View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Randall S. Kroszner

At the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Community Development Policy Summit,
Cleveland, Ohio
June 11, 2008

Protecting Consumers in the Credit Marketplace
I am delighted to be here today to help open this important conference. I thank my hosts, President
Pianalto and her staff at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, for the invitation. This year's
conference explores a confluence of consumer-related finance issues in the context of the current
difficulties in the mortgage markets. In my remarks today, I would like to discuss the key role of
consumer credit in our economy and describe how information disclosure and protecting consumers
can work to facilitate and promote the efficient functioning of markets for such credit.1
Good information is essential to achieving well-functioning markets. Consumers, equipped with the
right information at the right time, can make the choices most appropriate to their individual
circumstances and desires. For consumers to make the most meaningful use of the relevant
information, such information should be accessible and understandable. In turn, businesses rely on
consumers through their choices to signal their desires and preferences in order to produce the
products that consumers want. If consumers are not well informed, it is difficult for them to be
effective in conveying to businesses what they most want and in rewarding those businesses that do
produce such products. Good information in a marketplace thus not only empowers consumers to
make better choices but also helps competition work more effectively to provide the products
consumers most desire.
There are challenges in ensuring that the appropriate information is provided to help markets
function efficiently. Product suppliers may not always provide needed information or present it in a
format that enables meaningful comparison across competing products. Consumers must also have
the financial skills to evaluate the information effectively. However, even in the presence of good
information, practices can emerge that offer little benefit to consumers and, in some cases, may
cause harm. In such cases, improved disclosure alone may be insufficient to address these issues.
Rules can establish standards that promote increased certainty and restrain abusive practices. At the
same time, such rules need to be implemented in a careful and informed manner so that the potential
benefits of such rules are not offset by unintended consequences or the imposition of unnecessary
costs. The challenge to policymakers is to strike the right balance--that is, to find ways to empower
and protect consumers without diminishing access to credit and hindering future innovation. With
these principles in mind, I will briefly describe some of the key steps that the Federal Reserve is
undertaking to strike this balance in the area of consumer regulation to protect consumers and
provide them with the information they need, and when they need it, to make sound decisions.
Credit and the Economy
Credit is the lifeblood of the American economy. Whether it is to finance an education, purchase an
automobile or home, or simply bridge short-term differences in the timing between our income and
expenses, virtually all of us rely on credit at various points in our lives. Accordingly, choosing the
right type of credit with the most appropriate terms and conditions is important to each of us. The
Federal Reserve has an important role to play in this regard, as it has been given a mandate by the
Congress to help ensure that the costs and terms of credit use are both transparent and

understandable and to protect consumers from unfair and deceptive lending acts and practices. In
our role as a supervisor of banking institutions, the Federal Reserve also seeks to ensure that lending
is undertaken in a safe and sound manner.
Credit is not only important to each of us as individuals; it also plays a central role in the working of
our economy. Today's economy relies on consumer spending as an engine of growth--it accounts for
about 70 percent of the gross domestic product. Credit is an important underpinning to such
spending. Overall, evidence from the Federal Reserve's Survey of Consumer Finances shows that
about three-quarters of all households carry some debt.2 About three-quarters of automobile
purchases are currently either financed or leased, and about 95 percent of home purchases involve a
mortgage. The use of revolving credit is similarly widespread; about 75 percent of consumers hold
credit cards. The annual transaction volume on general-purpose credit card accounts reached nearly
$1.8 trillion in 2006, and our latest information suggests that consumers owed nearly $1 trillion on
revolving credit accounts of all types. Because consumer credit plays a central role in the economy,
the Federal Reserve has a macroeconomic interest in facilitating the efficient functioning of
consumer credit markets.
The Role of Credit
The prudent use of credit by households provides a number of important economic benefits. First,
for many families, credit allows for easier and timelier purchase of assets and goods, such as homes,
educations, and automobiles and other consumer durables that can generate savings in cost and time
and improve employment and income-generating opportunities.3 By facilitating such investmentoriented spending, credit enables consumers to save and consume at times that meet their needs. For
example, the purchase of an automobile, which many are only able to do using credit, can expand
employment opportunities, which, in turn, can lead to higher incomes. Access to consumer credit
also enables many entrepreneurs to finance the start-up or expansion of small businesses, a large
source of employment in the United States.
Second, a robust consumer credit market facilitates the growth of consumer durables industries (e.g.,
computers, autos, and appliances) in which new technologies, mass production, and economies of
scale have historically created employment growth and new wealth. It is simply hard to imagine the
pace of development in the automobile and appliance industries in the twentieth century without the
availability of credit to purchase their output. Indeed, the lack of well-developed credit markets has
been found to be an impediment to economic growth and prosperity.4 Even in a well-developed
economy such as ours, innovation in credit markets over the past two decades or so has expanded
credit availability to lower-income households and increased options for middle-income consumers
as well.5
Third, from an economy-wide perspective, credit provides an important outlet for the savings of
consumers through the financial intermediation process. Ultimately, the source of funds for
consumers who borrow is other consumers who have savings they hold in deposit accounts, life
insurance and pension reserves, or portfolios of securities that include bonds, stocks, and mutual
fund shares. Efficient markets for household credit are part of a well-functioning system of
financial intermediation that allocates savings to the most productive uses.
The developments in credit markets have generally benefited consumers. However, some of these
developments have increased the complexity of our choices and made mistakes potentially more
costly.6 A key challenge is to find ways to improve consumers' ability to identify products that are
suitable to their needs without diminishing the benefits market innovations can provide and without
reducing future access to credit. One important way this challenge can be met is by improving the
information available to consumers.
The Central Role of Information
Information is critical to the efficient functioning of markets.7 A central tenant of economics is that
markets are more competitive, and therefore more efficient, when accurate and complete
information is available to both consumers and product suppliers. Accurate and complete

information about credit terms and prices is essential for households to make sound judgments about
the use of credit. Information disclosure improves consumers' ability to compare products and to
choose those products that will help them meet their personal goals.
To be effective, disclosures must give consumers information about credit pricing and important
terms at a time when it is relevant, and in language consumers can easily understand. The
information must also be presented in a format that allows consumers to pick out and use the
information that is most important to them. Effective disclosures give consumers information they
notice, understand, and can use. Better credit-term disclosures permit better-informed credit
decisions and lead to more-intense competition among creditors. In a nutshell, effective disclosure
empowers consumers to choose wisely and enhances competition.
In some circumstances, the disclosure rules can facilitate efficient market outcomes by establishing
guidelines to improve information flows and establishing uniform standards for how information is
provided. For example, since enactment of the Truth in Lending Act of 1968, which requires
uniform disclosure of the cost of credit and other key lending terms, consumer awareness of and
sensitivity to interest rates in credit decisions has increased.8 Evidence also suggests that these
disclosures have improved competition and helped consumers.9 The prohibition of the provision of
misleading or erroneous information can also help to improve competitive outcomes.
To evaluate the effectiveness of disclosures, we must know what consumers understand, what
information they use, and how they use the information in making decisions. In designing rules, we
need to take consumers' actual behavior and understanding into consideration. As a result, the
Federal Reserve has been using consumer testing to address the considerable challenge of making
disclosures effective. As mentioned, consumers increasingly face more-diverse and more-complex
financial products, including nontraditional mortgages and credit cards with multiple and complex
features. Given this complexity, we are mindful of the challenges of information overload and seek
to design disclosures that are not only accurate, but also clear and concise, so that they are
meaningful and useful to consumers.
Numerous pages of fine print may provide the comprehensive descriptions that lawyers may prefer,
but they can also be confusing, or provide limited value, to consumers. We increasingly rely on
feedback from surveys and testing from actual consumers to determine the information they need to
make informed choices. In this regard, we recently completed several rounds of consumer testing for
credit card disclosures. That testing has been essential to our effort to redesign and improve them.
We have also begun using consumer testing of mortgage disclosures to help develop more-effective
disclosures around product features and other terms that consumers need to know.
Limitations of Disclosure Protections
When consumers are fully aware of and understand product terms and features, they are better
positioned to make the right choices and achieve the outcomes most appropriate to their given
circumstances, as well as give the signals and rewards to businesses that produce the products and
services consumers most value. However, some product features and contract terms may be so
complex that they are not readily understood. In some instances, even small misunderstandings,
misjudgments, or the challenge of focusing on the most essential features of a product can lead to
serious problems down the road. This is one reason why financial education and literacy efforts are
essential to enabling consumers to navigate our complex consumer financial marketplace.
Problems can arise if competition does not ensure that relevant information on some terms or
product features is provided in a timely and comprehensible way.10 Moreover, product terms or
features can sometimes emerge that offer little or no benefit to the vast majority of consumers.
Double-cycle billing, for example, is a practice in the credit card industry that is so complex that
few consumers can fully understand the implications of this practice, even in the presence of full
disclosure. Generally speaking, institutions using this practice assess interest not only on the
balance for the current billing cycle, but also on the balance for the preceding billing cycle. The
Board has conducted extensive consumer testing of various ways to describe this balance

computation method and found that disclosures are not successful in helping consumers understand
it. In such cases, improving information disclosure alone may not adequately address the issue.
Consequently, the goal of consumer protection may be most effectively realized, weighing the
potential costs and benefits, if certain product features are modified by rule or prohibited outright
rather than disclosed.
Current Challenges and the Federal Reserve's Regulatory Proposals
In today's vast and complex consumer finance marketplace, we face the challenge of ensuring that
disclosures for consumer credit remain effective in light of the growing complexity of consumer
credit products and terms. We also face the challenge of identifying when restrictions and
prohibitions are appropriate to ensure meaningful consumer protection and do not involve
unintended consequences that could ultimately reduce consumer welfare.
With the increased complexity of mortgage loans and credit cards in recent years, for example, there
has been great concern about the need for more-effective disclosure and increased consumer
protection in these transactions. The Federal Reserve has undertaken extensive efforts to gain insight
into industry practices and consumer experiences to understand how to improve disclosures when
possible and to enhance consumer protections where needed.
With respect to mortgage lending, we have been working to finalize the rules under the Home
Ownership and Equity Protection Act that we proposed in December. In developing this proposal,
we gained valuable insight through public hearings, discussions with industry and consumer groups,
input from our Consumer Advisory Council, and other sources. The amendments we have proposed
would better protect consumers from a range of unfair or deceptive mortgage lending and
advertising practices that have been the source of considerable concern and criticism. Our proposal
includes key protections for higher-priced mortgage loans secured by a consumer's principal
dwelling. Specifically, the proposal addresses concerns about underwriting and lenders'
consideration of the borrower's ability to make the scheduled payments, including verifying the
income and assets that lenders rely upon in making the loan. The proposal also addresses concerns
about prepayment penalties and the impact on consumers when lenders fail to establish escrow
accounts for taxes and insurance. We are working toward issuing final regulations in July.
For credit cards, the Federal Reserve has employed a two-step strategy toward improving consumer
protection. Our first step was the Board's proposal to substantially revise and improve credit card
disclosures under the Truth in Lending Act. We have done extensive consumer testing to determine
the type of information and its format that consumers find most useful in shopping for and choosing
a credit card. We issued this proposal last year, and we are still carefully considering the public
comment letters received on that proposal, many of which contain suggestions for how we might
further improve the disclosures. We believe that this proposal will result in credit card disclosures
that are significantly more effective for today's complex products. Testing disclosure forms and
formats with credit card users is crucial to ensuring that the disclosures are understandable and
useful to consumers. Effective disclosures can help to empower consumers and enhance the
competition because consumers find it easier to comparison shop. We are continuing to use
consumer testing as we work toward issuing final rules by year-end.
This extensive consumer testing--and the thousands of public comments generated by our 2007
credit card proposal--suggested that disclosures might not provide sufficient consumer protection
with regard to certain practices. Therefore, in May we took the next step in our ongoing effort to
enhance protections for consumers who use credit cards by proposing rules under the Federal Trade
Commission Act to prevent financial harm to consumers from specific practices. We proposed rules
that go beyond disclosure and could require financial institutions to make changes to their business
models and to alter some practices.
The Board has worked jointly with the Office of Thrift Supervision and the National Credit Union
Administration in drafting and issuing a proposal intended to prevent financial harm to consumers
from specific practices that the agencies find to be potentially abusive. Among other things, the
proposed rules would address the following:

z

z

z

z

Creditors would be required to provide consumers a reasonable amount of time to make
payments before they are considered late.
As a general rule, for accounts having multiple interest rates for different balances, creditors
would be prohibited from maximizing interest charges by applying payments exceeding the
minimum to the lowest rate balance first.
Creditors would no longer be permitted to increase the interest rate on existing account
balances at any time for any reason. Instead, card issuers could only apply a higher rate to the
existing balance under limited circumstances, such as when a consumer has been delinquent
for 30 days. Of course, creditors could still increase the rate on new transactions and could
offer variable-rate cards that have the rate on existing balances adjust based on changes to an
index.
Creditors could no longer accrue finance charges using the two-cycle balance computation
method.

The rules also prohibit a practice associated with the issuance of some subprime credit cards, in
which most of the credit limit is used for security deposits and high fees imposed at account opening
before the consumer actually receives the card.
In addition to rules for credit cards, our proposal also addresses potentially abusive practices in
connection with banks' payment of overdrafts to ensure that consumers have a choice of obtaining
overdraft protection and receive information related to its service and costs.
Conclusion
A robust, innovative, and competitive consumer finance market is crucial to a healthy economy and,
as I described earlier, can provide significant benefits to consumers. Such a market works most
effectively and brings the greatest benefits when consumers are well-informed and are not subject to
abusive practices. The Federal Reserve is working diligently to best use its authorities to provide
both creditors and consumers with rules that strike the right balance between ensuring that
consumers receive useful information at an appropriate time and restricting certain practices, while
at the same time minimizing the risk of unintended consequences and the imposition of unnecessary
costs that could reduce the benefits of a vital consumer finance marketplace.

Footnotes
1. Defined here, consumer credit includes both mortgage loans and other types of loans extended to
consumers. Return to text
2. Brian K. Bucks, Arthur B. Kennickell, and Kevin B Moore (2005), "Recent Changes in Family
Finances: Evidence from the 2001 and 2004 Survey of Consumers Finances (444 KB PDF),"
Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 91, pp. A1-A38. Return to text
3. Refer to, for example, F. Thomas Juster and Robert P. Shay (1964), "Consumer Sensitivity to
Finance Rates: An Empirical and Analytical Investigation," Occasional Paper 88 (New York:
National Bureau of Economic Research). Return to text
4. Thorsten Beck, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine (2004), "Finance, Inequality, and Poverty:
Cross-Country Evidence," Working Paper Series 10979 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research, December). Return to text
5. Joseph Nocera (1994), A Piece of the Action (New York: Simon and Schuster). Return to text
6. For example, Woodward finds that complicated loan arrangements raise the costs to homebuyers
engaging in mortgage transactions; Susan E. Woodward (2008), A Study of Closing Costs for FHA
Mortgages (Washington: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development). Return to text

7. Refer to, for example, George J. Stigler (1961), "The Economics of Information,"
Political Economy, vol. 69 (June), pp. 213-25. Return to text

Journal of

8. Thomas A. Durkin (2006), "Credit Card Disclosures, Solicitations, and Privacy Notices: Survey
Results of Consumer Knowledge and Behavior (104 KB PDF)," Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 92,
pp. A109-A121; Thomas A. Durkin and Gregory Elliehausen (forthcoming), Financial Economics
of Information Disclosure: Applications to Truth-in-Lending (New York: Oxford University
Press). Return to text
9. Durkin and Elliehausen (forthcoming), Financial Economics of Information Disclosure. Return
to text
10. Xavier Gabaix and David Laibson (2006), "Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and
Information Suppression in Competitive Markets," The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 121
(May), pp. 505-40. Return to text
Return to top