View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m.
August 2, 1995

TESTIMONY OF

RICKI HELFER, CHAIRMAN
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION

ON

THE CONDITION OF THE SAIF AND RELATED ISSUES

BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND CONSUMER CREDIT
COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES
U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES




10:00 A.M.
AUGUST 2, 1995
ROOM 2128, RAYBURN HOUSE OFFICE BUILDING

Madam Chairman and members of the Subcommittee: X am here
today to describe the difficulties facing the Savings Association
Insurance Fund (the SAIF), and to discuss recommendations for
resolving those difficulties.

These recommendations reflect

discussions and analyses by the Department of the Treasury, the
Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS), and the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (FDIC).

The FDIC has responsibility for two deposit insurance funds:
the SAIF and the Bank Insurance Fund (the BIF).

The Financial

Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act of 1989
(FIRREA) created the SAIF to replace the defunct Federal Savings
and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC), which had become
insolvent as the result of the savings and loan failures of the
1980s.

The law provided the SAIF with no funds at its inception.

For a variety of reasons, the mechanisms established to fund, or
capitalize, the SAIF have not enabled it to reach the target
minimum reserve ratio of 1.25 percent of insured deposits set by
Congress in FIRREA.

A number of other factors compound the problem of the SAIF's
inadequate capitalization.

This testimony describes each of the

SAIF's difficulties, shows how they are interrelated, and argues
that they require Congressional action.
the SAIF are real and substantial.

The difficulties facing

They can only be addressed

comprehensively through Congressional action.




2

This testimony is divided into four parts.
summarizes the SAIF's difficulties.

The first

The second discusses the

possible consequence of these difficulties —

an insolvent SAIF.

The third presents an overview of funding sources for dealing
with the SAIF's difficulties.

The fourth and final portion of

the testimony describes recommendations for resolving the
difficulties.

THE SAIF'S DIFFICULTIES

Three problems are at the heart of the SAIF's difficulties.
First, the SAIF is grossly undercapitalized.

Second, a sizable

portion of the SAIF's ongoing assessments is diverted to meet
interest payments on obligations of the Financing Corporation
(FICO).

Third, on July 1 the SAIF assumed responsibility from

the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) for paying the costs
arising from any new failures of thrift institutions.

These

three problems are exacerbated by several additional factors:
the shrinkage since the SAIF was created in 1989 in both the SAIF
assessment base and the portion available to provide assessment
income for the FICO obligation; the incentives that the
forthcoming BIF-SAIF premium disparity will provide for further
shrinkage in the SAIF assessment base, primarily through the
migration of deposits; and the difficulty of obtaining access to
funds Congress provided as emergency backup for the SAIF.




3
Undercapitalization

The foremost problem confronting the SAIF is that it is
grossly undercapitalized, a particular concern to the FDIC, which
oversees the deposit insurance funds.

At the end of the first

quarter of 1995, the SAIF had a balance of $2.2 billion, or only
0.31 percent of insured deposits.

The balance was less than

seven percent of the assets of SAIF-insured ••problem”
institutions.

At the current pace, and under reasonably

optimistic assumptions, the SAIF is unlikely to reach the minimum
reserve ratio of 1.25 percent until the year 2002.

In contrast, the $23.2 billion BIF balance at the end of the
first quarter was 1.22 percent of BIF-insured deposits and 70
percent of the assets of BIF-insured ••problem” institutions..

The

BIF probably reached the 1.25 minimum reserve ratio during the
second quarter of this year, although the FDIC cannot confirm
this fact until the Call Reports for the second quarter have been
received and analyzed.

The FICO and Other Diversions

A principal reason the SAIF is undercapitalized is that SAIF
assessments have been diverted to purposes other than building
the fund.

This problem was described in detail in a recent

General Accounting Office report.




In short, since 1989, $7.4

4
billion —

approximately three-quarters of SAIF assessments —

have been diverted from the SAIF to pay off obligations arising
from the government's efforts to handle the thrift failures of
the 1980s.

The Resolution Funding Corporation (REFCORP) received

$1.1 billion.

The Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation

Resolution Fund (FRF) received $2 billion.
$4.3 billion.

The FICO has received

Without these diversions, the SAIF would have

reached its designated reserve ratio of 1.25 percent last year,
prior to the BIF.

Only the FICO obligation remains, but under current law it
has an annual call of up to the first $793 million in SAIF
assessments until the year 2017, with decreasing calls for two
additional years thereafter.

In 1995, the FICO draw is expected

to amount to approximately 45 percent of all SAIF assessments.

Congress established the FICO in the Competitive Equality
Banking Act of 1987 (CEBA) in a vain attempt to recapitalize the
FSLIC.

Using $680 million in capital from the Federal Home Loan

Banks, the FICO purchased zero—coupon U.S. Treasury securities.
These securities in turn served as collateral for the issuance of
30-year interest-bearing debt obligations by the FICO.

The

proceeds from these obligations were channeled by the FICO to the
FSLIC.

From 1987 to 1989, the FICO issued approximately $8.2

billion in bonds.

When these bonds mature, the principal values,

or face amounts, will be paid with the proceeds of the




5
simultaneously maturing zero-coupon Treasury securities.

No FICO

bonds were issued after 1989, and the FICO's issuing authority
was terminated in 1991.

The obligation of SAIF-insured institutions to the FICO
involves the interest on the FICO bonds.

Congress in CEBA made

FSLIC-insured institutions responsible for the annual interest
payments on the FICO bonds.

When the FSLIC was abolished,

following its failure, and replaced with the SAIF in FIRREA,
SAIF-insured savings associations were given the obligation of
FSLIC-insured institutions for the FICO interest payments.
Attempts to capitalize the SAIF against the drain of the FICO
interest payments can be likened to trying to fill a bucket with
a hole in it.

Assumption of Responsibility for Thrift Failures

On July 1, 1995, the SAIF's undercapitalized condition
became a matter of significant, continuing concern.

On that

date, the SAIF assumed responsibility from the RTC for resolving
all new failures of SAIF-insured thrifts.

One large or several

sizable thrift failures could quickly deplete the $2.2 billion
balance in the fund.

While the FDIC is not currently predicting

such failures, they are possible.

The possibility is enhanced by

the portfolio concentration of SAIF-member institutions in
housing—related assets and the concentration of overall exposure




6

in California, a state that has experienced significant
volatility in real estate values.

The SAIF/s Shrinkage

The assumption at the time of the SAIF's creation in 1989 by
FIRREA was that the SAIF assessment base —
insured deposits —

would grow.

primarily SAIF-

The estimate by the

Administration and the Congressional Budget Office was that
thrift deposit growth would be six to seven percent annually.
That growth has not occurred.

Instead, SAIF deposits have

declined every full year since the fund's creation.
1989, SAIF deposits were $950 billion.
deposits were $733 billion.

At year-end

On March 31, 1995, SAIF

At the current average assessment

rate, a SAIF assessment base of $328 billion is necessary_to
generate sufficient assessment income to meet the FICO interest
obligation.

Although SAIF deposits grew slightly in the last quarter of
1994 and the first quarter of 1995, by 0.6 percent and 1.6
percent respectively, there is no indication that the growth
constitutes a permanent reversal of the long-term downward trend.
The growth can very likely be traced to efforts by thrifts to
seek lower—cost funding sources.

For thrifts, insured deposits

during the period were a low-cost source of funds because higher
return options for depositors were limited.




A shift in the

7
interest-rate environment could quickly result in the evaporation
of the growth SAIF-insured deposits experienced over the last two
quarters.

In addition, some SAIF members may have decided to

leave insured deposits in the SAIF while waiting to see whether
legislative solutions to the problems of the SAIF were possible.
If no solutions are found, a return to a shrinking SAIF
assessment base could come quickly.

A further problem concerning a shrinking SAIF is that under
current law a portion of SAIF assessments are not available for
the FICO interest payments.

The SAIF assessments unavailable for

the FICO interest payments are those from so-called Oakar and
Sasser banks.

An Oakar bank is a BIF-member bank that has

acquired SAIF—insured deposits and pays deposit insurance
premiums to both the BIF and the SAIF.

A Sasser institution is a

commercial bank or state savings bank that has changed its
charter from a savings association to a bank but remains a SAIF
member.

SAIF assessments from Oakar and Sasser institutions are
t

unavailable for the FICO obligation because under the law only
assessments from insured institutions that are both savings
associations and SAIF members may be used for the FICO interest
payments.

The portion of SAIF assessments from Oakar and Sasser
institutions, and consequently the portion of SAIF assessments
unavailable for the FICO obligation, has been growing.




At year-

8

end 1992, Oakar and Sasser institutions held 14 percent of SAIFassessable deposits? at year-end 1993, the proportion was 25
percent; and on March 31 of this year, it was 34 percent.

As of the end of March, the portion of the SAIF assessment
base available for the FICO payments —

that is, the portion of

the base remaining after the SAIF deposits of Oakar and Sasser
institutions are subtracted —

totalled $478 billion. This leaves

a ••cushion" of $150 billion above the assessment base of $328
billion that is needed at the current average assessment rate to
generate sufficient assessment income to meet the FICO interest
obligation.
.1992.

The cushion is only half of what it was at year-end

Continued shrinkage in the cushion —

because of continued

shrinkage in the overall SAIF assessment base, continued growth
in the Oakar and Sasser portions of the base, or some combination
of the two —

could result in a shortfall in assessment revenues

to meet the FICO interest obligation well before the year 2000.

BIF—SAIF Premium Disparity

A key additional factor complicating the SAIF's predicament
is the forthcoming assessment disparity between SAIF-insured and
BIF-insured institutions, and the market responses.
disparity stems from current statutory requirements.

The
Insurance

premiums for the BIF and the SAIF must be set independently.
When an insurance fund reaches its designated reserve ratio of




9
1.25 percent of insured deposits, the FDIC's mandate, absent a
factual basis for a higher designated reserve ratio, is to set
assessments to maintain the fund at that target ratio.
Therefore, the arrival of the BIF at the designated reserve ratio
requires that BIF assessment rates be substantially reduced.

In January of this year, the FDIC issued a proposal to lower
assessment rates for all but the riskiest BIF members when the
fund attains the designated reserve ratio.

Because the SAIF is

significantly undercapitalized, the FDIC proposed that assessment
rates for SAIF members remain at current levels.

The proposals

would result in SAIF members paying an average assessment rate
approximately 20 basis points higher than BIF members.

The

average assessment rate for SAIF members would be 24 basis
points, or 24 cents per $100 of assessable deposits; the average
assessment rate for BIF members would be 4.5 basis points, or 4.5
cents per $100 of assessable deposits.

When it takes final

action in the near future, the FDIC may not adopt this exact
proposal, but if it does not, under current law something similar
would be required because of the expected recapitalization of the
BIF.

Given the current size of the SAIF's assessment base, the
FICO obligation would constitute approximately 11 basis points of
the proposed premium differential.

If the assessment base of the

SAIF were to shrink, the size of the differential attributable to




10

the FICO obligation would increase.

Even when the SAIF reaches

the capitalization level, the responsibility for the FICO
interest payment would result in a BIF—SAIF premium disparity
until the year 2019.

The potential premium differential between BIF members and
SAIF members could adversely affect SAIF members in a number of
ways, including increasing the cost of remaining competitive,
impairing the ability to generate capital internally or
externally, and leading to higher rates of failure for thrift
institutions that compensate for the differential in unsafe or
unsound ways.

Most important from the standpoint of the SAIF,

however, a premium differential would create a powerful incentive
for SAIF members to minimize exposure to the higher SAIF rates.
A sufficiently heavy response to this incentive could reduce the
SAIF assessment base below the level necessary to provide
adequate assessment revenue to meet the FICO obligation.

Thus,

the forthcoming BIF-SAIF premium disparity poses the real
possibility of a default on the FICO interest payments.

Deposit Migration

There are two general ways SAIF members can act in response
to the incentive to reduce their exposure to higher SAIF
assessment rates.

First, SAIF members can increase their

reliance on nonassessable funding sources, such as Federal Home




11

Loan Bank advances and reverse repurchase agreements.

The

securitization of real estate lending portfolios can also
decrease the need for assessable deposits.

Second —
SAIF —

and constituting probably the bigger threat to the

members of the SAIF can pursue a deposit migration

strategy.

An FDIC analysis of the immediacy of the problems

confronting the SAIF is attached as Attachment A.

The analysis

includes a discussion of the potential for and impediments to
deposit migration from the SAIF.

Since March 1, a number of

holding companies with SAIF members have applied for de novo bank
charters and federal deposit insurance in the BIF.

Generally,

the proposals seek to establish branch offices of the new BIF
member in existing branch offices of the SAIF—member subsidiary.
Customers could then be encouraged through various incentives to
shift deposits from the SAIF-member subsidiary to the newly
chartered BIF-member.

Another deposit migration strategy is open to holding
companies that already have both BIF-member and SAIF-member
subsidiaries.

One such organization has applied for shared

branch locations.

Similarly, a thrift holding company could

acquire an existing BIF-member.

Finally, transfers of deposits

could be accomplished through agency relationships, as permitted
under the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency
Act of 1994.




Under the provisions of that Act, shared branching

12

arrangements between BIF and SAIF affiliates would not be
necessary because offices of SAIF-member thrifts could accept
deposits "as agent" for BIF-member affiliates.

To date, the applications for bank charters, deposit
insurance, and shared branch arrangements remain under
consideration by the chartering authorities and the FDIC.
Together, the thrifts involved have SAIF deposits that represent
more than 75 percent of the remaining FICO cushion against
default.

Even if all of these applications are approved, some

obstacles exist to a massive migration of deposits.

Still,

deposit migration due to the incentive provided by a BIF-SAIF
premium disparity is a significant threat to the existing balance
of the SAIF.

Deposit migration would also exacerbate potential structural
problems in the SAIF.

The institutions most likely to migrate

would be the stronger ones.

This would leave the SAIF to be

supported by, and to insure the deposits of, members that are
currently considered higher-risk institutions.
of the SAIF as a loss-spreading mechanism —

The effectiveness

an effectiveness

already less than optimal because of the large exposure of the
thrift industry to the volatile housing .industry —
reduced.

would be

In this regard, it is worth noting that the eight

largest SAIF-insured institutions operate predominantly in
California and hold 18.5 percent of all SAIF-insured deposits.




13
Any deposit migration that increased the SAIF's exposure to a
particular geographic region or accentuated the extent of
concentration among the SAIF's members would not be good for the
fund's financial health.

Banks also might be affected by deposit migration.

For

example, banks might be forced to pay later if the SAIF fails
because the stronger institutions have left it.

Moreover, a

migration of deposits from the SAIF to the BIF could lead to a
dilution of the BIF's reserve ratio and the need for higher BIF
premiums to compensate.

Therefore, for a variety of reasons, deposit migration poses
a number of problems for the SAIF and could ultimately threaten
its soundness.

For members of the SAIF, the specter of years of

high assessment rates attributable to the FICO interest
obligation may well produce a rush to a less expensive insurance
fund.

Backup Funds

When it replaced the FSLIC with the SAIF in 1989, Congress
recognized that the draws on the SAIF by the FRF, the REFCORP,
and the FICO would substantially delay the capitalization of the
fund.

Consequently, FIRREA authorized appropriations of up to

$32 billion to capitalize the SAIF.




An amount not to exceed $16

14
billion was to be in the form of payments of $2 billion annually
through 1999.

The purpose of the annual payments was to

supplement assessment revenue.

An additional $16 billion was

authorized to maintain a statutory minimum net worth through
1999.

Subsequent legislation extended the date for the receipt

of the Treasury payments to 2000.

Despite requests by the FDIC

for the funds authorized to capitalize the SAIF, the SAIF never
received any of the authorized funds.1

The RTC Completion Act of 1993 eliminated the authorized
funds for the SAIF.2

Instead, the Completion Act established a

procedure giving the FDIC possible access to two backup funding
sources for the SAIF: (1) for fiscal years 1994 through 1998, an
1The issue of the SAIF's need for appropriated funds to
reach mandated reserve levels has been recognized by the FDIC
since the creation of the SAIF. It was raised on January 10,
1992, in a letter from William Taylor, Chairman of the FDIC, to
Richard Darman, Director, U.S. Office of Management and Budget,
and it was raised again in a letter, dated February 20, 1992,
from Stanley J. Poling, Director, FDIC Division of Accounting and
Corporate Services, to Jerome H. Powell, Assistant Secretary for
Domestic Finance, U.S. Treasury. More recently, the issue was
addressed at the time Congress was considering the RTC Completion
Act in a letter dated September 23, 1993, from Andrew C. Hove,
Jr., Acting Chairman, to the House and Senate Banking Committee
Chairmen and Ranking Minority Members. See also the Testimony of
Andrew C. Hove, Jr., on "The Condition of the Banking and Thrift
Industries," before the United States Senate Committee on
Banking, Housing and, Urban Affairs, September 22, 1994.
2In his letter dated September 23, 1993, to the House and
Senate Banking Committee Chairmen and Ranking Minority Members,
Acting FDIC Chairman Andrew C. Hove, Jr., cautioned that the
legislation being considered to replace the SAIF funding
authorizations of FIRREA, and that subsequently was approved as
the RTC Completion Act, left significant problems: "[b]oth bills
leave unresolved issues regarding the viability and the future of
the thrift industry and the SAIF."




15
authorization for payments from the Treasury of up to $8 billion?
and (2) during the two years following the RTC's termination on
December 31, 1995, money authorized for the RTC to complete its
work but unspent by that agency.

In order to obtain funds from

either of these sources, however, the FDIC must certify to
Congress that an increase in SAIF premiums could reasonably be
expected to result in greater losses to the government, and that
SAIF members are unable to pay assessments to cover losses
without adversely affecting their ability to raise and maintain
capital or maintain the assessment base.

Such a certification essentially requires a finding that
there are foreseeable losses to the SAIF that will fully deplete
the fund.

Moreover, unlike the funds authorized for the SAIF

under FIRREA but never appropriated, the sources of funds for the
SAIF under the RTC Completion Act cannot be used to capitalize
the SAIF —

that is, to build an insurance reserve.

They are

available only to replenish SAIF losses, leaving to SAIF members
the continuing obligation to pay premiums at a level sufficient
to capitalize the SAIF in the face of losses and debt service on
the FICO bonds.

Summary

In summary, the SAIF is in a troubled state.

It is

significantly undercapitalized and since July 1 has had




16
responsibility for paying the costs of thrift failures.

The

forthcoming insurance premium disparity with the BIF, which is
required by law, is very likely to exacerbate the situation.

A

comprehensive solution to the SAIF's problems is beyond the
authority of the FDIC, and Congressional action is necessary.

If

there is no Congressional action, the continued
undercapitalization of the SAIF is virtually ensured, a default
on FICO interest payments is likely, and the insolvency of the
SAIF is a possibility.

The next section of this testimony

explores the ramifications of an insolvent SAIF and a FICO
interest payment default.

AN INSOLVENT SAIF?

Deposit insurance is a fundamental part of the financial
industry safety net.

As part of the larger safety net, the

deposit insurance system not only protects individual depositors
but serves to buttress the banking and thrift industries during
times of stress by substantially eliminating the incentives for
depositors to engage in runs on banks and thrifts.

Deposit

insurance and the safety net provide security for customers, and
stability for the financial system as a whole.

In 1933, the year the FDIC was created, there were 4,000
bank failures.

In 1934, the first year the FDIC was in

operation, there were nine bank failures.




Deposit insurance

17
provided the stability the banking industry needed to begin the
long road back from the brink of collapse.

In the 1980s and

early 1990s, deposit insurance helped prevent the troubles
encountered by the bank and thrift industries from escalating
into an economy-wide disaster.

Despite failures of a large

number of institutions, the harm was contained.

At one point,

the FDIC borrowed funds for working capital purposes from the
Federal Financing Bank, but the money was repaid with interest.
The balance in the BIF declined, and as a result of an extremely
large reserve for possible bank failures, fell below zero, but
the fund was completely rebuilt.

The rebuilding was due to

insurance premiums paid by banks and to the greatly improved
health of the banking industry, which permitted the reserve for
losses to be reduced.
recapitalization.

No taxpayer money was needed for the BIF's

The banking system not only survived but

emerged renewed and revitalized.

Deposit insurance and the

safety net worked.

the SAIF were allowed to become insolvent, the confidence
Americans have in FDIC insurance as a source of stability for
financial institutions .ould well be undermined, and the
government's commitment to the safety net for the financial
system could be called into question.

The deposit insurance

system and the other components of the financial industry safety
net rest ultimately on confidence —

on the belief that the full

faith and credit of the U.S. Government support the safety net.




18
Public confidence was a major reason that the troubles of the
1980s and early 1990s did not lead to widespread panic and
economic disarray.

That confidence could be damaged if

government is perceived as no longer willing to support one or
more components of the safety net.

Indeed, that confidence could be damaged if government is
perceived as once again pushing a financial problem into the
future in hopes that it will go away.

The government's early,

limited efforts in addressing the savings and loan crisis —

such

efforts as the inadequate $10 billion authorized in 1987 to
recapitalize the FSLIC through the issuance of FICO bonds —
ended up costing much more than a timely solution would have
cost.

Confidence in the government's backing of deposit

insurance and the safety net is reduced if difficult issues are
not fully addressed, and solutions are incomplete.

Experience with underfunded state deposit insurance funds in
Maryland, Ohio, and Rhode Island, and with the underfunded FSLIC,
shows that permitting an insurance fund to continue in an
undercapitalized position is an invitation to much greater
difficulties.

At times in the past, regulators and legislators

have failed, for various reasons, to take prompt action when
isrge

visible institutions insured by a grossly weakened fund

began to falter.

Fear of runs on deposits inhibited action.

Failed institutions were handled in a manner that minimized or




19
deferred cash outlays but ultimately increased costs.

In short,

the failure to take adequate corrective action allowed the
problems to become worse.

Related to the possible insolvency of the SAIF is the
question of what would happen if the FICO bonds go into default.
This is a subject of more direct concern to the Department of the
Treasury, but the effects could be widespread.

Among those

effects could be downward pressure on the prices —
pressure on the interest rates —

and upward

of securities issued by

government-sponsored enterprises such as Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac,
Farmer Mac, and Sallie Mae, which like the FICO are not backed by
the full faith and credit of the United States.

A fall in the

prices of these types of securities would harm the balance sheets
of investors holding them.

Banks, of course, have large

quantities of these securities in their portfolios.

A final but important point concerning the danger of
contagion inherent in the SAIF problem is that only a small
segment of the population distinguishes the SAIF, the BIF, and
the FDIC.

To most, only one acronym, "FDIC," matters.

Indeed,

Congress mandated in 1989 that the SAIF become "FDIC insured"
precisely to ensure confidence in its future.

Insolvency of the

SAIF could be viewed by the public as a problem with FDIC
insurance and with the federal safety net.

In a public hearing

the FDIC held in March, several bankers stated that "FDIC




20

insured" is like a prized brand name to customers, and that the
integrity of the name must be preserved.

SOURCES OF FUNDS

As with many public policy problems, the solution to the
problems of the SAIF begins with money.

Approximately $6.6

billion are needed to capitalize the SAIF —

to raise its balance

to the point where the designated reserve ratio is $1.25 for
every $100 in insured deposits.

Capitalizing the SAIF, however,

would resolve only part of its difficulties.

The forthcoming

BIF—SAIF premium disparity, the incentive this will give to
institutions to abandon the SAIF, and the resultant specter of
default on the FICO interest payments also must be addressed.

This section of the testimony examines the sources of money
to resolve the SAIF's difficulties from a broad perspective.

The

discussion shows that no single source of money is adequate to
alleviate all of the problems.
required.

A combination approach is

Such an approach is described in the succeeding

section.

Before the sources of money are examined, several
considerations are worthy of note.
use of insurance funds.

One involves the appropriate

The use of deposit insurance funds for

purposes other than the protection of deposits can create future




21

problems, as the diversion of SAIF funds from 1989 to the present
should attest.

That diversion led to the current

undercapitalization of the SAIF and the present dilemma.

Another consideration is fairness.

All parties touched by

the SAIF's difficulties can make compelling cases about fairness.
BIF members contend that the banking industry was not responsible
for the savings and loan crisis, and consequently should not have
to contribute financially to the resolution of a problem arising
from the crisis.

SAIF members argue that they should not be held

responsible for costs incurred years ago by thrift institutions
that failed.

Many members of Congress and other protectors of

the public purse argue that public funds should not be tapped
again for the savings and loan clean-up, particularly given the
strong need to balance the federal budget.

Banks and thrift

institutions point to others in the financial system who will
benefit from a resolution of the SAIF's problems.

Credit unions

would benefit from assuring a sound safety net, and governmentsponsored agencies would benefit from preventing a FICO default.

While each of these positions has merit, the fact remains
that solving the SAIF's difficulties requires a financial
sacrifice.

In the final analysis everyone in the financial

system has an interest in ensuring the system's stability.




22

In discussions with members of Congress, certain sources of
possible funding to resolve the SAIF's problems have been
identified more frequently than others, although the choice of
funding alternatives would of course ultimately be at the
discretion of Congress.

These sources of funds for resolving the

SAIF's difficulties are: (1) a special assessment on members of
the SAIF; (2) investment income from the insurance funds; (3)
FDIC insurance assessments themselves; and (4) funds appropriated
for the RTC that may remain unspent at the end of the year when
the RTC sunsets.

A one-time up-front special cash assessment on members of
the SAIF could raise the $6.6 billion needed as of the end of the
first quarter 1995 to capitalize the SAIF.

A full one-time

capitalization would require an assessment of approximately 85 to
90 cents per $100 of assessable deposits in SAIF-insured
institutions.

A possible downside of such a large one-time

assessment could be an increased potential for thrift failures.
Based on year-end 1994 financial reports, a 90-basis-point
assessment would move a very small number of SAIF members with
total -assets of $500 million into the critically undercapitalized
capital category.

Another 103 SAIF members would be downgraded

one notch from current capital categories.

An approach that

excludes the weaker SAIF members from a one-time up-front cash
assessment could help alleviate that difficulty.

A special

assessment to capitalize the SAIF would by itself, however, leave




23
the problem of the FICO interest payment and the resultant long­
term BIF-SAIF premium disparity unresolved.

Investment income of one or both of the insurance funds is a
second possible source of funding.

Various proposals have been

advanced to use investment income of the BIF and the SAIF for the
FICO interest payment.

The SAIF, of course, would have to be

near the level of full capitalization before it would be able to
generate a significant amount of investment income.

The use of investment income from the funds to meet the
interest obligation on the FICO bonds has the advantage of
limiting the precedent for applying insurance money to purposes
other than meeting insurance losses or adding to fund balances.
Nevertheless, because the investment income of a deposit
insurance fund adds to the fund's balance and offsets the need
for future insurance assessments, the difference between
investment income and assessment income as a source of funding is
more one of timing than result.

Over time, the financial impact

on individual institutions would be the same.

In any event, the

use of investment income of the insurance funds for the FICO
interest payment alone would leave the problem of the SAIF's
capitalization unresolved.

A third source of funding is insurance assessments
themselves.




If SAIF assessments were to be the main source of

24
funding for the FICO obligation, a long-term premium disparity
between the BIF and the SAIF would continue until the year 2019.
If there were a fifty-fifty sharing between the funds, the
disparity would be reduced to approximately 4 basis points in the
near term.

The disparity would increase if the shrinkage of the

SAIF continued.

Whether a 4-basis-point or more differential

over 24 years is sufficiently small to forestall deposit
migration from SAIF-insured institutions to BIF-insured
institutions is a matter of uncertainty.

Like the use of investment income of the insurance funds to
meet the FICO obligation, the use of assessment income goes
against, to an extent, the principle of limiting insurance funds
to insurance purposes.

In a broader sense, however, the FICO

obligation, arising as it did from efforts to recapitalize the
FSLIC, is an "insurance purpose."

Moreover, the precedent of

using assessment income for the FICO payment has, unfortunately,
already been established.

Therefore, broadening the sources of

assessment income for the FICO interest payment when the end
result is to ensure the safety of an FDIC-insured fund and the
stability that FDIC deposit protection provides to the financial
system would be more a matter of spreading the burden to all
FDIC-insured institutions than of opening new doors.

Using the

assessment income of the insurance funds for the FICO payment by
itself without complementary action, however, would not address
the problem of the SAIF's capitalization.




25
Another source to be considered is the estimated $10 billion
in appropriated RTC funds that may remain unspent when the RTC
completes its work at the end of this year.

These funds could be

used to address the undercapitalization of the SAIF, or to
defease the FICO bonds by providing a source of funding for
interest payments until 2019, or some combination of the two.
Depending on how much of these funds were so applied, there might
also have to be other funding to cover the remaining FICO burden
in order to prevent deposit migration.

The major problem with use of the unspent RTC funds, or use
of any taxpayer funds, to deal with the SAIF problem is the
impact of public funding on the federal deficit.

Use of unspent

funds authorized for the RTC would not be "revenue neutral.”
Reducing the federal budget deficit is a major priority of both
the legislative and executive branches of the government.

The

balancing of fiscal considerations against the need to address
the SAIF's problems overhangs all possible solutions to these
problems.

RECOMMENDATIONS

After extensive analysis of the relevant issues, the FDIC
strongly supports the proposal developed on an interagency basis
for resolving the problems of the SAIF.

The proposal has three

components to address the immediate, pressing financial problems




26
of the SAIF:

(1) the SAIF would be capitalized through a special

up-front cash assessment on SAIF deposits; (2) the responsibility
for the FICO payments would be spread proportionally over all
FDIC-insured institutions? and (3) the BIF and the SAIF would be
merged as soon as practicable, after a number of additional
issues related to the merger are resolved.

In addition to the

three components of the proposal, the FDIC and the OTS also
recommend making unspent RTC funds available as a kind of
reinsurance policy against extraordinary, unanticipated SAIF
losses to limit the potential future costs to taxpayers from the
existing full faith and credit guarantee of the U.S. Government
that the SAIF enjoys.

An outline of the proposal is attached as

Attachment B.

SAIF Capitalization

A special assessment on SAIF deposits would be used to
capitalize the SAIF immediately.

Institutions with SAIF-

assessable deposits would be required to pay a special assessment
in an amount sufficient to increase the SAIF's reserve ratio to
1.25 percent.

The special assessment would amount to

approximately 85 to 90 basis points, or 85 to 90 cents for every
$100 of assessable deposits.

A special assessment of this

magnitude would produce approximately $6.6 billion, increasing
the SAIF's balance to $8.8 billion and the reserve ratio to 1.25
percent.




The special assessment would be based on SAIF-

27
assessable deposits held as of March 31, 1995, and would be due
on January 1, 1996.

After the SAIF is capitalized, its risk-related assessment
schedule would be similar to the final schedule adopted for the
BIF.

Thereafter, as required by current law, assessments for the

two funds would be set independently and would take account of
losses to each fund separately, except that SAIF premiums would
not be allowed to be lower than BIF premiums until the funds are
merged.

For purposes of setting risk-related assessments for

calendar year 1996, the FDIC would calculate a SAIF-insured
institution's capital before payment of the special assessment
while at the same time taking into account fluctuations to
capital from other causes.

Under the proposal, the FDIC's Board of Directors could
protect the SAIF from losses that could result from imposition of
the special assessment by. exempting a weak institution from the
up-front special assessment if the Board determined that the
exemption would reduce risk to the SAIF.

Any institution

exempted from the special assessment would be required to
continue to pay regular assessments under the current SAIF riskrelated assessment schedule for the next four calendar years
(1996 to 1999).

As weaker institutions pay premiums of 29 to 31

basis points under the current risk-related premium schedules,
this would constitute a total payment of up to 124 basis points




28
per $100 of assessable deposits for the exempted institutions.
That total payment would recognize the cost to the SAIF of the
financial benefit given to the recipients of the deferral from
the special assessment.

FICO Payments

The assessment base for interest payments on the FICO bonds
would be expanded to cover all FDIC-insured institutions, both
members of the SAIF and members of the BIF.

The expansion would

not only add all members of the BIF to the assessment base for
the FICO payments but would also end the current exclusion of
Oakar and Sasser institutions from that base.
for the expansion would be January 1, 1996.

The effective date
The result of the

expansion would be to spread the FICO obligation pro rata over
all FDIC-insured institutions.

At current insured deposit

levels, the costs of this sharing would be 2.5 basis points, or
2.5 cents for every $100 in assessable deposits.

A sharing of

the FICO burden on a pro rata basis among all FDIC-insured
institutions would focus the solution on those institutions that
benefit directly from federal deposit insurance.

An alternative would be to look to other participants in the
financial system to share the FICO burden.

While the proposal is

based in large part on numerous discussions with members of the
Congress on viable approaches to solving the SAIF's problems, the




29
FDIC recognizes that it is ultimately Congress' judgment about
whether to enlist in a solution other participants in the
financial system who will benefit from stabilization of the SAIF
and assurance that the FICO obligation will be repaid.

As a corollary, the FDIC would be authorized to rebate
assessment income to BIF members if circumstances permit.

That

is, if the BIF had reserves exceeding its designated reserve
ratio target, BIF assessment income could be rebated to BIF
members.

From 1950 to 1989, the FDIC had the statutory authority to
make rebates from assessment income, and did so for every year
until 1985.

The rebate authority from 1950 to 1989 only covered

assessment income.

The authority did not extend to the

investment income of the insurance fund.

Because of losses to

the insurance fund, no rebates were made from 1985 to 1989.

The

rebate authority was substantially altered in 1989 in FIRREA,
altered again in 1990 in the Assessment Rate Act, and eliminated
entirely in 1991 in the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Improvement Act.

The elimination occurred because Congress

evidently considered rebate authority obsolete in view of the
FDIC's power to set risk-related premiums to maintain the
designated reserve ratio.

A reduction in assessment rates was

considered sufficient to accomplish the same result as rebates.




30
Experience is showing, however, that the power to reduce
assessment rates is not equivalent in all respects to the power
to make rebates.

The FDIC Board of Directors generally considers

three factors in setting deposit insurance assessments:

(1) the

designated reserve ratio; (2) expected operating expenses,
projections of losses to the insurance fund from the failures of
member institutions, and the effect of assessments on members'
earnings and capital; and (3) the obligation to maintain a riskrelated deposit insurance system.

Taking these factors into

account may lead to a significant buildup in an insurance fund.
To avoid such a buildup, the FDIC Board should have reasonable
discretion to rebate collected assessments, when circumstances
permit.

To promote assessment rate stability and to ensure the
soundness of an insurance fund, the FDIC's authority to set
assessment rates should be clarified to allow explicitly the
balance in the BIF to vary within a reasonable range from the
target designated reserve ratio.

The FDIC could be required

under the current provisions of the law to make frequent
relatively large adjustments in assessment rate schedules,
including at times when insured institutions may be least able to
sustain higher rates.

In an environment of frequent adjustments

in assessment rate schedules, depository institutions would have
difficulty making reliable projections about their costs, and the




31
FDIC during serious economic downturns could be constrained from
charging higher premiums.

Also to promote assessment rate stability, the minimum
average premium required under Section 7(b)(2)(E) of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Act when a deposit insurance fund is
undercapitalized or when the FDIC has borrowings outstanding for
the fund from the Treasury or the Federal Financing Bank should
be reduced from 23 basis points to 8 basis points.

The smaller

minimum would give the FDIC greater flexibility to smooth out or
phase in assessment rate changes, thereby making costs for the
industry less erratic.

Merger of the Funds

The two elements of the proposal discussed thus far would
provide immediate financial stability for the SAIF.

The third

element of the proposal, a merger of the BIF and the SAIF, is a
necessary component of a solution to long-term structural
problems facing the thrift industry, and consequently the
industry's deposit insl.Ince fund.

A sound deposit insurance system requires viable and sound
banking and thrift industries.

The thrift industry would seem to

fall short of that characterization in the longer term.
Encouraged or required by law, the industry concentrates on one




32
sector of the economy, the housing sector, that is particularly
volatile.

The concentration hinders the ability of institutions

to diversify risks and income sources.

Moreover, as noted

ea^lier in this testimony, the industry is concentrated
geographically:

the eight largest SAIF-insured institutions

operate predominantly in California and hold 18.5 percent of all
SAIF-insured deposits.

The FDIC strongly agrees that a merger of the BIF and the
SAIF as soon as practicable is an important component of a
solution to the structural problems of the SAIF and the thrift
industry.

With respect to the immediate financial problems

facing the SAIF, the FDIC believes that while a merger should be
of a solution, it should not be viewed as a substitute
approach to capitalizing the SAIF.

To avoid unfairness to BIF—

insured institutions and to avoid dropping the BIF below the full
recapitalization level, the task of recapitalizing the SAIF
should be a responsibility of the current members of the SAIF.

The FDIC fully supports a merger of the insurance funds as
Parf °f the immediate SAIF solution.

The FDIC supports also a

of the charters, however, the additional issues raised
will take substantial time and effort to resolve.

We can begin

addressing the charter issues now, but it must not delay action
on the interagency proposal to deal with the pressing financial
problems of the SAIF.




33
With respect to the charter question, many issues must be
resolved, such as the different powers permitted for banks and
thrifts.

The powers issue could be addressed by thrifts

accepting a bank charter, which could include a provision
allowing the mutual form of ownership.

In addition to the powers

issue, charter type impacts the Federal Home Loan Bank System, as
the current structure of the System —

capital requirements,

access to advances, allocation among the FHLBanks of the REFCORP
payment —

all hinge on the existence of the current thrift

charter.

Taxation questions, such as what is to become of the
^u^iifi®^ thrift lender classification and the treatment of past
additions to bad debt reserves, will have to be considered also.
Regulatory matters, such as the supervisory responsibilities of
the Office of Thrift Supervision, will need to be examined.

As

the insurer of banks and thrifts, the FDIC will work with the
chartering agencies to assure that the resulting charter provides
for a safe and sound form of institution.

The FDIC favors an approach that addresses these questions
sooner rather than later —

indeed as soon as practicable.

The

Treasury Department is working on a comprehensive approach to
deal with the additional issues and the FDIC expects to be a part
of the effort.

While these charter and other issues are being

addressed, the important goal is assuring that the SAIF will be




34
fully capitalized and its immediate financial problems resolved
as soon as possible.

The other elements of the proposal —

the special assessment

to capitalize SAIF, the spreading of the FICO burden, no rebate
authority for SAIF, and the provision that SAIF premiums could
not go below BIF premiums —

could, under favorable economic

conditions, result in a SAIF balance in excess of the designated
reserve ratio.

If this were to occur, any such excess funds in

the SAIF at the time of the merger should not be rebated but
remain in the merged fund as further protection from future
losses.

In summary, sound policy reasons mandate a merger of the BIF
and the SAIF.

The marketplace has made many of the charter

restrictions that govern the financial industry obsolete, even
economically harmful.

The structural problems of the thrift

industry lead the FDIC to support strongly a merger of the BIF
and the SAIF as soon as practicable.

Unspent RTC Funds

In addition to the three elements of the joint proposal, the
FDIC and the OTS believe a fourth component is necessary.

We

recommend that the unspent RTC funds be made available as a
backstop, or reinsurance policy, for extraordinary, unanticipated




35
SAIF losses until the BIF and the SAIF are merged.

Asking for

taxpayer money, even in a backup role, is not done lightly, but
the need to ensure a comprehensive resolution of the SAIF's
difficulties is imperative.

In 1989 in FIRREA, Congress

authorized appropriations of up to $32 billion in taxpayer funds
to capitalize the SAIF.

Also, those authorizations were

eliminated in the RTC Completion Act.

Currently, the FDIC has

access to taxpayer funds to replenish losses in the SAIF,
provided the FDIC finds that foreseeable losses will fully
deplete the fund.

Most of the savings and loan clean-up has been accomplished.
The undercapitalized SAIF, however, is unfinished business from
the savings and loan crisis in need of immediate attention.
Providing unspent RTC funds in a backup role would be in keeping
with Congress' original intention of providing funds to ensure a
sound SAIF.

It would be only a small step beyond current law,

which provides access to unspent RTC funds and other taxpayer
funds to pay for losses to the government from failed thrifts.

Moreover, the SAIF enjoys the full faith and credit
guarantee of the U.S. Government.

If the SAIF became insolvent,

taxpayer money would be required to compensate insured
depositors.

Authorizing access to unspent RTC money to cover

losses before an insolvency of the SAIF occurs is sound public
policy and could ultimately save taxpayer money.




36

The recommendation of the FDIC and the OTS for the unspent
RTC funds covers extraordinary losses above those currently
projected.

Under our recommendation, if SAIF losses were to

exceed $500 million in any calendar year during the period
beginning on July 1, 1995 —

when the SAIF took over the RTC's

responsibility for resolving failed institutions —

and ending

with the merger of the BIF and the SAIF, unspent RTC funds would
be used to cover the excess.

Thus, the SAIF would cover the

first $500 million in losses during any year, and unspent RTC
funds would cover only any additional losses.

Neither the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) nor the FDIC
currently projects that SAIF losses will reach $500 million in
any year.

The CBO projects losses of $450 million per year.

FDIC projects losses of $270 million per year.

The

It is, of course,

difficult to predict losses more than six months to a year ahead.
Unspent RTC funds would serve as a reinsurance policy against
losses more severe than those now anticipated.

The backup funds

would assure SAIF members that for the near term they would not
be asked to pay yet another special assessment to capitalize the
fund.

This assurance would further minimize the economic

incentive for thrift institutions to shift deposits from the SAIF
to the BIF.




37
CONCLUSION

Congressional action to resolve the difficulties facing the
SAIF is very much needed.

With a balance amounting to only 0.31

percent of insured deposits, the SAIF is grossly
undercapitalized.

This undercapitalized condition is directly

attributable to the fact that since the SAIF's establishment in
1989, approximately 77 percent of assessment revenues from SAIF
members has been statutorily diverted to pay for past losses
related to the savings and loan crisis.

Of the diversions, only

the FICO interest obligation remains, but it has been the
principal diversion —

and will consume 45 percent of the SAIF's

assessment revenue this year.

It will continue to be a drain on

the SAIF until the year 2019.

The SAIF's undercapitalized

condition became more pressing on July 1, 1995, when the fund
assumed the responsibility for paying the costs of thrift
failures.

One large or several sizable thrift failures could

quickly deplete the SAIF's balance.

Additional matters add to the SAIF's difficulties.

Contrary

to expectations when the SAIF was created in 1989, the SAIF
assessment base has decreased significantly.

The portion of the

base available to provide assessment income for the FICO
obligation has also been shrinking.

The forthcoming BIF-SAIF

premium disparity will likely cause further shrinkage in the SAIF
assessment base, primarily through the migration of deposits from




38
SAIF-insured accounts to BIF-insured accounts.

The possibility

of thrift failures and losses to the SAIF is enhanced by the
asset and geographic concentration of SAIF-member institutions.
These concentrations also constitute longer term structural
problems facing the industry.

Finally, revenue and net worth

supplements totalling $32 billion that Congress had authorized
for the SAIF were never appropriated, and funds authorized under
current law to replenish SAIF losses can be made available
essentially only if the FDIC concludes that the insolvency of the
SAIF is likely.

The FDIC believes that the interagency proposal and the
recommendations discussed in this testimony would resolve the
difficulties facing the SAIF.

The approach suggested would

prevent those difficulties from escalating to the point where the
deposit insurance system and the federal government safety net
for the financial industry are threatened.

The recommendations

would result in full capitalization for the SAIF.
provide for that capitalization quickly.
the FICO interest obligation is met.

They would

They would ensure that

They would avoid a crushing

burden to one small sector of the economy.

They would obviate

the necessity under current law of an ongoing significant
disparity in insurance premiums between BIF-member and SAIFmember institutions, and avoid the strong economic incentive for
SAIF members to shift deposits from the SAIF to the BIF, further
weakening the SAIF.




They would provide for a merger of the BIF

39
and the SAIF and an encompassing solution to significant long­
term issues facing the thrift industry.

The FDIC and the OTS would also recommend that Congress
provide access to leftover RTC funds to cover only losses to the
SAIF that significantly exceed those we currently project.

This

reinsurance policy for extraordinary losses would assure the
stability of the SAIF in the near term until the funds are
merged.

In short, the recommendations would resolve the serious
problems facing the SAIF and depository institutions.

Continued

confidence in the deposit insurance system would be assured —
confidence that is necessary for the government safety net to
accomplish its purposes.




ATTACHMENT A

THE IMMEDIACY OF THE
SAVINGS ASSOCIATION INSURANCE FUND PROBLEM

PROBLEMS CONFRONTING THE SAVINGS ASSOCIATION INSURANCE FUND
Despite the general good health of the thrift industry, the Savings Association Insurance
Fund (SAIF) is not in good condition and its prospects are not favorable. The SAIF faces the
following immediate problems.
The SAIF is significantly undercapitalized.
On March 31, 1995, the SAIF had a balance of $2.2 billion, or about 31 cents in
reserves for every $100 in insured deposits. An additional $6.6 billion would have been
required on that date to fully capitalize the SAIF to its designated reserve ratio (DRR) of 1.25
percent of insured deposits. At the current pace, and under reasonably optimistic assumptions,
the SAIF would not reach the DRR until at least the year 2002. However, even a fully
capitalized SAIF would be subject to risks stemming from its size and certain structural
weaknesses in the thrift industry. Relative to the Bank Insurance Fund (BIF), the SAIF has
fewer members and faces greater risk with the failure of any one member. The exposure of the
fund to insured deposits is higher for the SAIF than the BIF; that is, each dollar of SAIF-insured
deposits is backed by $1.34 in member assets, whereas the comparable figure for the BIF is
$2 .20 .
The SAIF also faces risks from geographic and product concentrations of the thrift
industry. In terms of SAIF-insured deposits, the eight largest institutions operate predominantly
in California and hold 18.5 percent of all SAIF-insured deposits.1 While economic conditions
and real-estate markets are beginning to improve in California, the SAIF would have significant
loss exposure in the event of a regional economic downturn on the West Coast. Product
concentration stems from the Qualified Thrift Lender (QTL) test that must be met to realize the
benefits available under a thrift charter. The QTL test requires thrifts generally to maintain 65
percent or more of their assets primarily in loans or investments related to domestic real estate.
Consequently, 49 percent of the assets of SAIF members are concentrated in l-to-4 family
mortgage loans, with another 13 percent in mortgage pass-through securities issued or
guaranteed by government-sponsored enterprises. While these loans and securities generally
involve relatively low credit risk, they can expose institutions to significant interest-rate risk.

’By contrast, the eight largest holders of BIF-insured deposits are located in five different
states and hold 10 percent of all BIF-insured deposits.




1

The SAIF assumed responsibility fo r resolving failed thrifts as o f July 1, 1995.
On July 1st, the SAIF assumed resolution responsibility for failed thrifts from the
Resolution Trust Corporation. Because the SAIF is undercapitalized, the failure of one large
thrift or several medium-size thrifts could render the SAIF insolvent and put the taxpayer at risk.
SAIF assessments contìnue to be diverted to meet FICO interest payments.
Since its inception in 1989, the majority o f SAIF-member assessment revenue was
diverted to pay for Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSOC) losses incurred
before the enactment of the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act of
1989 (F1RREA). These diversions totaled $7.4 billion through March of 1995: $4.3 billion for
the Financing Corporation (FICO), $2 billion for the FSLIC Resolution Fund and $1.1 billion
for the Refinancing Corporation. Without these diversions, the SAIF would have capitalized in
1994. Importantly, a significant portion of SAIF assessment revenue continues to be diverted
to pay the interest on bonds issued by the FICO.
From 1987 to 1989, the FICO issued approximately $8.2 billion in 30-year bonds. The
FICO has an ongoing first claim on up to $793 million of SAIF assessment revenues to meet
interest payments on these bonds through 2019. In 1995, the FICO claim is expected to amount
to approximately 45 percent of current SAIF assessment revenues (11 basis points of the current
23.7 basis point average SAIF assessment rate). The FICO draw on SAIF assessment revenue
will remain as an impediment to the SAIF for 24 years to come.
SAIF assessments that can be used for FICO payments are limited by law to assessments
on insured institutions that are both savings associations and SAIF members; these-institutions
currently account for just two-thirds of the SAIF assessment base. At current assessment rates,
an assessment base of $328 billion is required to generate revenue sufficient to service the FICO
interest payments. On March 31, 1995, the FICO-avallable base stood at $478 billion. The
difference of $150 billion can be thought of as a cushion which protects against a default on the
FICO bonds. Shrinkage In the FICO-avallable assessment base will cause this cushion to
dissipate, and it is now less than half of what it was at year-end 1992.
The remaining third of the SAIF assessment base consists of deposits held by so-called
Oakar and Sasser institutions.2 A change in the law concerning the availability of Oakar and

2Oakar institutions, which are created from the purchase of SAIF-insured deposits by a BIF
member, pay assessments to both the BIF and the SAIF based on the proportion of BIF- and
SAIF-insured deposits held by the institution at the time of purchase. They are BIF members.
Sasser institutions are SAIF members that have switched charter type and primary federal
supervisor without changing insurance fund membership; that is, they are either commercial
banks (state- or federally chartered) or FDIC-supervised state savings banks. They are not
savings associations, (continued)




2

Sasser assessments for FICO interest payments would postpone a FICO problem, but in all
likelihood would not prevent a FICO default. If there were minimal shrinkage in the SAIF
assessment base and current assessment rates were not lowered, the SAIF assessment base might
be sufficient to meet the FICO draw through maturity. However, an ongoing rate differential
between the BIF and the SAIF would make the prospect of minimal shrinkage of the SAIF
assessment base unlikely. Such a rate differential is required under current law once the FDIC
confirms the BIF has recapitalized at the DRR of 1.25 percent of insured deposits. More rapid
shrinkage of the SAIF assessment base, as would occur in the scenarios below, increases the
likelihood of a near-term FICO shortfall.

IMMEDIACY OF THE SAIF PROBLEM
Incentives to reduce reliance on SAIF-insured deposits.
The factors described above have created a situation that provides powerful economic
incentives for those institutions that have SAIF-insured deposits to devise means to minimize
their exposure to the higher assessment rates of the SAIF. SAIF assessments can be avoided in
a variety of ways, including shifting funding to nonassessable liabilities, changing business
strategies to reduce the volume of portfolio investments, and structuring affiliate relationships
to accommodate migration of deposits from the SAIF to the BIF.
As to the incentives that would precipitate such a change in behavior, there are at least
three considerations. First, SAIF assessment rates likely will be about 20 basis points above BIF
rates for the next seven years, until, it is projected, the SAIF may be capitalized, and at least
11 basis points higher thereafter, until the FICO bonds mature in 2017 to 2019. To place these
numbers in perspective, consider the impact that such a rate differential would have had on 1994
thrift financial returns. SAIF members had a return on assets (ROA) of 0.56 percent in 1994
and a return on equity (ROE) of 7.17 percent. A 20-basis point differential could have reduced
net income by as much as 17 percent, dropping the ROA to 0.46 percent and the ROE to 5.93
percent for the year.3 A long-term differential of this magnitude likely would make many thrifts
less competitive in the pricing of loans and deposits, erode earnings and capital and hamper
access to new capital.

(footnote 2 continued) A 1992 FDIC legal opinion determined that FICO assessments
can be made only on savings associations that are SAIF members. This opinion was described
as "reasonable” by the Comptroller General in a letter to the FDIC Board of Directors, dated
May 11, 1992 and recently reconfirmed by the FDIC. See Federal Register 60 (February 6,
1995): 7055-58.
3This assumes that banks would pass their entire assessment savings to borrowers or
depositors, forcing thrifts to set prices accordingly in order to compete. Alternatively, some
thrifts may be able to lessen the impact of a premium differential by reducing other expenses or
raising other revenues.
3




Second, the perceived fragility of the SAIF may mean that the remaining SAIF-insured
institutions not only will have to bear an increasing share of the FICO debt-service burden, but
also fund a larger share of failure costs if national or regional economic conditions deteriorate.
Moreover, to the extent it is the healthiest SAIF-insured institutions that are successful in
reducing their exposure to SAIF, the increased deposit insurance burden could increase failures
materially.
Finally, the recent announcements by several large thrifts of their intention to migrate
SAIF deposits to BlF-insured affiliates call into question the reasonableness of assuming a stable
or increasing SAIF assessment base and raise the specter of the fixed FICO obligation being
serviced by a decreasing number o f institutions and a diminishing assessment base.4 This
situation gives rise to the same incentives that are present in a bank run —if you are first in the
teller line, you redeem your deposits in full; on the other hand, if you are last in line, you may
get nothing. Moreover, if the SAIF assessment base shrinks, the SAIF will become a less
effective loss-spreading mechanism for insurance purposes, raising more significant structural
issues.
In summary, there is little question that the strong economic incentives created by the
present system and the reduction in BIF rates are likely to reduce reliance by thrift institutions
on SAIF-insured deposits. The real questions are how fast this will occur and how much the
SAIF assessment base will be reduced. While legislation could reduce or eliminate some
methods by which this could be accomplished, the financial markets are likely to create
alternative means. In addition to being ineffective, such legislative hurdles may be costly and
disruptive to the marketplace. Moreover, die structural weaknesses of the thrift industry would
be exacerbated by any acceleration in the shrinkage of the industry, leaving fewer thrifts and
deposits across which to spread risk.
Methods to reduce reliance on SAIF-insured deposits.
The following discussion examines several methods that thrifts can pursue to reduce their
reliance on SAIF-insured deposits. While the methods may be illustrative of business decisions
to reduce costs and uncertainty, the consequences of shrinkage in the SAIF assessment base are

4The funding mechanisms for the SAIF were based in part on assumptions that proved to be
overly optimistic about the level of the SAIF assessment base. At the time of FIRREA,
projected annual thrift deposit growth rates of 6 to 7 percent may have seemed conservative
relative to the higher growth rates of the early 1980s. However, for several years following
FIRREA, SAIF deposits actually declined annually 6 to 7 percent. This deposit shrinkage can
be explained by several factors including the runoff in deposits from RTC conservatorships and
other weakened thrifts, a decreased reliance on brokered deposits, and depositor flight from
declining or low interest rates. Higher capital requirements also may have encouraged
downsizing.




4

serious, both for purposes of meeting FTCO debt service obligations and minimizing fundamental
risks to the SAIF.
Increased reliance on nonassessable funding sources.
As part of their efforts to minimize the impact of a rate differential, thrifts could reduce
premium costs by shrinking their SAIF-assessable deposits. Nonassessable liabilities, such as
Federal Home Loan Bank (FHUB) advances and reverse repurchase agreements, could be
substituted for assessable deposits. The concentration of thrift portfolios in loans and
investments related to domestic real estate, which serve as eligible collateral for these products,
is an indicator of the capacity of thrifts to switch from domestic deposits to alternative
nonassessable funding sources. While there is no limit on the amount of FHLB advances a wellcapitalized thrift can receive, some level of deposits must be maintained in order to realize
certain federal income tax benefits. (This is discussed in a later section on the thrift tax bad-debt
reserve.)
Changing business strategies to reduce the volume of portfolio investments.
Funding needs also could be reduced through securitization. Thrifts could reduce their
exposure to SAIF assessments by shrinking their portfolio investments through the securitization
or sale of assets. Under certain economic conditions, the thrift could choose to become a
mortgage bank, eliminating the exposure to SAIF altogether. The costs of such a strategy may
include recapture o f the tax bad-debt reserves, which is discussed below.
Structuring affiliate relationships to accommodate deposit migration from SAIF- to BUn­
insured institutions.
It is possible for thrifts to structure these affiliate relationships in three ways: the
chartering of a de novo B1F member; employing an existing BIF affiliate; and acquiring an
existing BIF member. First, affiliate relationships could be established through the chartering
of a de novo BIF member. Thrifts could apply for charters and deposit insurance to establish
a national bank, a state-chartered commercial bank or, where available, a state-chartered savings
bank. Second, the migration of deposits from the SAIF to the BIF could occur readily if both
a BIF member and a SAIF member already are held within the same holding company. Finally,
thrift holding companies could purchase existing BIF members. Under the latter two options,
chartering and deposit insurance applications would not be necessary, although regulatory
approval would be necessary for an acquisition.5

5In cases where a BIF-member savings bank is acquired by a thrift holding company, the
approval of the Office o f Thrift Supervision (OTS) is required; acquisition of a BIF-member
commercial bank would require approval from the Federal Reserve. Issues involving various
applications related to new charters are discussed below.




5

Generally, these affiliate operations would function in the following manner. With the
cost advantage accorded by the premium differential, the BIF affiliate could offer higher interest
rates on deposits, thereby enticing customers to shift deposits from the SAIF affiliate to the BIF
affiliate. To the extent that it is cost effective to do so, the SAIF affiliate would maintain the
necessary qualifying assets and would fund these with nonassessable liabilities such as advances
from the BIF affiliate or a FHLB. The BIF affiliate would hold the advances to the SAIF
affiliate as its assets; its liabilities would consist primarily of the deposits that had migrated from
the SAIF to the BIF. As an alternative to using the BIF affiliate primarily as a funding source,
the holding company could choose to shift its thrift lending activities to the BIF affiliate.6
The migration of SAIF deposits can be accomplished through transfers between branch
offices, through the use of shared branch offices or through the use of agency relationships.
Shared or tandem operations are created when the BIF-affiliate branch offices are established in
the existing branches of the SAIF affiliate. Transfers of deposits from the SAIF to the BIF also
could be accomplished through agency relationships, as permitted under the Riegle-Neal
Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994. Under the provisions of this Act,
shared branching arrangements between BIF and SAIF affiliates would not be necessary, as
offices of SAIF-member thrifts could accept deposits "as agent" for BIF-member affiliates.
The potential magnitude o f deposit migration.
The potential deposit insurance premium differential between the BIF and the SAIF
triggered a response on the part of a number of SAIF members. A number of SAIF-member
thrift organizations have applied for de novo state or national bank charters and federal deposit
insurance. Generally, the proposals seek to establish branch offices of the de novo BIF member
in existing branch offices of the SAIF-member subsidiary. The parent holding company would
be in a position to create incentives for customers to shift deposits from the SAIF-member
subsidiary to the newly chartered BIF member. In addition, one thrift holding company has filed
applications for shared branches between its existing SAIF and BIF affiliates. There are more
than 100 bank or thrift holding companies that own both SAIF and BIF affiliates that could
establish shared BIF/SAIF office locations, subject to applicable branching restrictions, without
having to apply for de novo charters and deposit insurance.
To date, these applications for bank charters, deposit insurance and shared-branch
arrangements remain under consideration by the chartering authorities and the FDIC. The
applicants have SAIF-assessabl - . osits that represent more than 75 percent of the remaining
FICO cushion against default. Should all these deposits successfully migrate from the SAIF to
the BIF, the potential cost to the BIF would be approximately $1.4 billion, that is, the BIF
would require an additional $1.4 billion to maintain a reserve ratio of 1.25 percent. While there

6With the exception of restrictions on subquality assets, "sister" affiliates, that is, banks or
thrifts held within a single bank holding company structure, are not subject to the interaffiliate
transaction restrictions of Section 23A of the Federal Reserve Act.




6

are considerations discussed below that make it unlikely that a shift of this magnitude in these
institutions would be realized, the shift could be greater if other thrifts seek to shift deposits
from the SAIF to the BIF.
The migration of SAIF deposits has not occurred yet. That is not surprising because
affiliate relationships can be expensive to establish and, given current interest rates, SAIF
deposits are cheaper than some alternative funding sources. During the first three months of
1995, SAIF deposits increased $11 billion (1.6 percent), the second consecutive quarterly
increase after steadily declining for six years. As a result, at the end of the first quarter SAIF
members were more reliant on deposit funding (78.2 percent of total liabilities) than at year-end
1994 (77.2 percent). The first quarter’s deposit growth was at least partially attributable to
aggressive campaigns by some California thrifts to attract deposits, particularly lower-cost
demand deposits. In the event there is a significant premium disparity, SAIF members can
readily shift funding from demand deposits to other sources discussed above.
Impediments to reducing the reliance on SAIF-insured deposits.
Should conditions prevail that continue to provide incentives to migrate deposits or
otherwise reduce SAIF exposure, institutions will encounter certain impediments. While these
impediments would not eliminate any of the methods, in some instances they could result , in
added costs.
T hrift tax bad-debt reserves. The loss of the tax benefits inherent in the thrift charter
may limit the extent to which thrifts that have been profitable over the years are willing to cause
SAIF deposits to migrate to BIF affiliates. Since 1952, when thrifts first were subject to federal
taxation, thrifts that have met certain standards have been allowed to take tax deductions for bad
debts based on a percentage of their taxable income. The deduction essentially provided a
subsidy for the industry for many years, allowing thrifts to accumulate substantial tax bad-debt
reserves on a pre-tax basis. Changes in the tax laws slowly reduced the allowable deduction
until the 1986 tax legislation substantially lowered the deduction to its current level of 8 percent
of taxable income.7
Thrifts are required to recapture their reserves into taxable income if they fail to meet
a three-part test related to supervisory considerations, operations and assets. For supervisory
purposes they must have a thrift charter and thrift regulator; their operation must derive 75
percent of its income from loans and deposits; and, similar to the QTL test, they must maintain

7Data on the aggregate level of thrift tax bad-debt reserves is unavailable, although
America’s Community Bankers has indicated that they are in the process of conducting a survey
to estimate both the aggregate amount of reserves as well as the distribution of reserves across
the industry. Data on the reserves of individual thrifts, while not reported to bank or thrift
regulators, generally is noted in their annual financial reports.




7

60 percent of unconsolidated assets in mortgages and government- or mortgage-backed securities.
Failure to meet these tests for tax purposes can trigger the recapture of all or a portion of a
thrift’s reserves. There is considerable variability between institutions as to the size of these
reserves and the impediment they would pose to deposit migration. Thrifts that were profitable
for many years may have substantial reserves, and the recapture of these reserves could be
costly. On the other hand, thrifts that suffered long-term losses may face minimal recapture
costs. Of the SAIF-insured institutions that have converted to commercial bank charters (Sasser
institutions) and consequently were required to recapture some or all of their tax bad-debt
reserves, most incurred minimal tax liability.
Considerations related to the tax bad-debt reserves may have an impact on the decisions
of thrift institutions to cause SAIF deposits to migrate to the BIF or otherwise to reduce SAIF
deposits. If an institution shrinks its qualifying assets, it must also reduce its reserve by a
proportional amount. This can result in higher tax liability by causing the amount by which the
reserve was reduced to be recaptured into earnings (over some number of years, depending on
the method selected) and by limiting deductions going forward.
Under the three-part test for tax bad-debt reserves, the standards for assets are clearly
defined, but there are no clear quantitative standards on the required proportion of deposits to
total liabilities. The operations test mentioned above requires that thrifts demonstrate that they
are in the business of making loans and taking deposits. Therefore, a thrift could not avoid
SAIF assessments by shifting entirely to nondeposit liabilities without encountering tax
consequences. Some thrift industry tax experts suggest that the Internal Revenue Service would
not challenge institutions whose deposits represent only 20 percent or more of their total
liabilities.
Impediments affecting affiliate relationships. Impediments stem from factors such as
the costs associated with added regulation, the costs of establishing and maintaining affiliate
relationships, and the impact on customer relations.
In addition to application costs, the establishment of new affiliates could subject holding
companies to new layers of federal or state regulation. For example, the purchase of a BIFmember commercial bank by a thrift would cause the thrift to become a bank holding company
subject to supervision by the Federal Reserve. Bank holding company status would restrict the
activities and affiliations at the holding company level. Similarly, acquisition by a thrift holding
company of a second thrift charter would result in the loss of unitary thrift holding company
status, narrowing the list of permissible activities and affiliations. As such, it may deter some
thrift holding companies from pursuing a migration strategy.
To the extent SAIF deposits are held in a BIF-member Oakar institution, it may be less
cost effective to cause these deposits to migrate. The SAIF portion of each deposit dollar that
migrates to the BIF would be determined by the institution’s overall mix of SAIF and BIF
deposits, which generally remains constant. As a result, an Oakar institution cannot reduce its
SAIF exposure as rapidly as a non-Oakar, or pure, SAIF institution.




8

In addition, there may be costs associated with establishing and maintaining separate
affiliates. These include costs associated with corporate separateness, such as maintaining
distinct sets of books, boards of directors and management. For institutions establishing shared
offices, the potential confusion could adversely affect customer relations.

CONCLUSIONS
The SAIF is significantly undercapitalized and is further threatened by the structural
weaknesses of the thrift industry. Beginning July 1, 1995, losses from thrift failures must be
paid by the SAIF. The obligation to pay interest on FICO bonds through 2019 requires an
ongoing differential between the BIF and the SAIF. In combination, the problems facing the
SAIF create overwhelming incentives for SAIF members to minimize their exposure to higher
assessment rates. This can be accomplished through a variety of means. In addition to shifting
funding to nonassessable liabilities, a number of SAIF members have in place or are pursuing
the affiliate relationships that will enable the migration of SAIF-insured deposits to the BIF.
Depending on the response of SAIF members to the perceived benefits, this migration could
rapidly undermine the stability of the SAIF and threaten its viability. Moreover, this migration
likely would exacerbate the structural weaknesses of the thrift industry, leaving a smaller insured
pool against which to spread risks and costs.




9

RESOLVING THE PROBLEMS OF THE
SAVINGS ASSOCIATION INSURANCE FUND
July 27, 1995

BACKGROUND: THE NEED FOR ACTION
SAIF Is In Poor Condition, and Its Prospects Are Bleak.
•

SAIF is significantly undercapitalized.
As o f March 31 , 1995, SAIF held reserves o f $2.2 billion to cover
$704 billion in insured deposits - only 31 cents in reserves per
$100 o f insured deposits.

•

SAIF assessments have been —and continue to be ~ diverted to other
uses.
From SAIF's inception in 1989 through March 1995, $7.4 billion in
SAIF assessments were diverted to cover past thrift losses. If
those funds had gone into SAIF, the fund would have been fully
capitalized last year.
Payments on bonds issued to prop up a prior deposit insurance
fund (FJCO bonds) currently consume 4 5 percent o f SAIF
assessments —and that percentage will increase if SAIF deposits
continue to shrink.

•

SAIF's assessment base has declined sharply.
SAIF deposits shrank by 2 3 percent from year-end 1989 through
March 1995, or an average o f 5 percent annually, rather than
growing over 4 0 percent (as projected at the time o f SAIF's
creation in 1989).

•

SAIF is now responsible for resolving failed thrifts.
On July 1, 1995, SAIF became responsible for handling thrift
failures. Given SAIF's meager reserves, the failure o f one or two
large thrifts could render SAIF insolvent and put the taxpayer at
risk.




2
Consequences o f Inaction: Prospects for SAIF, the FICO Bonds, and the Thrift
Industry Will Worsen.
•

Erosion o f the SAIF assessment base would accelerate.
The healthiest SAIF members will have strong economic incentives
to avoid paying almost 6 times as much as the healthiest B/F
members for the same insurance coverage. Because o f SAIF's
obligation to make payments on the FICO bonds, a large differential
between BIF and SAIF premiums would persist until the year 20 19
even if SAIF were fully capitalized. Thus institutions would
continue to have incentives to shrink their SAIF deposits.
Healthy institutions have a wide variety o f ways in which to shrink
their SA/F deposits, despite the current moratorium on converting
from BIF to SA/F. For example, they can sell o ff loans instead o f
holding them in portfolio. They can replace deposits with
nondeposit funding sources. They can also seek to switch deposits
from SAIF to BIF by forming or acquiring affiliated BIF-insured
banks offering higher interest rates than thrifts.

•

SAIF's weaknesses could lead to a default on FICO Interest payments.
If the portion o f SAIF's assessment base available for FICO
payments declines 10 percent annually, FICO will default on its
interest payments in a few years.

•

Failure to resolve SAIF's problems could weaken the thrift industry, and
thus further weaken SA/F1
Uncertainties about S A IF — and high SAIF premiums — could make
it more difficult for SA/F members to attract and retain capital, thus
reducing the thrift industry's ability to help solve its problems and
respond to any adverse economic changes.

•

Structural issues make SAIF more vulnerable to economic downturns and
financial market instability|




SAIF faces increased risks because it insures institutions with
similar asset portfolios, and because SAIF-insured deposits are
concentrated in large West Coast thrifts.

3
PROPOSAL
Capitalize SAIF Through Assessments on SAIF Deposits
•

Require institutions with SAIF-assessable deposits to pay a special
assessment in an amount sufficient to capitalize SAIF (i.e., increase
the Fund's reserve ratio to 1.25 percent). Base the special
assessment on SAIF-assessable deposits held as of March 31,
1995. Make the special assessment due on January 1, 1996.
The special assessment would probably amount to 85 to 9 0
basis points. The rate would depend on (1) the extent to
which SAIF is undercapitalized at the end o f this year; and
(2) the total deposits subject to the special assessment (i.e.,
total SAIF-assessable deposits, minus deposits at weak
institutions exempted by the FD/C from the special
assessment, as discussed below).
The risk-based assessment schedule for the newly capitalized
SAIF would be similar to the schedule for B/F (the current
FDIC Board proposal has rates ranging from 4 to 31 basis
points).
For purposes only o f setting risk-based assessments for
coverage during the calendar year 1996, the FDIC would
calculate a SA/F-insured institution's capital before payment
o f the special assessment but taking into account other
capita! fluctuations.

•

Permit the FDIC's Board of Directors (acting pursuant to published
guidelines) to exempt weak institutions from the special
assessment if the Board determines that the exemption would
reduce risk to the Fund.
•




Require institutions exempted from the special assessment to
continue to pay regular assessments under the current SAIF
risk-based assessment schedule, with rates ranging from 23
to 31 basis points, for the next four calendar years (19961999).

4
Thus weak institutions would still, over time, generally
pay more than healthy institutions. A healthy
institution would pay approximately 101 basis points
from 1996 through 1999 (an 85 basis point special
assessment, plus a risk based assessment o f 4 basis
points for each o f four years as proposed by the FDIC
Board). A weak institution would pay annual
assessments o f 29-31 basis points (under the current
schedule weak institutions pay assessments o f 29-31
basis points) for a total o f 116-124 basis points (29-31
basis points for each o f four years).
•

•

2.

To encourage weak Institutions to resolve capital and other
deficiencies, give institutions exempted from the special
assessment the option — during the 1996*1999 period -- of
paying a pro-rated portion of the special assessment and then
paying assessments under the new risk-based schedule for
the remainder of the period.

Require that rates under the risk-based assessment schedule for
SAIF be no lower than the rates for comparable institutions under
the risk-based assessment schedule for BIF until the Funds are
merged.

Spread FIDO Payments Over All FOlC-lnsured Institutions
•




Effective January 1, 1996, expand the assessment base for
payments on FICO bonds to include the entire assessment base of
all FDIC-insured institutions |- both BIF members and SAIF members
(thus spreading the FICO obligation pro rata over all FDIC-insured
institutions). . _
As under current law, the cash to pay FICO bond interest
would come from assessment payments remitted by insured
depository institutions, rather than by withdrawing money
from the deposit insurance funds.
Spreading FICO payments would still allow healthy
institutions' BIF premiums to decline dramatically from
current rates.

5

3.

Merge the Deposit Insurance Funds
•

Effective as soon as practicable - preferably no later than the
beginning of 1998 — merge the BIF and SAIF.

A merger o f the funds would resolve the long-term
weaknesses o f SAIF by providing the requisite asset and
geographic diversification, which in turn should protect
taxpayers from the possibility o f another deposit insurance
crisis.
We recognize that any discussion o f a merger o f the funds
raises a host o f ancillary issues, such as the future o f the
thrift charter —and other distinctions between banks and
thrifts. The Treasury is developing a comprehensive proposal
to deal with these issues.

4.

Authorize Rebates of BIF Excess Premiums
•

Authorize the FDIC to rebate assessments paid by BIF members to
the extent that BIF reserves exceed the designated reserve ratio.
Rebate authority would not extend to B/F's investment
income, which has never been rebated in the FDJC's history.

5-

Adjust Rules to Promote Assessment-Rate Stability
•

Direct the FDIC's Board of Directors to maintain a deposit insurance
fund's reserve ratio so that it approximates the designated reserve
ratio. Give the Board flexibility to reduce the size and frequency of
assessment rate changes by permitting the reserve ratio to
fluctuate temporarily within a range of not more than 0.1
percentage point above or below the designated reserve ratio. This
would provide flexibility to smooth out premium rate fluctuations
but would not change the 1.25 percent designated reserve ratio.




6
The FDIC would seek to maintain the fund at approximately
the designated reserve ratio, but could permit it to fluctuate
temporarily within a narrow band. This flexibility would in no
way impair such other rules as (1) the FDIC's duty to base
assessments on risk; or (2) the requirement that SAIF
assessments be no lower than BIFassessments. Nor would
it authorize rebating BiF's investment income.
•




Lower from 23 basis points to 8 basis points the minimum average
assessment required under section 7(b)(2)(E) of the Federal Deposit
Insurance Act when a deposit insurance fund is undercapitalized or
when the FDIC has borrowings outstanding for the fund from the
Treasury or the Federal Financing Bank.

7

FDIC and OTS:
Make Unspent RTC Funds Available as a Backstop for
Extraordinary, Unanticipated SAIF Losses Until the BIF and SAIF are
Merged
•

If SAIF losses were to exceed $500 million in any calendar year
during the period beginning on July 1, 1995 (when SAIF takes over
the RTC's responsibility for resolving failed institutions), and ending
when the Funds are merged, make unspent RTC funds available to
cover the amount by which the losses in that year exceed $500
million.




Thus SAIF would cover the first $500 million in losses during
any such year, and unspent RTC funds would cover any
additional losses.
Neither the CBO nor the FDIC currently projects that SAIF
losses will reach $500 million in any year. (The FDIC
projects losses o f $270 million per year; the CBO projects
losses o f $450 million per year.) Thus unspent RTC funds
would serve only as a reinsurance policy against losses more
severe than those now anticipated.
The Treasury does not support use o f RTC funds.