View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:10 p.m. EDT (11:10 a.m. MDT)
June 28, 2021

Parachute Pants and Central Bank Money

Remarks by
Randal K. Quarles
Vice Chair for Supervision
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
The 113th Annual Utah Bankers Association Convention
Sun Valley, Idaho

June 28, 2021

I have been reflecting recently, and in connection with this speech, on America’s
centuries-long enthusiasm for novelty. In the main, it has served us and the world well,
by making America the home of so many of the scientific and practical innovations that
have transformed life in the 21st century from that of the 19th. But, especially when
coupled with an equally American susceptibility to boosterism and the fear of missing
out, it has also sometimes led to a mass suspension of our critical thinking and to
occasionally impetuous, deluded crazes or fads.
Sometimes the consequences are in hindsight merely puzzling or embarrassing,
like that year in the 1980s when millions of Americans suddenly started wearing
parachute pants. But the consequences can also be more serious.
Which brings us to my topic today: central bank digital currencies, or CBDCs. In
recent months, public interest in a “digital dollar” has reached fever pitch. A wide range
of experts and commenters have suggested that the Federal Reserve should issue—and in
fact may need to issue—a CBDC. But before we get carried away with the novelty, I
think we need to subject the promises of a CBDC to a careful critical analysis. In
offering my views on this and other issues related to CBDCs, I am speaking for myself as
a member of the Board of Governors, and not for the Board itself or any other Fed
policymakers. And, indeed, you will all have seen Chair Powell’s recent announcement
that we are preparing a comprehensive discussion paper on this issue that will be the first
step in a thorough public process to conduct just this sort of critical analysis, which I do
not want to prejudge. But I do want to give some sense of the issues I think we will need
to grapple with in this process, how I will be thinking about them, and the high bar that I
think any proposal to create a U.S. CBDC must clear.

-2So, let’s begin with a basic question: what problem would a CBDC solve? To
answer, we first need to define the term CBDC and assess the current state of the U.S.
payment system.
What Do We Mean by “CBDC”?
The Bank for International Settlements has defined a CBDC as “a digital payment
instrument, denominated in the national unit of account, that is a direct liability of the
central bank.” 1
My first observation is that the general public already transacts mostly in digital
dollars—by sending and receiving electronic balances in our commercial bank accounts.
These digital dollars are not a CBDC, because they are liabilities of commercial banks
rather than the Federal Reserve. Importantly, however, digital dollars at commercial
banks are federally insured up to $250,000, which means that for deposits up to that
amount—which means for essentially all retail deposits in the United States—they are as
sound as a central bank liability.
The Federal Reserve also provides digital dollars directly to commercial banks
and certain other financial institutions. Federal law allows these financial institutions to
maintain accounts with—and receive payments services from—the Federal Reserve.
Balances in Federal Reserve accounts serve a vital financial stability function by
providing a safe and liquid settlement asset for the U.S. economy.
To summarize then, the dollar is already highly digitized. The Federal Reserve
provides a digital dollar to commercial banks, and commercial banks provide digital
dollars and other financial services to consumers and businesses. This arrangement
See Central Bank Digital Currencies: Foundational Principles and Core Features (Basel: Bank for
International Settlements, October 9, 2020), https://www.bis.org/publ/othp33.htm.

1

-3serves the nation and the economy well: the Federal Reserve functions in the public
interest by promoting the health of the U.S. economy and the stability of the broader
financial system, while commercial banks compete to attract and effectively serve
customers.
So, given the existing digitization of the U.S. dollar, how would a CBDC differ
from the digital dollars we use today? The key distinction is that, when most
commentators speculate about a Federal Reserve CBDC, they assume that it would be
available to the general public directly from the central bank. A CBDC of this nature
could take different forms. One is an account-based model, in which the Federal Reserve
would provide individual accounts directly to the general public. Like the accounts that
the Federal Reserve currently provides to financial institutions, an accountholder would
send and receive funds by debit or credit to their Federal Reserve account.
A different CBDC model could involve a CBDC that is not maintained in Federal
Reserve accounts. This form of CBDC would be closer to a digital equivalent of cash.
Like cash, it would represent a claim against the Federal Reserve, but it could potentially
be transferred from person to person (like a banknote) or through intermediaries.
I am skeptical that the Federal Reserve has legal authority to pursue either of
these CBDC models without legislation. Nevertheless, the recent clamor over CBDCs
makes it appropriate to explore the benefits, costs, and practicalities of implementing one
in the United States if such legislative authority were granted. Let’s start with a look at
the current U.S. payment system that a Fed CBDC would fit into.
Current State of the U.S. Payment System

-4The Federal Reserve and private-sector interbank payment services already offer
an array of options that facilitate efficient, electronic U.S. dollar payments. A few
statistics related to the main large-value payment systems for U.S. dollars are illustrative.
The Federal Reserve’s large-value payment service (the Fedwire Funds Service)
processes nearly $4 trillion in payments every day. 2 These payments settle instantly in a
bank’s account at the Federal Reserve. A private-sector entity (The Clearing House)
operates a large-value payment system that settles nearly $2 trillion in payments every
day. 3 These payments do not settle in Federal Reserve accounts, but they are
underpinned by balances on the books of a Federal Reserve Bank.
Smaller-value payments often settle more slowly than large-value payments, but a
variety of efforts to speed up settlement have been completed or are underway. For
example, The Clearing House has developed an instant payments service that focuses on
smaller-value payments. Similarly, the automated clearinghouse (or ACH) network—a
batch-based payment network that first developed in the long-ago 20th century—now
enables same-day settlement of ACH payments. And the Federal Reserve is developing
an instant payment service—FedNow℠—that will soon provide recipients of small-value
payments with immediate access to their funds in commercial bank accounts.
The payment system is not perfect—some types of payments should move more
quickly and efficiently. Payments across international borders, for example, remain a key
area of concern because they often involve high costs, low speed, and insufficient

“Fedwire Funds Service—Monthly Statistics” (web page), Federal Reserve Bank Services, accessed June
27, 2021, https://www.frbservices.org/resources/financial-services/wires/volume-value-stats/monthlystats.html.
3
See “About CHIPS” (web page), The Clearing House, accessed June 27, 2021,
https://www.theclearinghouse.org/payment-systems/chips.
2

-5transparency. The Financial Stability Board, an international group that I chair, produced
a roadmap last year that is intended to address these concerns. 4 Additionally, privatesector stablecoins (which I will discuss in more detail in a moment) may facilitate faster
and cheaper cross-border payments.
In addition, some types of payments have not fully digitized or are subject to
ongoing contention between businesses with competing economic interests. For
example, paper checks remain widely used for certain types of payments (although the
interbank check collection process is now almost entirely electronic). 5 Debit and credit
card payments offer a convenient digital platform for consumers and retailers, but there
has been considerable controversy between banks and retailers over who will capture the
economics surrounding the fees associated with card transactions.
Finally, many more Americans could benefit from digital payments by increasing
their use of banking services, which can be promoted by wider use of low-cost, basic
bank accounts.
In summary, the U.S. payment system is very good, and although it is not perfect,
work is already underway to significantly improve it.
Policy Considerations
Yet, proponents of a Federal Reserve CBDC believe that it would solve a number
of significant problems. They suggest, for example, that a Federal Reserve CBDC may
be necessary to defend the critical role the U.S. dollar plays in the global economy.

Financial Stability Board, “FSB Delivers a Roadmap to Enhance Cross-Border Payments,” news release,
October 13, 2020, https://www.fsb.org/2020/10/fsb-delivers-a-roadmap-to-enhance-cross-borderpayments/.
5
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2019 Federal Reserve Payments Study (Washington:
Board of Governors, December 2019), https://www.federalreserve.gov/paymentsystems/2019-DecemberThe-Federal-Reserve-Payments-Study.htm.
4

-6Others say that a CBDC would overcome longstanding economic inequalities in
American society. As we begin our Fed analysis of these issues, I will have to be
convinced that a CBDC is a particularly good tool to address either of these issues, about
which I am skeptical, and I will especially have to be convinced that the potential benefits
of developing a Federal Reserve CBDC outweigh the potential risks.
Let’s examine some of the arguments raised by CBDC supporters. The first
argument is that the Federal Reserve should develop a CBDC to defend the U.S. dollar
against threats that would be posed by foreign CBDCs, on the one hand, and the
continued spread of private digital currencies, on the other.
Taking the threat from foreign CBDC’s first, this argument presumes that at least
some foreign currencies—all of which are already highly digitized in our current
international banking system in the same way the dollar is and yet which do not pose a
significant challenge to the international role of the dollar—will suddenly pose a much
greater challenge to the dollar if that digitization is accomplished through a direct central
bank digital currency instead of through the current digital payments system. In this
view, the U.S. dollar will lose its place in the global economy if the Federal Reserve does
not offer a similar product.
I think it’s inevitable that, as the global economy and financial system continue to
evolve, some foreign currencies (including some foreign CBDCs) will be used more in
international transactions than they currently are. It seems unlikely, however, that the
dollar’s status as a global reserve currency, or the dollar’s role as the dominant currency
in international financial transactions, will be threatened by a foreign CBDC. The
dollar’s role in the global economy rests on a number of foundations, including the

-7strength and size of the U.S. economy; extensive trade linkages between the United
States and the rest of the world; deep financial markets, including for U.S. Treasury
securities; the stable value of the dollar over time; the ease of converting U.S. dollars into
foreign currencies; the rule of law and strong property rights in the United States; and last
but not least, credible U.S. monetary policy. None of these are likely to be threatened by
a foreign currency, and certainly not because that foreign currency is a CBDC.
CBDC supporters also suggest that private digital currencies pose a threat to the
U.S. dollar. Private digital currencies come in multiple flavors, but for this purpose I will
divide them into two categories: stablecoins and non-stablecoins, or cryptoassets, such as
bitcoin. Let’s begin with stablecoins. The value of a stablecoin is tied to one or more
other assets, such as a sovereign currency. 6 There are multiple existing and potential
stablecoins that are or would be tied in value to the U.S. dollar.
Some commentators argue that the United States must develop a CBDC to
compete with U.S. dollar stablecoins. Stablecoins are an important development that
raise difficult questions. For example, how would widespread adoption of stablecoins
affect monetary policy or financial stability? How might stablecoins affect the
commercial banking system? Do stablecoins represent a fundamental threat to the
government’s role in money creation?
In my judgment, we do not need to fear stablecoins. The Federal Reserve has
traditionally supported responsible private-sector innovation. Consistent with this
tradition, I believe that we must take strong account of the potential benefits of

Financial Stability Board, Regulation, Supervision and Oversight of “Global Stablecoin” Arrangements
(Basel: Financial Stability Board, October 13, 2020), https://www.fsb.org/2020/10/regulation-supervisionand-oversight-of-global-stablecoin-arrangements/.
6

-8stablecoins, including the possibility that a U.S. dollar stablecoin might support the role
of the dollar in the global economy. For example, a global U.S. dollar stablecoin network
could encourage use of the dollar by making cross-border payments faster and cheaper,
and it potentially could be deployed much faster and with fewer downsides than a CBDC.
And the concern that stablecoins represent the unprecedented creation of private money
and thus challenge our monetary sovereignty is puzzling, given that our existing system
involves—indeed depends on—private firms creating money every day.
We do have a legitimate and strong regulatory interest in how stablecoins are
constructed and managed, particularly with respect to financial stability concerns: the
pool of assets that acts as the anchor for a stablecoin’s value could—if use of the
stablecoin became widespread enough—create stability risk if it is invested in multiple
currency denominations; if it is a fractional rather than full reserve; if the stablecoin
holder does not have a clear claim on the underlying asset; or if the pool is invested in
instruments other than the most liquid possible, principally central bank reserves and
short-term sovereign bonds. All of these factors create “run risk” —the possibility that
some triggering event could cause a large number of stablecoin holders to exchange their
coins all at once for other assets and that the stablecoin system would not be able to meet
such demands while maintaining a reasonably stable value. But these concerns are
eminently addressable—indeed, some stablecoins have already been structured to address
them. When our concerns have been addressed, we should be saying yes to these
products, rather than straining to find ways to say no. Indeed, the combination of
imminent improvements in the existing payments system such as various instant

-9payments initiatives combined with the cross-border efficiency of properly structured
stablecoins could well make superfluous any effort to develop a CBDC.
In contrast to stablecoins, cryptoassets like bitcoin are not tied to the value of an
asset like a sovereign currency. Rather, they seek to create value in the coin through
other means, usually some intrinsic mechanism to ensure scarcity, like bitcoin’s mining
process, or some characteristic of the coin that cannot be matched by the traditional
payment system, such as inviolable anonymity. Some commentators assert that the
United States must develop a CBDC to counter the appeal of cryptocurrencies. This
seems mistaken. The mechanisms used to create such cryptoassets’ value also ensure that
this value will be highly volatile—rather similar to the fluctuating value of gold, which,
like bitcoin, draws a significant part of its value from its scarcity, and like bitcoin, does
not play a significant role in today’s payments or monetary system. Unlike gold,
however, which has industrial uses and aesthetic attributes quite apart from its vestigial
financial role, bitcoin’s principal additional attractions are its novelty and its anonymity.
The anonymity will make it appropriately the target for increasingly comprehensive
scrutiny from law enforcement and the novelty is a rapidly wasting asset. Gold will
always glitter, but novelty, by definition, fades. Bitcoin and its ilk will, accordingly,
almost certainly remain a risky and speculative investment rather than a revolutionary
means of payment, and they are therefore highly unlikely to affect the role of the U.S.
dollar or require a response with a CBDC.
A second broad argument raised by proponents of CBDCs is that a Federal
Reserve CBDC would improve access to digital payments for people who currently do
not keep bank accounts because of their expense, a lack of trust in banks, or other

- 10 reasons. This is a worthwhile goal. However, I believe we can promote financial
inclusion more efficiently by taking steps to make cheap, basic commercial bank
accounts more available to people for whom the current cost is burdensome, such as the
Bank On accounts developed in collaboration between the Cities for Financial
Empowerment Fund and many local coalitions. 7 Between 2011 and 2019, the percentage
of households that are unbanked dropped from 8.2 percent to an estimated 5.4 percent. 8
Banks and regulators are working to shrink this percentage further still. I am far from
convinced that a CBDC is the best, or even an effective, method to increase financial
inclusion. 9
Last, some believe that a Federal Reserve CBDC would spur and facilitate
private-sector innovation. This is an interesting issue that merits further study. I am
puzzled, however, as to how a Federal Reserve CBDC could promote innovation in a way
that a private-sector stablecoin or other new payment mechanism could not. It seems to
me that there has been considerable private-sector innovation in the payments industry
without a CBDC, and it is conceivable that a Fed CBDC, or even plans for one, might
deter private-sector innovation by effectively “occupying the field.”
In brief, the potential benefits of a Federal Reserve CBDC are unclear.
Conversely, a Federal Reserve CBDC could pose significant and concrete risks. First, a
Federal Reserve CBDC could create considerable challenges for the structure of our
banking system, which currently relies on deposits to support the credit needs of
See https://joinbankon.org/.
“Key Findings from How America Banks: Household Use of Banking and Financial Services”
(web page), Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, accessed June 27, 2021,
https://www.economicinclusion.gov/surveys/2019household/.
9
It seems unlikely, for example, that people who avoid bank accounts because of concerns about privacy or
trust in the banking system, rather than the cost of such accounts, will greatly prefer having accounts with
the Federal Reserve.
7
8

- 11 households and businesses. An arrangement where the Federal Reserve replaces
commercial banks as the dominant provider of money to the general public could
constrict the availability of credit, fundamentally alter the economy, and expose the
public to a host of unanticipated, and undesirable, consequences. 10
Among other potential problems, a dominant CBDC could undermine the
consumer and other economic benefits that accrue when commercial banks compete to
attract customers.
A Federal Reserve CBDC could also present an appealing target for cyberattacks
and other security threats. Bad actors might try to steal CBDC, compromise the CBDC
network, or target non-public information about holders of CBDC. The architecture of a
Federal Reserve CBDC would need to be extremely resistant to such threats—and would
need to remain resistant as bad actors employ ever-more sophisticated methods and
tactics. Designing appropriate defenses for CBDC could be particularly difficult because,
compared to the Federal Reserve’s existing payment systems, there could be far more
entry points to a CBDC network—depending on design choices, anyone in the world
could potentially access the network. 11
Critically, we also would need to ensure that a CBDC does not facilitate illicit
activity. The Bank Secrecy Act currently requires that commercial banks take steps to

10

The Federal Reserve also needs to consider whether private-sector stablecoins could disintermediate
deposits out of the banking system, but in general, the risk of disintermediation should be lower for
stablecoins compared to a CBDC. Importantly, if a stablecoin is backed by short-term securities, the
stablecoin provider must take the funds received in return for the issuance of stablecoins and purchase
short-term securities for the stablecoin “anchor” pool. The seller of those securities will then take the funds
received and put them back into the banking system.
11
Private-sector stablecoins are also subject to cyber risk, of course, but any individual private stablecoin
network would be less systemic than a CBDC for an entire advanced economy, and private companies are
frequently better able to make the rapid and constant investment in technology required to keep current
with technological security threats.

- 12 guard against money laundering. 12 Policymakers will need to consider whether a similar
anti-money-laundering regime would be feasible for a Federal Reserve CBDC, but it may
be challenging to design a CBDC that respects individuals’ privacy while appropriately
minimizing the risk of money laundering. At one extreme, we could design a CBDC that
would require CBDC holders to provide the Federal Reserve detailed information about
themselves and their transactions; this approach would minimize money-laundering risks
but would raise significant privacy concerns. At the other extreme, we could design a
CBDC that would allow parties to transact on a fully anonymized basis; this approach
would address privacy concerns but would raise significant money-laundering risks.
A final risk is that developing a Federal Reserve CBDC could be expensive and
difficult for the Federal Reserve to manage. A Federal Reserve CBDC could, in essence,
set up the Federal Reserve as a retail bank to the general public. That would mean
introducing large-scale, resource-intensive central bank infrastructure. We will need to
consider whether the potential use cases for a CBDC justify such costs and expansion of
the Federal Reserve’s responsibilities into unfamiliar activities, together with the risk of
politicization of the Fed’s mandate that would come with such an expansion.
To conclude, I emphasize three points. First, the U.S. dollar payment system is
very good, and it is getting better. Second, the potential benefits of a Federal Reserve
CBDC are unclear. Third, developing a CBDC could, I believe, pose considerable risks.
So, our work is cut out for us as we proceed to rigorously evaluate the case for
developing a Federal Reserve CBDC. Even if other central banks issue successful
CBDCs, we cannot assume that the Federal Reserve should issue a CBDC. The process

12

See, e.g., 31 U.S.C. § 5318(h).

- 13 that Chair Powell recently announced is a genuinely open process without a foregone
conclusion, although obviously I think the bar to establishing a U.S. CBDC is a high one.
The upcoming discussion paper that constitutes the first step in this process will
importantly ask for input from the public. I look forward to reviewing public input on the
discussion paper, which will inform the Federal Reserve’s ultimate evaluation of a
potential CBDC.