View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by
Ricki Helfer
Chairman
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
before the
Government Affairs Conference
America's Community Bankers
Washington, D.C.
March 12, 1996

I am here today to talk about fairness. One working definition of the idea of "fairness" is "a
balance of claims and considerations that shows no undue favoritism." That is pretty dry. I
prefer the definition of fairness put forward by the great George Burns when he won an Oscar
for best supporting actor in the Neil Simon film "The Sunshine Boys," which he made at the age
of 79 in 1975. Burns said: "I don't deserve this Oscar, but I have arthritis and I dont deserve
that, either."
Sometimes we get what we do not deserve -- but if the pluses and minuses are balanced, the
outcome is fair. For more than a year, we have worked on a solution to the problem of the
Savings Association Insurance Fund (SAIF) that would be fair to all the parties involved.
Regardless of whether anyone intended it to be so -- and no one did -- the Savings Association
Insurance Fund is a structural defect in the deposit insurance system -- a defect that weakens
the whole -- a defect that could prove fatal. You have your immediate concerns about that. I
have to worry about it because it is a Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation-insured fund: its
weakness affects its members and banks and the 63-year-old reputation of the FDIC for
operating a sound deposit insurance fund.
Everyone benefits from a sound deposit insurance system, everyone -- the thrift executive, the
banker, and the depositor -- as well as all the indirect beneficiaries: the taxpayer who ultimately
guarantees the system and all the people who benefit from the stability in the financial markets
and the economy that deposit insurance provides. If you have not been keeping count, that is
virtually everyone.
For three generations of Americans, federal deposit insurance -- with the full faith and credit
backing of the U.S. government -- has provided a reason for unconditional faith in the banking
system. It is a certainty in an uncertain world.

The customer does not differentiate between the Bank Insurance Fund (BIF) and the Savings
Association Insurance Fund. The only thing that matters to the customer is the FDIC seal on the
window or the door. Anything that tarnishes that seal, anything that tarnishes the FDICs
reputation for sound insurance funds, carries the prospect of lessening public confidence in the
deposit insurance system as a whole. It is not hard to look ahead to see what will happen if the
SAIF problem is not fixed: The BIF recapitalized long before the SAIF. The BIF has more than
$1.25 for every $100 of deposits it insures -- at the end of 1995, the SAIF had 47 cents -- and 23
percent of the increase in the SAIF balance in 1995 stemmed from a one-time occurrence: $321
million from reserves no longer needed for projected failures being transferred into the fund.
As a result of this wide gulf between BIF and SAIF, a significant differential in the premiums for
BIF and SAIF will continue until 2019, without legislation. The ongoing differential provides a
strong incentive for SAIF members to seek ways to shift deposits from SAIF to BIF. As ways to
shift deposits are found, fewer institutions will carry the load and the SAIF will experience
increasing structural weakness.
Indeed, from 1989 through last September, the portion of the SAIF assessment base made up of
thrift deposits declined 11 percent annually. The SAIF has grown, but this growth came, not in
deposits at thrifts, but from the SAIF-insured deposits acquired by banks. Banks represent a
greater and greater portion of the SAIF -- today it is 38 percent. At year-end 1992, it was 14
percent. Stated simply, SAIF is becoming more and more a bank fund.
There is also the problem of thrifts leaving the SAIF fold. Despite a ban on conversions, thrift
deposits can -- and do -- shift from the SAIF to the BIF. Today, about 75 SAIF members have BIFmember affiliates and another dozen or so large thrifts are actively pursuing affiliates. In the
last quarter alone, one large thrift was able to shift $2.6 billion in deposits to a BIF-affiliate.
Using a different route, another thrift was able to exploit an anomaly in the assessment formula
to shift more than $3 billion on its books from SAIF to BIF. Together, these shifts actually caused
a slight reduction in the BIF reserve ratio -- the first reduction in 12 quarters. Every time a thrift
deposit shifts to the BIF, it goes without any reserves. This is a problem, not only for the SAIF,
but also for BIF members. Bankers must pay -- if not now, then later -- for the reserves the thrift
deposits do not carry. As long as there is an economic incentive to shift deposits from one fund
to the other, this will occur. As the pace of deposit shifts from SAIF to BIF increases -- and there
is reason to believe the pace will increase if there is no clear prospect of legislation -- these
costs will rise. Every SAIF deposit that shifts to BIF weakens the SAIF, increases bank ownership
of the SAIF, and dilutes the BIF.
Our solution to the SAIF problem may not be perfect, but it will work and it is fair. Parts of that
solution are the least bad choices we could make among worse alternatives. We had to work

with the alternatives given us -- and could not work with alternatives denied us. The solution is
the best of the possible worlds. Once it is done, the shadow of uncertainty over the insurance
fund will fade.
Under that solution, all financial institutions that benefit from FDIC insurance pay. Under that
solution, banks pay a pro rata portion of Financing Corporation obligations, which they do not
want to do, and thrifts pay a special assessment to capitalize SAIF, which they do not want to
do. In return, everyone is assured safe FDIC-insured funds -- a viable SAIF as well as a viable BIF
-- the continuing certainty that deposit insurance provides in an uncertain world -- a world
where the customer has no reason to distinguish between BIF and SAIF. In addition, it would be
a big step toward the merger of the SAIF and the BIF. A common fund will be the best -- and
soundest -- of all worlds for everyone.
In the end, given the available alternatives, we put together a solution for the SAIF that works,
both in the short term and the long term, a solution based on the merger of the two FDIC funds
and the development of a common charter for insured institutions. Given the costs and the
benefits to all, everyone will win from this approach. And, significantly for the FDIC, and for the
public, the stability of the deposit insurance system will be assured. When in 1989 Congress
gave the FDIC the responsibility for the SAIF, it joined the future of the BIF and the SAIF
together. They became sister funds -- and what affects one fund affects the other. That is what
the words insured by the FDIC are all about.
We have the opportunity to address the SAIF problem -- the structural defect that threatens the
deposit insurance system -- a chance to do it right, once and for all. If we let the opportunity
pass, we cannot know whether and when we will have such an opportunity again.

Last Updated 06/28/1999