View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
5:30 a.m. EST (11:30 a.m. local time)
November 14, 2023

Elevated Economic Uncertainty: Causes and Consequences
Remarks by
Philip N. Jefferson
Vice Chair
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
“Global Risk, Uncertainty, and Volatility,” a research conference sponsored by
the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Swiss National Bank, and the Bank for
International Settlements
Zurich, Switzerland

November 14, 2023

Introduction
Thank you for the opportunity to speak with you today. I am very much attuned
to the important work that you’re doing on uncertainty. Indeed, as a monetary
policymaker, the subject is rarely far from my mind. It’s not a new subject, of course.
John Maynard Keynes and Frank Knight provided book-length treatments of the subject a
century ago (Keynes, 1921; Knight, 1921). In addition, in 2003, Alan Greenspan
observed, “Uncertainty is not just an important feature of the monetary policy landscape;
it is the defining characteristic of that landscape” (Greenspan, 2003).
Before I begin, let me remind you that the views I express today are my own and
are not necessarily shared by my colleagues in the Federal Reserve System.
My plan is to talk about recent advances in how to measure uncertainty, what may
cause uncertainty, what effect uncertainty may have on economic outcomes, and the
conduct of monetary policy in the presence of uncertainty.
Defining and measuring uncertainty
Uncertainty is not directly observable in the same way inflation and economic
output are observable. It is therefore more difficult to measure. To complicate matters
further, there are three related concepts that are often used interchangeably: risk,
volatility, and uncertainty. According to Frank Knight, risk describes a situation in which
the outcome is unknown, but the probability distribution governing that outcome is
known. Volatility, often used synonymously with risk, is a statistical measure of the
variation in observed outcomes. In contrast, uncertainty is characterized by both an
unknown outcome and an unknown probability distribution. These concepts are used
interchangeably, in part, because empirically it can be difficult to identify them

-2separately, and because they all capture aspects of what policymakers do not know when
making decisions. Therefore, the uncertainty measures I will discuss are a mixture of
these three concepts, and a theme for me will be the necessity of monetary policymakers
to consider what they don’t know in their decisionmaking, an argument often attributed to
Friedrich Hayek (1974).
Notwithstanding the difficulty in measuring uncertainty, economists have
developed tools to assess it. In fact, in the past two decades, there has been tremendous
growth in research devoted to the subject. In my talk today, I will focus on four broad
categories of uncertainty measures: text-based, survey-based, econometric-based, and
financial market-based measures. 1 There have been advances in all four categories, and
there are advantages and disadvantages to each of these measures.
One example of text-based measures of uncertainty is that by Baker, Bloom, and
Davis (2016), who created an uncertainty index based on the number of leading
newspaper articles that contain a combination of words related to economic policy
uncertainty. They showed that newspaper text-based measures are highly correlated with
stock price volatility, and that higher values of these measures are associated with lower
investment and employment. An advantage of these measures is that they are highfrequency, real-time measures that can narrow the type of uncertainty being measured by
linking particular words regarding uncertainty to a specific topic, such as inflation or
monetary policy. A limitation of these measures is that they suffer from dual causality
with the economic outcomes we are trying to measure, and therefore it is difficult to use
them to ascertain what impact (if any) uncertainty has on economic outcomes. For
For a detailed description of these four categories of uncertainty measures, please see Cascaldi-Garcia and
others (2023).

1

-3example, does stock price volatility cause journalists to worry about uncertainty, or is the
uncertainty discussed in newspaper articles causing volatility? I note, though, that this
disadvantage is common to all four broad categories of uncertainty measures to greater or
lesser degrees.
The second set of uncertainty measures is survey based. These measures use
responses to questions by households, businesses, and market participants about their
forecasts and how certain they are about those forecasts. Advantages of survey-based
measures are that they are explicit about the segments of society facing uncertainty, and
they are relatively precise in pinpointing the horizon over which the uncertainty prevails.
Disadvantages are that these measures are not necessarily timely in capturing uncertainty
around fast-breaking new events, and, depending on the issue, they may be less
representative than those based on the news.
The third set of uncertainty measures is econometric based. In general, these
calculate how far off econometric model forecasts are from actual values at each point in
time. Intuitively, when uncertainty increases, it becomes harder to predict economic
variables. Advantages of these measures are that they are easy to interpret and calculate
and are less prone to dual causality associated with the economic outcomes of interest.
Disadvantages are that they are sensitive to the choice of the econometric forecasting
model used to calculate them, and their timeliness depends on the availability of the data
the forecasting model uses.
The last set of uncertainty measures is market-based measures, which use
financial market prices to estimate either realized volatility or option-implied volatility.
For example, one widely used uncertainty measure is the Chicago Board of Options

-4Exchange’s Volatility Index, the VIX, which is calculated using equity index options that
measure market participants’ expectations for the volatility of the S&P 500 index over
the coming 30 days. The advantages and disadvantages of these measures are similar to
the text-based measures: They are high-frequency, real-time estimates of market
participants’ views, but they suffer from dual causality with the economic outcomes we
are trying to measure. An additional disadvantage is that it is often difficult to specify the
type of uncertainty being measured.
Current state of uncertainty
Based on the range of measures discussed above, what can we say about the
current state of uncertainty? Figure 1 shows three measures of uncertainty. The red line
is an econometric-based measure constructed by Federal Reserve Board staff (Londono,
Ma, and Wilson, 2023) called U.S. economic uncertainty. According to this measure,
U.S. economic uncertainty reached an all-time high at the onset of the pandemic, came
down slightly after the pandemic, but has remained elevated ever since. Consistent with
this measure, policymakers, including Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
participants and central bankers around the globe, have been emphasizing the elevated
level of uncertainty, especially related to inflation, and the challenge this poses for
monetary policy. Since the onset of the pandemic, most FOMC participants have been
indicating in the Summary of Economic Projections that they view uncertainty around
their forecast of personal consumption expenditure inflation to be higher than the average
level of uncertainty over the past 20 years. But we policymakers are not alone in this.
The July 2023 and September 2023 issues of the Federal Reserve Beige Book, which
summarizes the commentary on current economic conditions of businesses, repeat the

-5words “uncertain” and “uncertainty” much more than the historical average and with
much of the uncertainty associated with inflation. 2
In contrast to policymakers and commentary from businesses and the
econometric-based U.S. economic uncertainty measure, the other two uncertainty
measures in figure 1—the VIX index, the black line, and the news-based economic policy
uncertainty measure, the blue line—declined quickly after the onset of the pandemic in
2020 and have remained relatively subdued since then. One interpretation of the
divergence in the measures is that they are capturing different aspects of uncertainty.
Over the past year or so, the lack of predictability of economic outcomes, as captured by
the elevated econometric-based U.S. economic uncertainty measure, did not lead to
heightened expectations of near-term equity market volatility by market participants or to
a higher frequency of discussions of economic policy uncertainty in the news. This leads
me to the next topics I want to discuss—namely, what causes uncertainty to increase, and
does it matter that the harder-to-predict outcomes are not correlated, at least for now, with
a higher VIX index?
What causes uncertainty to increase?
Figure 2 shows the econometric-based U.S. economic uncertainty measure since
1960, scaled in standard deviations from its mean. The figure illustrates a certainty about
uncertainty: Uncertainty tends to increase during recessions, the shaded gray areas in the
graph. Economic theory offers four mechanisms through which bad events—such as
recessions, oil supply disruptions, terrorist attacks, wars, and pandemics—can increase
uncertainty (Bloom, 2014). First, it is easier to predict the future when “business as

2

The historical average is computed over the sample period from 1996 to the present.

-6usual” prevails in a growing economy (Orlik and Veldkamp, 2022). Forecasting is harder
during recessions and when bad events hit the economy. This was especially the case
during the pandemic, a once-in-a-century disturbance of worldwide consequence. Some
have even argued that the pandemic has caused structural changes that will make it harder
to predict future economic outcomes. Second, when business is good, firms are trading
actively, which helps to generate and spread information (Van Nieuwerburgh and
Veldkamp 2006; Fajgelbaum, Schaal, and Taschereau-Dumouchel, 2017). Bad events
disrupt trading activity and the flow of information, and this lack of information increases
uncertainty. Third, public policy that is unclear, hyperactive, or both may raise
uncertainty (Pastor and Veronesi, 2013). Fourth, when business is slow, it is cheap to try
new ideas and to divert unused resources to research and development; this dynamic
leads to microeconomic uncertainty, which may in turn lead to macroeconomic
uncertainty (Bachmann and Moscarini, 2011; D’Erasmo and Moscoso-Boedo, 2011).
Of these four theoretical mechanisms, the first one strikes me as a highly likely
explanation for uncertainty remaining high today. We are still learning about the effects
of pandemic-specific factors on the economy. Additionally, heightened geopolitical risks
have recently contributed to increased uncertainty. 3
In figure 3, I decompose the econometric-based U.S. economic uncertainty
measure into three subcomponents to investigate which economic outcomes are harder to
predict since the pandemic and after the increase in geopolitical tensions. The
subcomponents are inflation indicators, the black line; labor market conditions, the red
line; and economic output, the blue line. All three subcomponents rose significantly

3

See, for example, Caldara and Iacoviello (2022) for a measure of geopolitical risk.

-7during the pandemic but have behaved quite differently since 2021, with inflation
uncertainty becoming the dominant source of aggregate economic uncertainty, especially
since the Russian invasion of Ukraine. A message one could take from this is that,
through the eyes of an econometrician with a rich set of predictors, inflation over the past
two years was objectively difficult to predict.
The rise in inflation and inflation uncertainty in the post-COVID era has been a
global phenomenon. The left panel of slide 7, figure 4.1, plots an econometric-based
foreign economic uncertainty index calculated as the equally weighted average of the
measures of 38 foreign countries. As in the case of the U.S. economic uncertainty index,
the foreign index spikes around the Global Financial Crisis and soars around the COVID
pandemic, and it has remained quite elevated since, at around 3 standard deviations from
its historical mean. The right panel of slide 7, figure 4.2, shows the components of
foreign economic uncertainty: inflation, the black line; labor, the red line; and output, the
blue line. Again, as in the U.S., foreign inflation uncertainty has become the dominant
source of economic uncertainty.
What effect may uncertainty have on economic outcomes?
Now that I have established that some measures of economic uncertainty are
elevated, one may wonder, to what extent does it matter? Economic theory offers at least
two channels for uncertainty to influence growth negatively. 4 The first channel comes
from the “real options” literature and the fact that the option value of waiting to make

Economic theory also offers at least two channels for uncertainty to influence growth positively. The
“growth options” theory argues that uncertainty can encourage investment if it increases the potential prize
(Bar-Ilan and Strange, 1996). The “Oi-Hartman-Abel” theory after Oi (1961), Hartman (1972), and Abel
(1983), argues that if firms can expand to exploit good outcomes and contract to insure against bad
outcomes, they may be risk loving.

4

-8decisions increases with uncertainty (for example, Bernanke, 1983). According to this
theory, it is optimal for firms to not invest and to not hire new employees when
uncertainty is high. This lack of investment and hiring in turn exacerbates recessions.
The second channel comes from the reaction of financial markets to uncertainty.
Investors require compensation for higher risk and uncertainty in the form of higher risk
premia, which manifests in lower equity prices, and higher borrowing costs. In the
presence of financial constraints, these tighter financial conditions will reduce economic
growth (for example, Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno, 2014). In addition, higher
uncertainty is often accompanied by higher equity market volatility and illiquidity, which
in turn exacerbates uncertainty. As I mentioned earlier, the elevated econometric-based
uncertainty measure this past year has not been accompanied by higher equity market
volatility, as measured by the VIX index. This suggests that the economic effects of the
higher economic uncertainty may be somewhat mitigated, relative to the more serious
case where higher economic uncertainty is accompanied by a higher VIX index
(Ludvigson, Ma, and Ng, 2021).
Because uncertainty can influence growth negatively, policymakers often aim to
reduce uncertainty about their objectives. One way they attempt to do this is by adopting
a systematic approach to achieving their objectives, as circumstances allow. This point
leads me to my final topic, the conduct of monetary policy in the presence of uncertainty.
What should policy makers do when uncertainty is high?
In 1967, William Brainard argued that uncertainty about the power of monetary
policy implied that policy should respond more cautiously to shocks than would be the
case if this uncertainty did not exist (Brainard, 1967). Brainard’s attenuation principle is

-9a classic example of what has come to be known as the Bayesian approach to uncertainty
and is often cited as the foundation for gradualism in the adjustment of monetary policy:
Calculate what you think your best policy response is for the economy you observe—and
then do less.
It is often suggested, however, that the ambiguity aversion approach to
uncertainty leads to anti-attenuation. That is, in the face of uncertainty over which a
policymaker is unwilling or unable to attach prior probabilities, the appropriate response
is to apply stronger monetary medicine than in the certainty equivalence case. For
example, as Chair Powell mentioned in a speech in 2018 that, during crisis periods,
words like “we will do whatever it takes” will likely be more effective than “we will take
cautious steps” (Powell, 2018).
Advocates for both approaches have their theoretical justifications. In practice,
however, the best response to uncertainty can be context specific and can vary over time. 5
Fortunately, sometimes the context leads to the same conclusion, broadly speaking,
regardless of the approach. One case of perennial interest to central bankers is inflation
persistence where both the Bayesian and ambiguity aversion approaches tend to lead to
policy that is stronger than the certainty equivalent case to forestall the possibility of
inflationary forces becoming embedded in inflation expectations. 6

See Barlevy (2011) for an accessible survey and Tetlow and von zur Muehlen (2001) for a more technical
treatment.
6
Bernanke (2007) and Powell (2018) highlight this case. Söderstöm (2002) establishes the result for the
Bayesian case. Tetlow (2019) is a simple demonstration of that case alongside the ambiguity aversion case.
Adam and Woodford (2012) show that uncertainty regarding the data generating process for inflation in the
New Keynesian model retains as the optimal policy the same general form as in the standard model but
with a more aggressive response to inflation.
5

- 10 Conclusions
Let me end where I began. Monetary policymakers need to consider what they
don’t know in their decisionmaking, along with what they do know. This is not a new
idea. We have long appreciated that policy decisions under uncertainty should consider a
range of possible scenarios about the state, and the structure, of the economy. Economic
history and recent research have sharpened some of the questions, even if they have not
produced the easy policy narratives we might prefer. What is clear is that policy
decisions taken under uncertainty may look quite different from those that would be
optimal under certainty, and properly so.
The fact that economic agents are uncertain about their environment and must
learn about the economy—and policy—means that monetary policy can be a positive
force in stabilizing expectations. In my thinking, this prospect serves as a reason for
central banks to strive for predictability and transparency in policy actions and
communications while avoiding the hubris of overrepresenting the state of our
knowledge.

- 11 References
Abel, Andrew B. (1983). “Optimal Investment under Uncertainty,” American Economic
Review, vol. 73 (March), pp. 228–33.
Adam, Klaus, and Michael Woodford (2012). “Robustly Optimal Monetary Policy in a
Microfounded New Keynesian Model,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 59
(July), pp. 468–87.
Bachmann, Ruediger, and Giuseppe Moscarini (2011). “Business Cycles and
Endogenous Uncertainty,” 2011 Meeting Papers 36, Society for Economic
Dynamics.
Baker, Scott R., Nicholas Bloom, and Steven J. Davis (2016). “Measuring Economic
Policy Uncertainty,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 131 (November), pp.
1593–636.
Bar-Ilan, Avner, and William C. Strange (1996). “Investment Lags,” American
Economic Review, vol. 86 (June), pp. 610–22.
Barlevy, Gadi (2011). “Robustness and Macroeconomic Policy,” Annual Review of
Economics, vol. 3, pp. 1–24.
Bernanke, Ben S. (1983). “Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and Cyclical Investment,”
Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 98 (February), pp. 85–106.
——— (2007). “Monetary Policy under Uncertainty,” speech delivered at the 32nd
Annual Economic Policy Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, October
19, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20071019a.htm.
Bloom, Nicholas (2014). “Fluctuations in Uncertainty,” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, vol. 28 (Spring), pp. 153–76.
Brainard, William C. (1967). “Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Policy,” American
Economic Review, vol. 57 (May), pp. 411–25.
Caldara, Dario, and Matteo Iacoviello (2022). “Measuring Geopolitical Risk,” American
Economic Review, vol. 112 (April), pp. 1194–225.
Cascaldi-Garcia, Danilo, Cisil Sarisoy, Juan M. Londono, Bo Sun, Deepa D. Datta,
Thiago Ferreira, Olesya Grishchenko, Mohammad R. Jahan-Parvar, Francesca
Loria, Sai Ma, Marius Rodriguez, Ilknur Zer, and John Rogers (2023). “What Is
Certain about Uncertainty?” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 61 (June), pp.
624–54.

- 12 Christiano, Lawrence J., Roberto Motto, and Massimo Rostagno (2014). “Risk Shocks,”
American Economic Review, vol. 104 (January), pp. 27–65.
D’Erasmo, Pablo N., and Hernan J. Moscoso-Boedo (2011). “Intangibles and
Endogenous Firm Volatility over the Business Cycle,” Virginia Economics
Online Papers 400, University of Virginia, Department of Economics.
Fajgelbaum, Pablo D., Edouard Schaal, and Mathieu Taschereau-Dumouchel (2017).
“Uncertainty Traps,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 132 (November), pp.
1641–92.
Greenspan, Alan (2003). “Monetary Policy under Uncertainty,” speech delivered at a
symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson
Hole, Wyoming, August 29,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003/20030829.
Hartman, Richard (1972). “The Effects of Price and Cost Uncertainty on Investment,”
Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 5 (October), pp. 258–66.
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1974). “The Pretence of Knowledge,” Alfred Nobel Memorial
Lecture delivered at the Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm, December
11.
Keynes, John Maynard (1921). A Treatise on Probability. London: Macmillan.
Knight, Frank H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Londono, Juan M., Sai Ma, and Beth Anne Wilson (2023). “Global Inflation Uncertainty
and its Economic Effects,” FEDS Notes. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, September 25, 2023,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/global-inflationuncertainty-and-its-economic-effects-20230925.html.
Ludvigson, Sydney C., Sai Ma, and Serena Ng (2021). “Uncertainty and Business
Cycles: Exogenous Impulse or Endogenous Response?” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 13 (October), pp. 369–410.
Oi, Walter Y. (1961). “The Desirability of Price Instability under Perfect Competition,”
Econometrica, vol. 29 (January), pp. 58–64.
Orlik, Anna, and Laura Veldkamp (2022). “Understanding Uncertainty Shocks and the
Role of the Black Swans,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2022-083.
Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December,
https://doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2022.083.

- 13 Pastor, Lubos, and Pietro Veronesi (2013). “Political Uncertainty and Risk Premia,”
Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 110 (December), pp. 520–45.
Powell, Jerome H. (2018). “Monetary Policy in a Changing Economy,” speech delivered
at “Changing Market Structure and Implications for Monetary Policy,” a
symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson
Hole, Wyoming, August 24,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20180824a.htm.
Söderstrom, Ulf (2002). “Monetary Policy with Uncertain Parameters,” Scandinavian
Journal of Economics, vol. 104 (March), pp. 125–45.
Tetlow, Robert (2019). “The Monetary Policy Response to Uncertain Inflation
Persistence,” Economics Letters, vol. 175 (February), pp. 5–8.
Tetlow, Robert, and Peter von zur Muehlen (2001). “Robust Monetary Policy with
Misspecified Models: Does Model Uncertainty Always Call for Attenuated
Policy?” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 25 (June), pp. 911–49.
Van Nieuwerburgh, Stijn, and Laura Veldkamp (2006). “Learning Asymmetries in Real
Business Cycles,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 53 (May), pp. 753–72.

Elevated Economic Uncertainty:
Causes and Consequences
Philip N. Jefferson
Vice Chair, Federal Reserve Board
GRUV, Nov. 14, 2023

Disclaimer: The views I will express today are my own and not necessarily those of the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) or the Federal Reserve System.

Roadmap of Talk
• Measurement of Uncertainty
• Causes of Uncertainty
• Impact of Uncertainty
• Policy Response Under Uncertainty

2

Four Broad Categories of
Uncertainty Measures
• Text-based
• Survey-based
• Econometric-based
• Financial market-based

3

4

5

6

7