View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Randall S. Kroszner

At the Central de la Republica Argentina (BCRA) Seminar, Central Bank of Argentina,
Buenos Aires, Argentina
May 15, 2007

International Capital Flows and the Emerging-Market Economies
I am delighted to be here in Buenos Aires at a sister central bank, the Banco Central de la República
Argentina.1 The topic of my discussion today--international capital flows--is sure to be of interest
to any student of Argentina's economic history. As in all countries, the evolution of the Argentine
economy has been conditioned fundamentally by the nation's own framework of laws, policies, and
social practices. Nevertheless, the progression of economic developments in Argentina has always
been intertwined with developments in global capital markets, and that connection will likely persist
as Argentina continues to open up to the world economy.
I will start by identifying three interrelated aspects of international capital flows in today's global
economy. First, the scale of gross capital flows throughout the world is expanding, reflecting
financial innovation, lowered barriers to capital movements, and a decline in what economists refer
to as "home bias." Second, increased capital mobility is making it possible to finance ever larger
current account deficits, and, indeed, these deficits have grown in recent years relative to the size of
the global economy. Finally, in the aggregate, we see that capital has been flowing, on net, from
emerging-market economies to industrial countries in recent years, the reverse of the pattern in
previous decades.2
I would like to focus on the last of these features--the flow of capital between developing and
industrial countries. We will see that the aggregate data obscure important features of the flow of
capital between the two global regions. After discussing various explanations for the net flow of
capital to industrial countries, I will address the steps that emerging-market economies can take to
enhance their prospects for capital formation and financial investment. I will also touch on changes
in emerging-market financing and how this has altered the distribution of risks in the global
financial system.
Please note that the opinions I'll be expressing today are my own and not necessarily those of my
colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee.
The Scale and Composition of Capital Flows
Let's begin by getting some sense of the size, source, and composition of the net capital flows that
are moving from developing to industrial countries. One reasonable measure of the size of these
flows is the combined current account balance of the developing economies. According to estimates
by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the developing economies as a group had a current
account surplus of $640 billion last year (IMF, 2007a).3 Because the financial counterpart to this
surplus is a deficit on the financial accounts, it represents the net capital outflow to the industrial
economies. $640 billion is a big number and stands in sharp contrast to the situation preceding the
Asia crisis. For example, in 1996 the combined current account balance of the developing
economies was a deficit of $80 billion, representing a capital inflow of that amount from the
industrial world.
The sources of the $640 billion in net capital flow out of the developing economies are remarkably

concentrated. Of those developing economies running current account surpluses, a mere seventeen
of them--China, four other Asian economies, Russia, and eleven members of the Organization of
Petroleum Exporting Countries--accounted for a combined surplus of $710 billion. And about half
of that was generated by the major oil-exporting countries in the Middle East and by Russia, whose
surpluses ballooned in the past several years as oil prices soared. Thus, the other 131 developing
economies in our data had a combined current account deficit, or net capital inflow, of $70 billion.
This is not to say that things have not changed for these 131 countries in the past decade: In 1996,
their combined current account deficit was twice as large as it was last year.
That's the big picture in terms of the size and country source of last year's net capital flows. Let's
dig a little deeper and take a look at the gross capital inflows and outflows that constitute these net
figures. Unfortunately, the information on gross capital flows is not as timely as that for the current
account, and the data sets are not as consistent as we might like. Nonetheless, the estimates we have
are informative and, again, a bit surprising. For example, for 2005, the latest year for which we
have reasonably complete data, the developing economies as a group reported a gross capital inflow
of $720 billion, more than double the inflow recorded for 1996 (IMF, 2007b).
So how did we end up with a switch to net outflows? In 2005, gross capital outflows from the
developing economies totaled almost $1.2 trillion--more than a tripling of the 1996 figure. Thus,
we see that the question we have to answer is not, "Why has capital stopped flowing from the
industrial countries to the developing economies?" In gross terms it has not stopped; in fact, the
flow has accelerated! The question instead is, "Why are the developing economies investing so
much in the industrial countries?"
In a moment I will turn to several explanations for the recent pattern of capital flows. Before doing
that, however, we should take one additional insight from the gross figures: Of the gross capital
outflow from the developing economies in 2005, fully half reflects the further accumulation of
foreign exchange reserves by the official sector. To be sure, a large part of this reserve
accumulation was by the seventeen economies singled out earlier as large capital exporters (IMF,
2007c). But the other 131 economies also recorded substantial reserve accumulations. Once we put
aside these official reserve flows, it turns out that, in 2005, private capital flowed, on net, from the
industrial economies to the developing economies.
Why Is Capital Flowing Uphill? Why Does it Matter?
Recognizing that the aggregate data lump together the very different circumstances of different
economies, it is still true that, on the whole, net capital is flowing from the developing to the
industrial world. Economists sometimes refer to this phenomenon as capital flowing "uphill"
because it appears to contradict economic logic (See Prasad, Rajan, and Subramanian, 2006). There
are two elements of that logic. First, in developing economies, labor is generally much more
available than capital; accordingly, capital should in principle be more productive in these
economies and should thus flow there from the relatively labor-scarce industrial countries. Second,
the relatively rapid income growth expected by developing economies as they catch up to industrial
countries should provide them with incentives to borrow against their expected higher future
incomes. These considerations lead economists to puzzle over both the net outflow of capital from
the developing economies and its implications for the global economy.
One approach to explaining the uphill flow of capital focuses on divergent patterns of growth and
investment. According to one such view, the rise in U.S. productivity growth since the mid-1990s
boosted perceived rates of return on U.S. assets and thus attracted capital; expectations of higher
rates of return and higher incomes likely boosted U.S. investment and consumption spending as well
(Erceg, Guerrieri, and Gust, 2006; Ferguson, 2005). A complementary explanation, labeled the
"global saving glut" by Federal Reserve Chairman Bernanke several years ago, argues that during
the past decade, declines in investment spending outside the United States--in part because of
emerging-market crises--led to a surplus of saving over investment abroad that was channeled
toward the U.S. economy (Bernanke, 2005; Gruber and Kamin, forthcoming).
The global saving glut argument suggests that developing economies have benefited from the recent

pattern of global capital flows, gaining both demand for their products and a safe return on their
assets at a time when an investment slump threatened to depress domestic activity and rates of
return. The implications of the U.S. productivity story are a little harder to read, but developing
economies, especially in Asia, likely have benefited from the expansion of investment and
production opportunities created by the revolution in information technology.
Neither the global saving glut nor the U.S. advantage in productivity growth, however, can be
expected to persist indefinitely. How long the differences will persist depends upon a number of
factors. In rapidly developing countries that have had high savings rates such as China, for
example, consumption demand is likely to increase as they grow wealthier, thereby reducing their
savings rates. Concerning productivity differences, it may require more than simply the diffusion
and adoption of information technology around the globe. As I will come back to later, flexible
labor, product, and financial markets appear to be crucial to reaping the full benefits of the
information technology revolution, so national policy choices will play an important role in
maintaining or closing productivity differences. In any event, this set of explanations for the uphill
flow of capital suggests that it would be likely and desirable for net capital flows to reverse direction
and head back toward the developing economies at some point.
A second--but not mutually exclusive--set of explanations for this phenomenon focuses on what
might be more-persistent, structural differences between developing and industrial economies. The
financial systems in many developing nations are relatively weak and are not effective at directing
saving toward appropriate investment projects. That failing leads to inadequate investment,
particularly if business activity is further impeded by inadequate property rights and faulty
regulations. As a result, excess saving flows to countries with better financial systems (Prasad,
Rajan, and Subramanian, 2006; Ju and Wei, 2006).
A closely related point is that, compared with developing economies, industrial countries are
believed to produce financial assets that are safer, less volatile, and more liquid, advantages that also
draw capital out of developing economies (Caballero, Farhi, and Gourinchas, 2006; Mendoza,
Quadrini, and Rios-Rull, 2007). These considerations suggest that the current pattern of
international capital flows represents a win-win scenario: Developing economies gain access to
better financial services, and industrial economies enjoy the larger quantities of imports they can
purchase with this financing. These explanations also suggest that the uphill flow of capital will be
reversed to the extent that financial systems of emerging-market economies develop and improve.
Because such a process is likely to take time, this set of explanations suggests that the uphill flow of
capital is likely to persist for a while.
A third set of explanations traces the emergence of current account deficits in the industrial
countries, especially the United States, to increases in both public and private consumption which
show up as declines in national savings rates.4 Some observers draw a less sanguine message from
this approach than the first two mentioned above, namely, that current increases in consumption in
the industrial economies could potentially cost them greater indebtedness and lower future
consumption, and developing economies might then have less investment than otherwise. The high
level of gross flows into emerging markets and the "downhill" flow of private capital to some extent
temper this interpretation.
The three sets of explanations I have just discussed are only some of the many stories that have been
offered to explain the uphill flow of capital, and none of them have gained wide acceptance as the
best. Elements of each of them could account for some aspects of the current state of global capital
flows, and none are complete explanations for this complex phenomenon. For example, concerning
structural differences, as I discussed earlier, the aggregate current account balance of the developing
economies turned to surplus only in the late 1990s; before then, it was in deficit, even though the
financial sectors in those economies were, if anything, even less mature than they are today.
That said, the financial-sector stories as well as the productivity stories I've reviewed probably are at
least part of the explanation for the global pattern of capital flows. Moreover, these stories help to
identify policies that developing economies can undertake to boost domestic capital formation and

enhance the attractiveness of financial assets, both for foreign and domestic investors. Such policies
lay the foundation for future economic growth as well as promise to alter the current pattern of
capital flows and external balances.
Making Emerging-Market Economies a More Attractive Place to Invest
Businesses in many emerging-market economies face a multitude of hurdles. Red tape, rigid
regulations, and weak legal systems impede the formation of businesses, their ongoing operation,
and their confidence in having their contracts enforced without long and costly litigation.
Accordingly, governments in these countries could greatly improve the environment for domestic
capital formation by simplifying business regulations, strengthening property rights, including the
rights of creditors, and improving contract enforcement (Kroszner 2003 and 2006b; Mishkin,
2006). These kinds of institutional improvements would also help ensure that capital inflows are
channeled in a growth-enhancing manner (Arteta, Eichengreen, and Wyplosz, 2003).
As noted above, I believe it will take more than simply investment in information technology (IT)
for a country to enjoy the large productivity enhancements that can be brought about by the IT
revolution (Kroszner 2003 and 2006b). The IT revolution has not simply allowed a worker to turn
the crank faster on an improved machine (the traditional way we think of technological innovation)
but opened the possibility of fundamentally altering the way production (or provision of a service)
takes place. In this way, IT can contribute larger productivity improvements when an economy has
flexible labor, product, and financial markets.
To provide the greatest incentive for investment in the context of the IT revolution, business must
operate in an environment that will permit them to transform themselves in ways that allow
technology-intensive investment to have the highest possible effect on productivity growth.
Similarly, labor markets must be flexible enough to allow for the prompt re-allocation of resources
in response to changes in demand. The economy also must be competitive enough to allow useful
innovations at some firms to be transmitted throughout the industry by market pressure. This
underscores the importance of the overall regulatory and property rights environment to fostering
investment necessary for productivity growth in emerging economies.
More generally, a related set of policies should focus on strengthening the financial system so that it
better channels domestic saving into appropriate domestic investment projects. Adopting
international best practices in financial supervision and regulation would help promote prudent risk
management and effective intermediation. Intermediation could also be enhanced by developing
capital markets outside the banking system. The creation of secondary markets for mortgage debt
and, as I will describe in more detail shortly, the development of local bond markets more generally
has promoted deeper and more liquid financial systems in some emerging markets. Installing
modern trading and electronic payment systems, which facilitate quick and easy allocation of
capital, would also help.
A simple, intuitive principle governs all efforts to develop markets that channel funds efficiently
from a large number investors (both domestic and foreign). The principle is that all investors must
believe they all have the same access to information about investments and that they all will be
treated in the same way. To this end, policies to increase transparency, disclosure, and restrictions
on insider advantages are critical (Gelos and Wei, 2005; Ahearne and others, 2004).
Finally, prudent macroeconomic policies--fiscal consolidation and monetary policies aimed at price
stability--are crucial to any effort to boost investment and attract financing (Kroszner 2003 and
2006b).
Emerging-Market Financing and the Distribution of Risks
Emerging-market economies have, to varying degrees, already made progress in improving their
financial environment over the past decade. Inflation has been substantially reduced, and fiscal
balances have been brought under control. Many countries have reformed their financial systems
and modernized their business regulations. These policies have helped attract private capital
inflows, even though total capital flows still move from developing to industrial economies on net.

Financing mechanisms in the emerging-market economies have also evolved. Most notably,
external borrowing increasingly is in the form of bonds denominated in domestic currency, often
issued at fixed interest rates, and dated for long maturities, in contrast to the foreign-currency
instruments that dominated external borrowing in earlier years. Government bonds of this new type
were first issued by Korea and Thailand in the 1990s; Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Indonesia, Mexico,
and Russia soon followed suit (Kroszner, 2006a).
These new instruments have helped establish long-dated benchmark yield curves and thus encourage
corporate bond issuance and mortgage lending in domestic currency and at longer maturities. The
new instruments are also changing the distribution of risk. When entities in the emerging markets
borrowed in foreign currencies, they bore the exchange rate risk while lenders bore default risk.
This arrangement made the financial crises of the 1990s very costly: Sharp currency depreciations
caused the domestic-currency value of foreign-currency debt to balloon.
With domestic-currency financing, lenders now bear most of the exchange rate risk. And with
fixed-rate bonds, the interest rate risk, too, is being shifted to the lenders. We would expect that
emerging-market borrowers would have to pay higher yields to compensate lenders for this
additional risk. But yields on the new instruments have generally been moving down. For example,
Mexico, even with its history of macroeconomic instability, can borrow in pesos at a thirty-year
maturity at roughly 8 percent.
These low yields are part of a more general decline in compensation for risk in emerging markets, a
trend also evidenced by low risk spreads on dollar-denominated bonds and rising stock prices. In
part, this trend reflects the low volatility in international financial markets in recent years. However,
it also reflects improvements in the economic policies and debt positions of emerging-market
economies. In the past, an environment of low risk spreads contributed to overborrowing, booms,
and then busts. So far, that cycle has not developed, and it is crucial that sound and prudent policies
continue to guard against it's doing so. Credible macroeconomic and financial policies in the
emerging-market economies provide double benefits: They help keep borrowing costs low, and, in
the event of a future retreat from risk by global investors, they will help the affected economies
weather any ensuing financial turbulence.
Conclusion
In conclusion, I believe that the current net flow of capital toward the industrial world is not in the
long-term interest of the developing economies. To raise incomes and reduce poverty, the
developing economies must boost their productivity, and that, in turn, will require complementing
their large and growing labor forces with increasing quantities of capital. I would add that the
current pattern of net capital flows is more the deviation than the norm. The developing economies
in the aggregate swung into current account surplus only in the past decade. Moreover, at present,
only a subset of developing economies account for those surpluses, and even those are enjoying
substantial gross capital inflows.
Of course, there are better ways and worse ways to achieve a reversal in net capital flows. In the
past, current account deficits in the emerging-market economies were frequently the outcome of
large budget deficits and inappropriate exchange rate regimes, and I am certainly not calling for a
return to such policies. Rather, a swing in net capital flows back toward the developing economies
would best be achieved through policies they need--regardless of their effect on external balances-to promote capital formation and economic growth. Such policies would improve the environment
for business investment, strengthen domestic financial systems, and encourage the development of
more-attractive financial instruments. In particular, an increase in transparency and disclosure is
important so that all investors believe they will be treated equally and have an equal chance to enjoy
the returns from their investments. These steps, against the background of prudent monetary and
fiscal policies, will help both to encourage capital inflows and to ensure that they are used to best
advantage. By the same token, industrial countries can undertake policies to enhance their prospects
for solid, sustainable growth that would also have the effect of altering the current pattern of
international capital flows. In the United States, it is crucial to address the implications of
demographic changes for the longer-term path of entitlement spending. Other industrial economies

also face this challenge.
To a certain extent, financial and economic reforms are already under way in many emergingmarket economies, and private capital flows to these countries have expanded sharply over the past
decade. Moreover, financial flows increasingly are in the form of fixed-rate domestic-currency
bonds, which makes emerging-market borrowers less vulnerable to precipitous movements in
exchange rates and other asset prices. Financial crises may materialize and disrupt economic
activity, as they have in the past. However, provided that emerging-market economies continue to
pursue structural reforms and stabilizing macroeconomic policies, their prospects for solid economic
growth and resilience in the face of crisis will improve.

References
Ahearne, Alan G., William L. Griever, and Francis E. Warnock (2004). "Information Costs and
Home Bias: An Analysis of U.S. Holdings of Foreign Equities," Journal of International
Economics, vol. 62 (March), pp. 313-36.
Arteta, Carlos, Barry Eichengreen, and Charles Wyplosz (2003). "When Does Capital Account
Liberalization Help More than It Hurts?" in Elhanan Helpman and Efraim Sadka, eds., Economic
Policy in the International Economy: Essays in Honor of Assaf Razin. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Bernanke, Ben (2005). "The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit," the Homer
Jones Lecture, St. Louis, Missouri, April 14, /boarddocs/speeches/2005/20050414/default.htm
Caballero, Ricardo J., Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas (2006). "An Equilibrium
Model of ‘Global Imbalances' and Low Interest Rates," NBER Working Paper Series 11996.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11996
Chinn, Menzie D. (2005). Getting Serious About the Twin Deficits. Council Special Report 10.
New York: Council on Foreign Relations.
Cline, William R. (2005). The United States as a Debtor Nation: Risks and Policy Reform.
Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Erceg, Christopher J., Luca Guerrieri, and Christopher Gust (2006). "SIGMA: A New Open
Economy Model for Policy Analysis," International Journal of Central Banking, vol. 2 (March).
Ferguson, Roger W., Jr. (2005). "U.S. Current Account Deficit: Causes and Consequences," speech
delivered to the Economics Club of the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, April
20, /boarddocs/speeches/2005/20050420/default.htm
Gelos, R. Gaston, and Shang-Jin Wei (2005). "Transparency and International Portfolio Holdings,"
Journal of Finance, vol. 60 (December), pp. 2987-3020.
Gruber, Joseph W., and Steven B. Kamin (forthcoming). "Explaining the Global Pattern of Current
Account Imbalances," Journal of International Money and Finance.
International Monetary Fund (2007a). World Economic Outlook. Washington: IMF, April,
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2007/01/data/index.aspx
__________ (2007b). Global Financial Stability Report. Washington: IMF, April,
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2007/01/pdf/statappx.pdf (794 KB PDF)
__________ (2007c). International Financial Statistics. Database maintained by the Board of

Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Washington: IMF.
Ju, Jiandong, and Shang-Jin Wei (2006). "A Solution to Two Paradoxes of International Capital
Flows," IMF Working Paper WP/06/178. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Kroszner, Randall S. (2003). "Promoting Global Economic Growth: The Productivity Challenge (64
KB PDF)," working paper. Chicago: University of Chicago, July.
__________ (2006a). "Why Are Yield Curves So Flat and Long Rates So Low Globally?" speech
delivered at the Institute of International Bankers, New York, New York, June
16, /newsevents/speech/kroszner20060615a.htm
__________ (2006b). "What Drives Productivity Growth? Implications for the Economy and
Prospects for the Future," speech delivered to the Forecasters Club of New York, September
27, /newsevents/speech/kroszner20060927a.htm
Mendoza, Enrique G., Vincenzo Quadrini, and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull (2007). "Financial
Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances," NBER Working Paper 12909. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, http://www.nber.org/papers/w12909
Mishkin, Frederic S. (2006). The Next Great Globalization: How Disadvantaged Nations Can
Harness Their Financial Systems to Get Rich. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Prasad, Eswar, Raghuram Rajan, and Arvind Subramanian (2006). "Foreign Capital and Economic
Growth," paper presented at an IMF workshop, November,
https://www.imf.org/External/NP/seminars/eng/2006/growth/as.pdf (564 KB PDF)

Footnotes
1. Steve Kamin, Charles P. Thomas, and Carlos Arteta, of the Board's Division of International
Finance, contributed to this speech. Return to text
2. I will use the terms "developing economies" and "emerging-market economies" interchangeably
in this speech, although some observers draw distinctions between them. Return to text
3. In this section, the developing economies consist of those listed under "Other Emerging Market"
and under "Developing" in the IMF's World Economic Outlook plus Hong Kong SAR, Israel, Korea,
Singapore, and Taiwan. The data for these countries are drawn from the database published with
IMF (2007a). Return to text
4. Elaborations on the role of fiscal policy in the U.S. current account deficit are in Cline (2005)
and Chinn (2005). Return to text
Return to top