View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Challenges for Monetary Policy
in a Globalized Economy
Remarks before the Global Interdependence Center

Richard W. Fisher
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
January 17, 2008

The views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System.

Challenges for Monetary Policy in a Globalized Economy
Richard W. Fisher
Thank you, Charlie [Plosser]. I am grateful for the invitation to speak to the Global
Interdependence Center.
I am going to take advantage of this podium to provide the Dallas Fed’s point of view, from a
global perspective, on the issue that preoccupies President Plosser and me and our colleagues on
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). That issue is the conduct of monetary policy
given our current economic predicament. If you will indulge me, we can address other issues of
global interdependence in the Q&A session. Before I get started, let me go on record as having
said that, as always, I speak today only for myself and not for the Federal Open Market
Committee, its members or the Federal Reserve System.
First, a word about Philadelphia. I spent a tad more than my Fed per diem last night and stayed at
the Ritz Carlton at Broad and Chestnut. Before it became a hotel, that monumental building
housed the old Girard Trust Company. True Philadelphians know the rock-solid financial legacy
of Stephen Girard. In 1811, he bought the remaining shares in the First Bank of the United States
and renamed it Girard’s Bank. History footnotes Girard’s Bank as the key financial backer of the
U.S. during the War of 1812. According to one estimate, the value of Girard’s net worth at his
death in 1831 was roughly $2 trillion in today’s dollars. Imagine: Girard made Warren Buffett
look like a piker! He and his bank were so financially solid that the saying “In Girard we trust”
was later morphed into the Girard Trust Company.
It was Girard Trust that took an interest in me in 1963 and gave my family the means to send me
far from home to a New Jersey boarding school. I never quite learned why they treated me so
kindly, but I do remember my father saying that Girard had a soft spot for wayward boys from
“challenged” backgrounds who might—just might—have some potential for salvation. I would
never have accumulated all those honors mentioned in President Plosser’s introduction, nor
would I have had the good life I have enjoyed, nor would I be addressing you today as a Federal
Reserve Bank president, had it not been for Girard Trust.
So I slept well last night in the bosom of that solid old building that was once a pillar of financial
rectitude—a rare luxury for a policymaker in these fitful times.
You’d be hard pressed to find an economist or market operator in this city or anywhere else on
the planet who is not concerned about waning U.S. economic growth. Some analysts and
commentators sound like Chicken Littles. Others are less excitable, but are nevertheless
assuming a defensive crouch. Most are mindful of recent developments in employment patterns,
uneven retail sales and downward shifts in shipping, rail and trucking indexes, industrial activity,
business capex plans, credit card payables, purchasing manager activity and other carefully
watched indicators. These stresses follow on the severe housing downturn and the liquidity bind.
There is an increasingly insistent drumbeat urging the Fed not only to not impose contractionary
policy on a weakening economy, but indeed to get “ahead of the curve” through further monetary
accommodation.
1

Chairman Bernanke spoke last week and made it clear that the FOMC stands “ready to take
substantive action needed to support growth and provide insurance against downside risks,”
adding that “additional policy easing may well be necessary.” In short, he made clear that the
FOMC does not intend to just squat and wait should economic data and sound risk management
signal that monetary accommodation is required.
It needs to be underscored that being proactive and not passive in doing our job does not mean
that we will abandon prudent decisionmaking. We are the central bank of the United States, the
bellwether economy of the world. Our job is not to bail out imprudent decisionmakers or errant
bankers, nor is it to directly support the stock market or to somehow make whole those money
managers, financial engineers and real estate speculators who got it wrong. And it most
definitely is not to err on the side of Wall Street at the expense of Main Street.
In fact, to benefit Main Street, we have a duty to maintain a financial system that enables
American capitalism to do its magic. To this end, we have recently taken steps designed to
circumvent bottlenecks in interbank lending—steps that include changing the operation of our
discount window and opening a new term auction facility. This facility has provided $70 billion
in funds in roughly a month and will soon provide another $30 billion, and perhaps even more
over time if needed.
In setting broader monetary policy and the fed funds target rate, the Fed operates under a dual
mandate. We are charged by Congress with creating the monetary conditions for sustainable,
noninflationary employment growth. Put more simply, our mandate is to grow employment and
to contain inflation. Unstable prices are incompatible with sustainable job growth. Some critics
worry that we have forgotten that axiom. We haven’t.
Let me give you my personal view.
In discharging our dual mandate, we must be mindful that short-term fixes often lead to longterm problems. The Fed occupies a unique place in the pantheon of government institutions. It
was deliberately designed to be calm and steady, untainted by the passion of the moment and
immune to political exigency and influence. Because monetary policy’s effects spread into the
economy slowly and accumulate over time, having an itchy trigger finger with monetary policy
risks shooting everyone in the foot. Our policy mandate must be discharged with careful and
deliberate aim.
In the attention-deficit world of television and Internet commentary, where so-called “instant
analysis”—an oxymoron if there ever was one—makes headlines, it is easy to understand why
one might think that the effect of a change in the fed funds rate would immediately alter the
dynamic of the economy. To be sure, movement in the fed funds rate, or even no movement at
all, may have an immediate psychological effect and influence expectations for future monetary
policy action. But the act of changing or not changing the fed funds target rate, in and of itself,
has no immediate effect on the economy. Like a good single malt whiskey, the ameliorating or
stimulating influence kicks in only with a lag.
The lag time necessary for inflation to respond to policy is especially long. As a policymaker
discharging our dual mandate, I am always mindful that in providing the monetary conditions for
employment growth, we must not also sow the seeds of inflation that will eventually choke off
2

the very employment growth we seek to encourage. You do not have to be an inflation “hawk” to
recognize that would be a Faustian bargain.
Those of you who follow my speeches—probably a very small number of you with way too
much time on your hands—will recall that I like neither the term “hawk” nor “dove.” I like to
think that all FOMC members are best metaphorically described in ornithological terms as
“owls”—wise women and men seeking to achieve the right balance in carrying out our dual
mandate. To be owlish, and to avoid the imbalance of emphasis that gave rise to needed harsh
discipline imposed by the Volcker FOMC, one has to bear in mind that the seeds of inflation,
once planted, can lie fallow for some time, then suddenly burst through the economic topsoil like
kudzu, requiring a near-toxic dose of countermeasures to overcome.
In the pre-Volcker era, the Fed had a less-than-admirable record of keeping inflation at bay. But
over the past few decades, we have done well enough to both contain inflation and engender
growth that far outpaced other advanced economies for a sustained period with only a smattering
of short recessions. In short, the Fed has delivered on its mandate.
To be sure, we have been profoundly impacted by the shifting economic dynamics that have
complicated our efforts to continue delivering on our mandate. I need not try to convince
members and supporters of the Global Interdependence Center that we are living in a globalized
world. Increasingly, globalization is blurring economic boundaries. On the inflation front, for
example, we have extensive economic playbooks that tell us how to treat the wage–price spiral
or cost-push forces in a closed economy. In a closed environment, one would ordinarily expect
that a weakening economy would lead, in turn, to a diminution in price pressures. But we have
less experience with prescribing policy in an open economy where demand-pull forces come
from beyond our borders—such as the burgeoning demand for commodities and food from
rapidly growing and newly consequential economies like China, India, Latin America and the
countries liberated from the oppression of Soviet communism. These faraway places play an
ever-increasing role in determining prices here at home.
Writing in last Sunday’s New York Times, Ben Stein noted this and that the Fed does not have
much power to influence the price of oil. 1 He is right. And for that matter, we can’t do much
about the external demand impacting the price of food—which, by the way, carries twice the
weight of energy in the consumer basket of personal consumption expenditures. But the
dynamics of production and demand among the new participants in the global economy
nonetheless impact us in different ways at different times. As these new participants joined the
global economy, they provided significant tailwinds, helping us grow by providing cost savings,
new sources of productivity enhancement and new sources of demand, helping fatten both the
top line and bottom line of our businesses while also holding down inflation. Under such
conditions, the Fed could operate with a more accommodative monetary policy than what might
have been appropriate in a closed economy, without putting upward pressure on inflation. And
that is what the Fed did, although some argue—with the benefit of hindsight—it did so for too
long.
I think it is now clear that the winds have shifted. The growing appetite for raw inputs from the
new participants in the global economy represents an inflationary headwind that is unlikely to
1

“Larry, Curly, Moe and the Economy,” The New York Times, page BU4, January 13, 2008.
3

soon abate. The so-called “income elasticity of demand” for energy is 1.2 across a wide range of
countries, which is a fancy way of saying that economic theory should lead one to conclude that
the demand for energy in, say, China, for example, would begin to grow faster than China’s
income growth, which continues to increase at a rapid rate. Put more simply, income growth in
China and India and elsewhere, even if it slows from its torrid pace, is likely to continue raising
demand for food and energy. There is a risk that upward price pressures will continue to affect
American producers and consumers of energy and food products and a continuing danger that
overall inflation expectations will drift upward as a result.
If I am correct, then the situation today is the flip side of the 1990s and early 2000s: In delivering
on our mandate to be monetary policy “owls,” we will have to err on the side of running tighter
policy than would otherwise be justified if we wish to limit upward inflation pressures.
I mentioned single malt whiskey earlier to describe the effective time lags of monetary policy. I
realize it is only lunchtime, but let’s return to the economics liquor cabinet for a moment.
Inflation is like absinthe. The narcotic allure of inflation is a dangerous thing. It might seem like
the remedy to bail out a government or a bad book of business and forget your troubles. Yet our
experience in the past has taught us only too well that inflation is a dangerous elixir that
ultimately proves debilitating for businesses, consumers, investors—including those foreign
investors who have lately come to the aid of some large balance sheets here—and especially for
the poor, the elderly and people on fixed incomes. It even inculcates bad financial behavioral
patterns in the young by encouraging spending rather than investment and saving. Inflation is
bad for Main Street and Wall Street and even for Sesame Street.
Yet we central bankers also traverse Lombard Street, and we know from Walter Bagehot that in
times of crisis, liquidity is key. As a voter on the FOMC this year, I stand ready to take
substantive action to support growth and provide insurance against downside risk, as long as
inflation expectations remain contained.
You will note the operative qualifying words there were “as long as inflation expectations remain
contained.” Each of us looks to different indicators for a sense of inflation’s direction. Some
peruse markets for signs of shifting expectations, looking, say, to the yield on Treasury InflationProtected Securities, or TIPS, or to the spread between yields in the forward markets between
TIPS and nominal Treasuries at different points of the yield curve or all along the entire curve.
Personally, as a former market operator, I am wary of relying on Treasury spot or futures
indicators during a flight to quality or at times when liquidity is at a premium, as investors may
have other preoccupations that trump or distort conventional inflation concerns.
Others look to surveys of consumers and professional forecasters, like those conducted by the
University of Michigan and the Philadelphia Fed. The latest, the University of Michigan survey,
released in December, is forecasting headline Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation of 3.4
percent, which is hardly comforting. The Philadelphia Fed survey, released last November,
provides a more palatable forecast of 2.4 percent for the next four quarters; yet if you plot that
survey against actual headline inflation obtained for the last four years, it has more often than not
underestimated inflation’s true path.
The brow of a central banker considering further accommodation furrows further when looking
at the inflation measures that form the basis for Main Street’s inflationary expectations—the CPI
4

and the Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE) deflator. On a 12-month basis, the most
recent CPI, released yesterday, was running at a rate of 4.1 percent. The last PCE deflator,
released in December, was 3.6 percent. The Trimmed Mean PCE Deflator, which the Dallas Fed
tracks in an effort to eliminate “noise from signal” and as a basis for projecting inflation, is no
longer trending downward. Even the so-called “Core PCE,” which I personally consider least
useful because it eliminates food and energy prices, is rising rather than declining.
Of course, what matters most is the future direction of inflation, not the past. In the course of
preparing for each FOMC meeting, I regularly consult directly with some 30-plus CEOs to
develop a sense of future business activity, including cost and pricing developments. I have
found this rigorous exercise to be extremely helpful in placing our staff’s econometric analysis in
context as I have prepared for FOMC meetings in the past, and I will be listening especially
carefully to these business operators’ reports on inflation-related developments as I prepare for
upcoming FOMC meetings.
In my view, the degree of substantive action to support economic growth and insure against
downside risk will be conditioned by what we see coming down the inflation pike. To deliver on
its dual mandate, the Fed must keep one ear cocked toward signs that inflationary expectations
are drifting upward as we execute additional monetary measures.
Let me bring this home to Philadelphia. In 1748, Benjamin Franklin wrote an “Advice to a
Young Tradesman.” In it, he speaks in the language of the day of the concepts of opportunity
cost and of the power of compound interest—pretty precocious stuff for those times. Of the
money supply, he wrote that “the more there is of it, the more it produces [at] every turning, so
that the profits rise quicker and quicker.” Yet he also warns in earthy terms of the dangers of
being too prolific. “He that kills a breeding sow,” Franklin warned, “destroys all her offspring to
the thousandth generation. He that murders a crown [the currency of the day], destroys all that it
might have produced….”
The late Dame Mary Douglas was no Ben Franklin. Nor was she a Philadelphian. She was a
brilliant British economic anthropologist who wrote a pathbreaking book titled Purity and
Danger. In it, she wrote something that Franklin or Stephen Girard or any good central banker
since the onset of time has understood implicitly: “Money can only perform its role of
intensifying economic interaction if the public has faith in it. If that faith is shaken, the currency
is useless.”
Like Charlie and my other colleagues, I have every desire to use monetary policy to intensify
economic interaction, to keep breeding jobs and growing our economy, so that we might keep
America strong to the thousandth generation. I have no intention of being party to any action that
might shake faith in the dollar. The challenge to monetary policy, as I see it, is to achieve the
growth part of our mandate in the short term and get “ahead of the curve” without shaking faith
in the currency over the long term.
I know that the GIC has other things on its mind than just monetary policy. So let me stop there
and answer any questions you might have.

5