the principle I have just referred
to, insofar as that could be done w i t h i n the constraints of a broadscale p r o g r a m of wage and price controls.

Under that concept, the

large-business prime rate was allowed to evolve toward a rate
floating up and down w i t h short-term money m a rket rates - and the
p r e p o n d e r a n c e of larger cyclical borrowers from banks seem to be
covered by that loan pricing policy.
Looking back on this experience, I b e l ieve a fair observer
w o u l d have to say that the "dual prime rate" ap p r o a c h has w o r k e d
r e asonably well, as controls go.

If so, an important reason is

that it was in good part simply an extension and formalization of
a p r i c i n g tendency already extant w i t h i n the ban k i n g community namely, distinguishing between big national and smaller local
b usi n e s s customers in adjusting lending rate charges.

Some of the

m e m bers of your organization helped the Committee on Interest and
D i vidends to a better understanding of this fact, and I think your
customers, your shareholders, and your communities are better off
as a result.
Another lending policy that deserves r e v i e w is that w i t h
respect to bank loan commitments.

Banks maki n g commitments are

p r o m i s i n g assured future a v a i l ability of funds to their customers,
and recent developments are suggesting changes in bot h the range




-

7

-

of costs w h i c h banks might face in bidding for the promised funds
and in their ability to garner them.

The flat banker statement

that, ’
W e ' l l pay whatever it takes to raise the money to cover our
c o m m i t m e n t s , 11 has a ringing sound, but it can bet o k e n a simplistic
p o licy that is very expensive both for the bank a n d for the
c ommunity at large.

To encourage more careful ba n k plan n i n g for

how big a volume of commitments to make and how to balance bank
r esources and cost-carrying ability accordingly, all three of the
Federal bank supervisory authorities last spring directed letters
on this subject to large banks under their jurisdiction, and asked
their examiners to check the commitment policies of each bank they
go into.
A corollary commitment practice w o r t h y of further scrutiny
is its pricing.

Commitment fees can be thought of as a kind of

insurance p r emium charged borrowers who are thus insured access to
bank funds.

But to the outsider, commitment fee-setting appears

d ominated more by convention than by careful

cost-benefit analysis.

In particular, those fees do not appear adjustable to compensate
for the risks of sharply higher bank costs that flow from the kind
of cyclical fluctuations in money market interest rates and line
take-downs that we have been experiencing recently.
The kind of credit squeeze we have been living through
always creates incentives for banks to find ways to lighten or




8

-

-

avoid some of the pressures on them.

Sometimes this p r o d u c e s

banking innovations that are useful and sound, and that b e come a
par t of ongoing b a n k i n g behavior.

But o c c a s ionally there emerge

not-so-sound devices, whose advantages to either the b a n k or the
borrower are short-lived--or even illusory-~and w h i c h are antagonistic
to the long-run interest of banking and the public at large.
There is one practice developing around the c o u ntry these
days that I a m a f r a i d belongs in this latter category.

I refer to

banks issuing letters of credit to businesses that use them to
support their own notes sold in the mark e t to raise m o ney e i ther for
long-term i n v estment or for general s h o r t-term w o r k i n g capital.
These are sometimes sold under the label of "documented d i s c o u n t
notes.11 So used, these letters of credit function v i r t u a l l y as a
guaranty, and therefore they are of questionable legality in some
jurisdictions.

A p a r t from their legal status, such letters of

credit are o f t e n t i m e s not backed by adequate credit analysis nor
constrained by either regulatory or management limj ts of the type
applied to conventional loans.

W h e n that happens, they impose

credit and l i q uidity risks upon the bank that - if reali z e d - can
be very dispropor t i o n a t e to the b a n k fs w i l l i n g n e s s and a b i l i t y to
bear them.
Furthermore, this kind of use of letters of credit is
subversive of monet a r y policy, since it conveys the e q u i v a l e n t of

-

9

-

b ank credit outside the present scope of reserve requirements and
other deposit regulations, yet in a form that is cushioned by the
bank's name from the full rigors of competition in the open market
for funds.

All told, this type of use of letters of credit - much

different in safety and in purpose from the typical letter of credit
- strikes me as being p o t entially unsound and contrary to the purposes
of monetary policy.

Bank supervisory authorities are concerned with

this development, and if bank managements themselves cannot deal
w i t h the undesirable aspects of this credit use, the supervisors
m a y have to do so.
M u c h of this speech has dwelt upon the effects of interest
rates fluctuating upward to relatively high levels.

That is simple

realism; we are currently in such a high-interest-rate phase.

But

if we are able to lick this stubborn p r o b l e m of inflation, the other
influences I mentioned should wor k just as well to make interest
rates fluctuate downward for significant spans of time.
Moreover, this environment of sharply fluctuating interest
rates is not necessarily any bonanza for bank profits.

Increasing

gross revenues from more loans at higher rates can easily be offset
by investment p o r t folio losses and increased payments to attract




and hold time and savings deposits.

Indeed, how best to manage the

raising of ba n k funds under circumstances of w i d e l y varying interest
rates can be the subject of conferences in its own right.

-

10

-

Insofar as bank lending policies are concerned, let me
conclude by pointing out that monetary policy depends upon them to
spread i-s effects efficiently and rViirly among bank customers.
How far monetary policy can go, and how successful it can be in
serving its varied objectives, rests in important degree on what
transpires across the desks of your lending officers.

I hope that

they and we all can draw the kind of object lessons from our latest
experiences that will help us to make our next round of banking
decisions better than ever.