View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Randall S. Kroszner

At the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Conference on the Asian Financial Crisis
Revisited, San Francisco, California
(via videoconference)
September 6, 2007

Analyzing and Assessing Banking Crises
Good morning. I am delighted to be speaking to you today at the second of a pair of excellent
conferences that the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco has organized on the tenth anniversary
of the Asian financial crisis. Janet Yellen and her staff deserve kudos for focusing our attention on
this important topic and I feel honored for the invitation to speak today.1
Introduction
Before moving to the main topic, I would like to reinforce remarks made last week by Chairman
Bernanke on the recent turbulence in financial markets. In the United States we have seen a fairly
sharp downturn in housing markets, and in recent weeks there have been growing investor concerns
about mortgage credit performance, particularly with subprime mortgages. If current conditions
persist in mortgage markets, the demand for homes could weaken further, with possible implications
for the broader economy. And financial stress has not been limited just to mortgage markets, but
has spread to other markets. In general, a shift in risk attitudes has interacted with heightened
concerns about credit risks and uncertainty about how to evaluate those risks. Fortunately, this
recent period of turbulence in financial markets has occurred at a time when U.S. commercial banks
are strongly capitalized, reflecting years of robust profits.
As the nation's central bank, the Federal Reserve seeks to promote general financial stability and to
help to ensure that financial markets operate in an orderly manner. Accordingly, the Federal
Reserve has taken some steps in recent weeks to provide liquidity and to promote the orderly
functioning of markets. We continue to follow these developments in financial markets closely,
particularly those that may have a broad impact on real economic activity.
Today I plan to offer some thoughts about ways to analyze and assess the impact of banking crises
on real economic activity. Others at this conference will be addressing some of the specifics of the
Asian financial crisis in 1997-98 and the status of economies and financial systems of Asian
countries today, so I believe I can best contribute by setting up a conceptual and empirical
framework that can be applied to various types of financial crises, including Asia in 1997-98.
Much of what I plan to discuss is based on a paper I published earlier this year with colleagues at
the International Monetary Fund and World Bank, Luc Laeven and Daniela Klingbiel, titled
"Banking Crises, Financial Dependence, and Growth".2 In particular, this research focuses on a key
question for policy, namely, through what channels can financial turmoil have an impact on real
economic activity? We study the effect of different types of crises on the performance of various
sectors and firms in economies with differing levels of development of their banking and financial
systems. Surprisingly, little systematic empirical work had been done detailing the mechanisms by
which financial crises can generate problems in the real economy.3 I will provide a brief overview
of these results and then draw some lessons that policymakers might keep in mind when considering
ways to help prevent and mitigate future crises.

As a final introductory thought, I want to note that my remarks today on banking crises relate to
research conducted on a range of countries, many of them emerging-market countries, and are not a
commentary on current financial conditions or on the health of the U.S. banking system, which, as I
noted above, is quite good.
Framework for Assessing and Analyzing Banking Crises
Financial crises can assume various forms. I am going to focus primarily on financial crises
involving the banking sector and do so for several reasons. First, banks play a prominent role in the
credit intermediation process in most countries, providing funding to firms beyond the cash flow
provided by their normal operations. Banks also typically serve as custodian of a significant portion
of household saving. In many Asian countries, for example, banks play a key role in channeling
credit to firms--particularly those firms not able to acquire funding from capital markets or other
sources--and also hold substantial consumer deposits.
In addition, much of the literature on financial crises indicates that crises involving the banking
sector can lead to disruptions in the real economy. The definition of banking crisis I will use today,
consistent with the definition in our recent paper, is an episode during which the capital of the
banking sector has been depleted due to loan losses, resulting in a negative net worth of the banking
sector.4 Therefore, the use of the term "banking crisis" in our research refers to major disruptions in
a country's banking system, not just minor downturns or disturbances. By focusing on banking
crises in our research paper, we were able to isolate the impact of banks on the provision of credit
and liquidity to firms during times of distress. I believe that combining this type of empirical
research on banking crises with practical experience from bank supervisors and market participants,
such as those attending this conference, helps us all to understand and address the problems
associated with banking crises--and perhaps even to help to prevent them.
Much work has been done on how financial intermediaries and financial markets facilitate
investment by firms and, hence, promote economic growth.5 Financial intermediaries and financial
markets are generally thought to reduce information asymmetry problems that can make raising
external funds difficult and expensive for firms. Well-functioning and well-developed financial
intermediaries and markets thus should particularly benefit firms that rely most heavily on external
funding to finance their growth.6 Conversely--and this is the novel aspect of our research--crises in
the financial sector thus should have a disproportionately negative impact on firms that rely heavily
on external sources of finance.
In particular, we investigate whether the impact of a banking crisis on sectors dependent on external
sources of financing varies with the level of development of the financial system. If the banking
system is the key element allowing firms that depend heavily upon external funding sources to
finance their growth, then an impairment of these intermediaries--in a system where such
intermediaries are important--should have a disproportionate contractionary impact on precisely
those sectors that flourished in "normal" times, due to their reliance on banks. Thus, an important
element of our analysis is the level of development of a country's financial system, that is, whether it
is "deep" (more developed) or "shallow" (less developed).7
To address these issues, we gathered data from thirty-eight developed and developing countries that
have experienced a banking crisis during the last quarter century.8 We documented clear linkages
between the state of the banking system and the performance of the real economy. More
specifically, we find that in well-developed and deep financial systems, sectors highly dependent on
external sources of funding tend to experience a greater contraction during a banking crisis than do
externally dependent sectors in countries with shallower financial systems. In other words, sectors
of the real economy that rely heavily on external finance (that is, do not fund capital expenditures
through cash flow) tend to experience a substantially slower growth of value added during a banking
crisis than those sectors that do not rely so heavily on external funding. This effect is more
pronounced in countries with more developed financial systems. Our results hold for a wide group
of countries and over a long time span, but as I note below, have particular relevance to emerging
market countries.

While these results are consistent with a so-called credit channel impact of banking crises on real
economic activity, there are further implications of the "credit channel" view that we explore in
more detail. Among firms that depend heavily on outside financing, young firms with short
histories and firms with a large fraction of hard-to-measure intangible assets, for example, may have
particular difficulties raising funds from the market due to information problems. Instead, such
firms would tend to depend heavily on banks and other intermediaries for funding. Consistent with
this, we find a greater negative impact of banking crises on growth for industries dominated by
young firms that are highly dependent on external finance and for industries with high levels of
intangible assets.
While all of these results are consistent with a "credit channel" view of the impact of banking crises
on real economic activity, we certainly need to explore some alternative explanations before
drawing final conclusions. In particular, many factors may be correlated with the level of financial
development of a country, so we want to make sure that the level of financial development is not
simply standing in for something else. The differences in financial development, for example, can
arise from historical, political, cultural, and legal reasons. There is a well-developed literature
emphasizing, for instance, that the nature of a country's legal system and the manner in which laws
are enforced can have an effect on the development of its financial system.9 Similarly, other
country-specific factors also might have an influence on how financial institutions and markets
behave. If one of these factors, rather than financial development, is driving the results, we might
have to interpret those results differently.
As a way to try to address such questions of interpretation, we controlled for the quality of the
political and legal institutions in the countries included in our data analysis. We found that our
results still hold, namely that a banking crisis has a more pronounced effect on a country's economy
when its financial system is more developed and when its firms rely more on external finance, even
after taking into account a variety of proxies for the differences in the quality of institutions and
legal structures across countries.
Furthermore, we explored differences in the effect of banking crises on countries based on their
overall levels of development. In other words, we wanted to assess separately the impact of banking
crises in less-developed countries versus more-developed countries since, of course, overall
economic development and financial sector development tend to be correlated. Interestingly, when
we remove Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries from our
sample, the effects of banking crises were more pronounced, indicating that banking crises in
emerging market countries likely do more harm to the overall economy than in developed countries.
Interestingly, our research also provides evidence that crises affecting the banking sector can have a
more serious impact on the real economy than alternative economic disruptions such as economic
contractions or shocks such as currency crises.10 That is, banking crises have represented a unique
shock to a country's financial system. These results suggest that the "credit channel" effects on real
economic activity we document are operating through the banking system.
In short, the results highlight that a healthy banking system generally contributes to strong economic
growth, and banking crises can present a substantial drag on the real economy. This underscores
why we consider it important to analyze the economic impact of financial crises involving the
banking sector, and to mitigate potential drivers of such crises. Indeed, in the case of Asia a decade
ago, the trouble experienced by the region's banks, given their dominant role in Asian financial
systems, created disruptions that spread across Asia. Problems in the real economies of Asian
countries would likely not have been so great had the banking systems been stronger.
So far I have been discussing results that focus on the real growth impact on sectors or industries.
We were able to obtain data on the impact on individual firms but for a smaller sample than for the
sectors or industries. We use a variety of measures for individual firm performance, such as real
growth in sales, real growth in earnings before interest and taxes, and real stock market returns. The
results are the same as in the sectoral level data I described above: The performance of firms
heavily dependent upon external sources of funding is disproportionately negatively affected in deep

financial systems during periods of banking crisis.
In addition to providing microeconomic support for the credit channel view, individual firm data
also allow us to examine important hypotheses about the impact that transparency and public
disclosure by individual firms can have to mitigate the effects of banking crises on those firms. One
author, using data from the Asian crisis, has investigated the relationship between stock market
performance and quality of public disclosure.11 Our recent paper also delved into this issue by
using certain proxies for individual firm disclosure practices, such as having a listing in the United
States (hence disclosing by U.S. standards) or by being audited by one of the major international
accounting firms. Our results suggested that greater public disclosure had a favorable impact on
stock market performance, both during the crisis period as well as afterward. Indeed, there is a large
literature supporting the idea that a country can benefit by promoting transparency and disclosure.
But I know that there is still ongoing debate about the effects of globalization on financial markets
and economies and I believe that further research and discussion about the benefits of openness and
transparency are worthwhile. Perhaps a discussion on this topic will ensue at this conference over
the next two days.
I will pose one final topic before moving on to some policy suggestions. I believe it is important to
try to understand the long-term impact of a crisis on the financial system and the real economy. In
particular, it is useful to examine whether a particularly deep crisis or a recent one may have effects
on participants in that country during the next crisis. Interestingly, our recent work provided some
evidence that past crises do not necessarily create a stoppage of bank credit to firms once "normal"
times returned, but when the next crisis occurred, its impact on growth was usually deeper in
magnitude.
Thoughts on Preventing and Managing Banking Crises
Having raised some issues for consideration about banking crises--and having tried to provide some
answers, where possible--I would now like to offer some thoughts that policymakers may consider
as they try to prevent and manage banking crises. I note that market participants should also
consider these ideas, since it is not just policymakers who can learn lessons from past crises.
First, one of the major lessons to be learned from past banking crises is the importance of a healthy
banking system. Maintaining a safe and sound banking system, given the key role that banks play in
most financial systems, contributes to the health of a country's overall economy. Most countries do
this by some form of banking supervision, generally accepting that the added protection to the
banking system in the form of supervision is worth the costs of the regulatory burden. Effective
banking supervision has helped foster a banking system in the United States that today is safe,
sound, and well-capitalized.
One of the ways that bank supervisors can help promote a healthy banking system is to focus banks
on the development of improved risk-management techniques. Indeed, identifying, assessing, and
promoting sound risk-management practices have become central elements of good supervisory
practice. Bankers should ensure that their risk-management practices include a focus on less likely
outcomes, not just the most common ones, and that the bank is being adequately compensated for
the risk it is bearing. The use of exercises such as stress tests and scenario analyses can help
bankers identify certain points of vulnerability that may arise during potential downturns.
In some countries, bank supervisors have an explicit responsibility to ensure that banks adhere to
existing laws and maintain and implement appropriate consumer protection policies. For example,
in the United States the federal banking agencies play an important role in fostering not just a safe
and sound banking system, but also one that is diverse and fair in meeting the needs of consumers.
Good banking supervision is vital to the health of banks, particularly when the banking system has
some type of government support--for example, either explicit or implicit deposit insurance. But
ensuring a safe and sound banking system that is also competitive and profitable has its challenges.
Clearly, banking supervision on its own can create some distortions or burden, so it is also very
important to let market forces work as much as possible, with reliance on market participants--in

their role as depositors, counterparties, creditors, and shareholders--to exercise discipline on banks.
Policymakers have to find the right balance between the more visible hand of government
supervision and the invisible hand of market forces.
Second, pursuing sound macroeconomic policies is another way for policymakers to help prevent
banking and financial crises. For instance, it is beneficial to have sound and sustainable monetary
and fiscal policy to provide a stable operating environment for entrepreneurs and financial
institutions and markets. Many past crises were precipitated either by an external shock affecting an
already vulnerable financial system or by market participants targeting vulnerabilities in certain
markets or in certain institutions or governments. History has taught us that if a condition or policy
looks unsustainable, it most likely is and market forces will eventually bring it to an end. To
paraphrase Herb Stein, if a policy cannot go on forever, it won't!
Third, I referred earlier to research on the benefits of disclosure and transparency. Our analysis
contributes to the evidence that having an open and transparent financial system and economy,
accompanied by reliable and accurate accounting standards, generally benefits a country and its
market participants. A core principle of economics is that markets are more competitive, and
therefore more efficient, when accurate information is available to both consumers and suppliers.
Information is thus critical to the effective functioning of financial markets: timely and accurate
financial information about markets, market participants, and governments is important for all actors
to be able to make informed decisions. This is of course true during normal times, but perhaps more
so during a crisis when market participants and governments are sometimes trying to determine
where problems lie and how severe they might be. Lack of information can present additional
problems during a crisis, and incorrect or incomplete information provided by firms, governments,
and other institutions can severely undermine their credibility, worsening the problem.
Conclusion
These conferences on the Asian crisis serve as excellent forums to analyze the events of ten years
ago and share views on ways to prevent and mitigate future crises. They also allow market
participants to offer feedback on past policy steps, including which past policies helped and which
ones hindered. Policymakers and market participants must remember that preventing and mitigating
financial crises requires a blend of sharp analysis, keen judgment, practical experience, and rigorous
understanding of how markets work--in both normal times and times of stress.
I have tried to provide a framework for analyzing the impact of banking crises on real economic
activity, described some results analyzing crises from around the world during the last quarter
century, and offered three policy lessons: the importance of a healthy banking system, of sound
macroeconomic policy, and of high levels of transparency and disclosure. This is by no means an
exhaustive list but I hope it can provide a useful starting point for the discussions that will take place
during the rest of the day.
As a final thought, I counsel policymakers and market participants alike to remember that no two
crises are the same. Recall that the Asian crisis of 1997-98 actually manifested itself differently
across Asian countries, with each country having its own set of problems and needing to find its
own solutions. In other words, there is never a single remedy to each crisis and each brings its own
surprises and risks. Clearly, we can all learn a lot from past crises--which is the value in holding
conferences like this one. But we should not assume that past remedies will fully solve the next set
of problems or address all future risks. The key is to take lessons from the past and tailor them
appropriately to future situations of potential distress.

References
Beck, T., Levine, R., Loayza, N. (2000). "Finance and the Sources of Growth," Journal of
Financial Economics, vol. 58, pp. 261–300.

Braun, M., Larrain, B., (2005). "Finance and the Business Cycle: International, Inter-industry
Evidence." Journal of Finance, vol. 60 (June), pp. 1097–1128.
Caprio, G., Klingbiel, D. (2002). "Episodes of Systemic and Borderline Financial Crises." In:
Klingebiel, D., Laeven, L. (Eds.), Managing the Real and Fiscal Effects of Banking Crises. World
Bank Discussion Paper No. 428, Washington, DC, pp. 31–49.
King, R.G., Levine, R. (1993). "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, vol. 153, pp. 717–738.
Kroszner, R.S., Strahan, P.E. (2005). "Regulation and Deregulation of the U.S. Banking Industry:
Causes, Consequences, and Implications for the Future. In: Rose, N. (Ed.), Economics of
Regulation. NBER Conference Volume, Forthcoming.
Kroszner, Randall and Luc Laeven and Daniela Klingbiel (2007). "Banking Crises, Financial
Dependence, and Growth, Journal of Financial Economics," vol. 87 (April), pp. 187-228.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W. (1998). "Law and Finance," Journal
of Political Economy, vol. 106, pp. 1113–1155.
Levine, R. (1997). "Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda (371 KB
PDF)," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 35, pp. 688–726.
Levine, R. (2005). "Finance and Growth." In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (Eds.), Handbook of Economic
Growth. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, Forthcoming.
Milesi-Ferretti, G.M., Razin, A. (1998). "Current account reversals and currency crises: empirical
regularities (176 KB PDF)." NBER Working Paper No. 6620, Cambridge, MA.
Mitton, T. (2002). "A Cross-Firm Analysis of the Impact of Corporate Governance on the East
Asian Financial Crisis," Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 64, pp. 215–241.
Rajan, R.G., Zingales, L. (1998). "Financial Dependence and Growth,"
Review, vol. 88, pp. 559–596.

American Economic

Footnotes
1. The views I express today are, of course, my own and do not necessarily represent those of the
Board of Governors or the Federal Reserve System. Return to text
2. Kroszner, Laeven, and Klingbiel (2007). Return to text
3. Our paper provides a literature review. Return to text
4. Caprio and Klingbiel (2002). Return to text
5. See Levine (1997, 2005) and Kroszner and Strahan (2005) for overviews. Return to text
6. One measure of financial or external dependence is the fraction of capital expenditures not
financing with cash flows from operations. See Rajan and Zingales (1998). Return to text
7. In our recent research paper, the proxy for depth of the financial system is the ratio of private
credit to gross domestic product. Return to text

8. Clearly, determining the precise timing of crises is difficult, both in terms of identifying the
beginning and the end of a crisis. In our research we experimented with alternative definitions of
crisis windows, expanding and contracting the length of the crisis, pre-crisis, and post-crisis periods
as well as the gap between the crisis and the pre- and postcrisis periods; our results are not sensitive
to the alternative definitions. Return to text
9. La Porta et al (1998). Return to text
10. For our definition of economic contractions, see Braun and Larrain (2005); for our definition of
currency crises, see Milesi-Ferretti and Razin (1998). Return to text
11. Mitton (2002). Return to text
Return to top