View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Governor Randall S. Kroszner
At the Conference on Competitive Markets and Effective Regulation, Institute of International
Finance, New York, New York

November 16, 2007

Risk Management and the Economic Outlook
The disruption in financial markets over the past few months has altered the economic landscape
appreciably. This morning, I would like to talk about the analytical framework that I use to help guide
my thinking about the appropriate path for monetary policy. Just as an analytical risk-management
framework is fundamental to the safe and sound operation of large banking and financial institutions, it
is also, I believe, essential for sound monetary policy-making.
The Federal Open Market Committee recently announced that it will increase the frequency and
expand the content of its economic projections. A clear understanding of the risk-management
framework should help improve the public's comprehension of these expanded announcements and
thereby, I believe, improve the efficacy of monetary policy actions and the overall functioning of the
economy. After briefly outlining the risk-management approach, I will discuss the application of this
analytical framework to the current economic and financial environment. The views I will express
today are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC).
Monetary Policy and Uncertainty about the Outlook
In thinking about an analytical framework for guiding policy decisions, it is helpful to understand two
basic principles of monetary policy making: First, monetary policy must be set on the basis of
forecasts; and, second, because forecasts are subject to substantial uncertainty, policymakers must
adopt aspects of risk management in their approach. After all, as the Nobel laureate Niels Bohr once
said (in a comment later attributed to Yogi Berra), "prediction is very difficult, especially when it's about
the future." But, of course, policymakers cannot wait until the economy's overall performance comes
clearly into view before judging the most appropriate stance for monetary policy. Rather, given the
long and variable lags between changes in interest rates and changes in economic activity, as well as
lags in receiving data about economic activity, monetary policy must be forward looking.
Moreover, not only must policymakers decide on the path the economy is most likely to take over the
medium term, they must also judge how the macroeconomic risks are arrayed around that path. In the
case of the FOMC, when risks appear to be too heavily weighted to one side or the other, it may be
appropriate to adjust the stance of policy to better align the array of future possible outcomes with our
dual mandate of promoting maximum sustainable employment and stable prices over the longer term.
For some time now, central bankers have used principles of risk management to help inform their
monetary policy decisions. In essence, through risk management, monetary policymakers consider
economic scenarios that may have a relatively low probability of occurring but may have very adverse
consequences if they do occur. Households, business managers, and policymakers all face the need
to reduce the risks surrounding such relatively improbable but potentially high-cost events. Buying
auto insurance is an example of risk management intended to lessen the adverse (financial)
consequences of an automobile accident, and driving carefully is a risk-management technique that
can reduce the probability of having an accident. Thus, as with most economic decisions, we face a
trade-off, in this example between the benefits of risk management in mitigating very adverse
outcomes versus the costs of auto insurance and the additional travel time required by more careful
driving.
In the case of monetary policy, the possibility of adverse consequences arises in part from the
uncertainty that surrounds the outlook for economic activity and inflation at any given time--uncertainty
often referred to as macroeconomic risk. Generally, the main benefit of policy actions to lower
macroeconomic risk is that they reduce the probability of a very adverse outcome occurring while
raising the odds of achieving an outcome relatively close to the forecasted central tendency. In the

language of statistics, the actions are intended to move some of the probability mass from the tail of
the distribution of possible outcomes toward the center of the distribution. But, of course, there's no
such thing as a free lunch--what I mean is that here, too, we face a tradeoff: The cost of the riskmanagement action is the possibility that it may have increased the odds of inflation moving beyond
some acceptable range or of economic activity moving significantly away from its longer-run
sustainable path.
Financial Market Turmoil and Risks to the Outlook
Turning from the abstract to the concrete, the FOMC's decisions to ease policy at its September and
October meetings were, in my view, governed in part by an attempt to manage the macroeconomic
"tail risks" facing the U.S. economy. To no small extent, stresses in financial markets contributed
significantly to those macroeconomic risks.
Early in the summer, losses on securities backed by subprime home mortgages sparked concerns
about the performance of a range of securities with exposure to those mortgages, and investors
quickly pulled back. With secondary markets under significant strain, a number of large originators
announced substantial changes to their subprime-mortgage programs, and the volume of newly issued
securities backed by subprime mortgages fell precipitously and stayed low. The same forces also
damped investors' willingness to fund other types of nonconforming mortgages (that is, loans that do
not qualify for sale to Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac). The issuance of securities backed by mortgages
in so-called "alt-A" pools--which consist of loans to borrowers who typically have higher credit scores
than subprime borrowers but whose applications may have other risky attributes--declined markedly.
Prime jumbo home-purchase loans continued to be originated, but the spread of rates on such loans
over those on conforming loans was considerably higher than earlier in the year, and banks reportedly
tightened lending standards and other loan terms, as well. In terms of the macroeconomic outlook,
this substantial tightening in mortgage markets seemed likely to increase the odds of a deeper and
more long-lasting contraction in the housing market.
The mounting losses from securities backed by subprime mortgages led investors to lose confidence
in structured finance products more generally--investors apparently had relied heavily on credit-rating
firms to determine the quality of these often-complex instruments rather than perform their own
independent evaluations. Once losses began to mount, the earlier lack of due diligence by investors
brought them to the realization that they had an insufficient amount of information about these
products, and the normal price-discovery mechanism began to break down.1 The concerns about
structured credit products led to severe problems in markets for asset-backed commercial paper
(ABCP), where spreads spiked and programs had difficulty issuing paper with maturities longer than a
few days.
The largest banks began to worry about difficult-to-forecast expansions of their balance sheets--they
recognized that they might have to provide backup funding to commercial paper programs that were
no longer able to over their paper, and they faced substantial challenges syndicating the leveraged
loans they had underwritten. As a result, banks became very protective of their liquidity, and interbank
funding markets came under considerable pressure. Moreover, the extent to which banks were
protecting their liquidity and the pressures on their balance sheets raised in my mind the possibility that
banks could tighten lending standards and terms significantly and thereby exert a material drag on
economic growth.
Policy Deliberations in September and October
From my perspective, the outlook for future economic growth had thus weakened appreciably by the
time of the September FOMC meeting, and the downside risks associated with that weakened outlook
had increased markedly. Most notably, the incoming data and the continuing strains in mortgage
markets suggested that the outlook for housing activity had become gloomier. Moreover, although the
data in hand did not provide direct evidence of spillovers from the housing sector to other segments of
the economy, a heightened sense of uncertainty about economic and financial conditions had the
potential to lead households and businesses to be cautious about spending. Moreover, conditions in
financial markets could be expected to improve slowly at best; and even if conditions did begin to
normalize, credit conditions appeared likely to remain much tighter than they had been in the spring.

The actions taken at the September meeting were intended to help forestall some of the adverse
effects on the broader economy that might otherwise arise from the disruptions in financial markets-that is, to reduce the macroeconomic tail risk, and to promote moderate growth over time--or, put
another way, to increase the likelihood of achieving a desirable path for economic activity. Economic
growth appeared likely to run below its potential for a while. Given incoming inflation data to the
favorable side and reasonably well anchored inflation expectations, the costs of easing policy,
measured in terms of heightened inflation risks, seemed relatively low.
By the time of the FOMC meeting on October 31, it was evident that real gross domestic product
(GDP) had grown at a solid pace in the third quarter. However, the information that had come in
during the preceding six weeks suggested an intensification of the housing correction. In addition,
although some financial markets showed signs of reduced stress, normal price discovery was still
absent from many markets. In particular, mortgage markets remained significantly impaired, and
survey information suggested that banks had tightened terms and standards considerably for a range
of credit products, including mortgages.
All told, FOMC members saw the stance of monetary policy as being still somewhat restrictive, partly
because of the effects of tighter credit conditions on aggregate demand. Accordingly, the FOMC
lowered the target federal funds rate an additional 25 basis points, to 4-1/2 percent. The further
reduction in the target rate was intended to lessen the extent of macroeconomic risk in the economy
and to increase the likelihood of achieving moderate growth over time. In terms of the potential
inflation costs associated with that action, the incoming data on consumer prices continued to be
encouraging and inflation expectations appeared to remain reasonably well anchored. But, the recent
run-up in energy prices and the fall in the foreign exchange value of the dollar suggested to me that,
since the September FOMC meeting, somewhat greater inflation risks had raised the costs of easing
policy to manage the macroeconomic risks. Nonetheless, on balance, I viewed the benefits of that
action as being greater than the costs.
Looking forward, one feature of monetary policy to keep in mind is that, all else equal, each successive
action in the same direction tends to lower the incremental benefits and to raise the incremental costs
of additional actions. For example, unless underlying economic conditions or risks change
substantially, reductions in the target federal funds rate tend to be associated with decreasing
incremental benefits in terms of further mitigating tail risks and with increasing incremental costs in
terms of the potential for inflation to increase. In the current context, I would be especially concerned if
inflation expectations were to become unmoored and will watch both market-based and survey-based
measures of inflation expectations closely.
In sum, in September and again in October, I believed that achieving the FOMC's statutory mandate to
promote price stability and maximum employment would best be accomplished by lowering the target
federal funds rate. With those actions, however, the downside risks to economic growth now appear to
be roughly balanced by the upside risks to inflation. I would add that the limited data and information
received since the October FOMC meeting have not changed my thinking in this regard.
Economic Outlook
With the September and October policy actions as a backdrop, I would now like to provide a more
detailed description of where I think the U.S. economy is most likely to be headed in the near-term and
further ahead.
In the near term, the economy will probably go through a rough patch during which a number of
economic data releases may be downbeat. Home sales seem likely to weaken further given the
difficulties faced by some potential buyers in obtaining a mortgage and, perhaps, some concerns on
their part about buying into a falling market. Moreover, with the inventory of unsold homes already
quite high relative to sales, a further weakening of demand is likely to prompt additional cutbacks in
construction.
In the mortgage market, two considerations suggest that conditions for subprime borrowers will get
worse before they get better. First, the bulk of the first interest rate resets for adjustable-rate subprime

mortgages are yet to come. On average, from now until the end of 2008, nearly 450,000 subprime
mortgages per quarter are scheduled to undergo their first reset, eventually causing a typical monthly
payment to rise about $350, or 25 percent. Second, the weakness in house prices and the resulting
limit on the build-up of home equity will hinder the ability of subprime borrowers to refinance out of their
mortgages into less expensive loans; as a result, more borrowers will be left with a mortgage balance
that exceeds the value of the house.
The likely consequences of these two factors--imminent interest rate resets and the difficulty of
refinancing--will be yet higher rates of delinquencies and foreclosures over the next several quarters
and, in turn, additional downward pressure on house prices. The overhang of unsold homes also will
weigh heavily on the prices of newly built and existing homes. From a risk-management perspective,
these housing-related factors together pointed the FOMC toward its recent easings in policy to mitigate
the likely resulting drag on economic activity over the coming quarters.
Elsewhere in the economy, increases in consumer spending can be expected to be limited for a while
by the effects of sluggish home prices on household balance sheets. Consumer spending will also be
constrained, although probably to a lesser extent, by the drain on aggregate purchasing power caused
by mortgage resets; that drain will likely be exacerbated by the current run-up in energy prices.
Meanwhile, heightened uncertainty in the business sector could lead to reductions in capital spending
plans. Nonetheless, indicators of business sentiment from a variety of national and regional surveys
have remained generally favorable. Moreoever, conditions in the labor market, although a bit softer
recently, are still relatively solid, and foreign demand for U.S. goods and services remains strong.
Looking further ahead, the current stance of monetary policy should help the economy get through the
rough patch during the next year, with growth then likely to return to its longer-run sustainable rate. As
conditions in mortgage markets gradually normalize, home sales should pick up, and homebuilders are
likely to make progress in reducing their inventory overhang. With the drag from the housing sector
waning, the growth of employment and income should pick up and support somewhat larger increases
in consumer spending. And as long as demand from domestic consumers and our export partners
expands, increases in business investment would be expected to broadly keep pace with the rise in
consumption.
Such developments would not be likely to fuel a rise in inflation expectations or in actual inflation.
Sizable increases in energy and food prices have contributed to a pickup in headline inflation this year,
but the developments on core inflation (which excludes prices for food and energy items) have been
moving in a more favorable direction. For example, data released yesterday show that the overall
consumer price index (CPI) rose 3.5 percent over the twelve months ending in October, a gain about 2
percentage points greater than that of the preceding twelve months. In contrast, core CPI inflation was
2.2 percent over the twelve months ending in October, 1/2 percentage point less than the rate a year
ago.
Against this backdrop, inflation expectations have remained reasonably well anchored. The prices of
oil and other commodities continue, of course, to be a source of major uncertainty for the overall
inflation outlook. Currently, quotes from futures markets suggest that investors expect food and
energy prices to come off their recent peaks next year. That said, I think it's also fair to say that
political and economic developments around the world, not to mention the vagaries of the weather,
make any forecast of oil and other commodity prices highly uncertain. Moreover, spillovers from the
latest run-up in crude oil prices could begin to put upward pressure on core inflation.
So, to sum up, the economy seems poised to grow for a while at a noticeably slower pace than it did
during the summer, in part because of lower home sales, less residential construction, and generally
smaller increases in consumer and business spending. A sequence of data releases consistent with
the rough patch for economic activity that I expect in coming months would not, by themselves,
suggest to me that the current stance of monetary policy is inappropriate. I will, of course, continue to
carefully assess the implications of the incoming economic data and financial market developments for
economic growth prospects and the outlook for inflation.

Federal Reserve Communications
Let me close by saying a few words about the other important decision made by the FOMC at the
October meeting--a decision to adjust our communications strategy. As Chairman Bernanke explained
in more detail two days ago, the Committee decided that it would release its economic projections four
times per year rather than semiannually and that it would extend those projections from two years to
three. The new information will include a description of the economic considerations underlying the
forecasts, a discussion of the sources of risk to the overall outlook, and a sense of the dispersion of
views among policymakers. The changes adopted by the FOMC are an important advance: They will
provide additional insight into the Committee's outlook, they will help households and businesses
better understand and anticipate our policy decisions, and they will enhance our accountability for the
decisions we make. The Committee's decision to provide this expanded information represents the
latest step in an ongoing process, extending back at least thirty years, to foster that accountability and
improve the public's understanding of U.S. monetary policy making. I hope that my remarks this
morning also prove helpful in fostering a better understanding of how the risk-management tradeoffs
affect the policy deliberations of the FOMC as it pursues its dual mandate of promoting maximum
employment and price stability over the longer term.