View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
WEDNESDAY, JUNE 6, 1979
10:00 A.M. LONDON TIME (5:00 A.M. E.D.T.)




THE DOLLAR AS AN INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY

Remarks of

Philip E. Coldwell, Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the

1979 Central Banking Course of the Bank of England

London, England
June 6, 1979

The Dollar as an International Currency

The topic that I have been asked to address today is "The Dollar
as an International Currency." Fy discussion of thi & subject will focus on
four main issues.
currency."

First, a brief clarification of the term "international

Second, an analysis of why the dollar is an international currency.

Third, a discussion of the costs and benefits flowing from this role.

And

finally^a few remarks on why there is such strong interest in this subject
at the present time.
The term "international currency" can have several meanings.

For

the sake of clarity let me emphasize that I will use that term to refer to
a currency that is widely held outside of its country of issue.

Thus my

remarks will be primarily concerned with the question of why non-residents of
the United States hold dollars.

I

will not be directly concerned with the

related and important questions of whether these dollars are held by official
or private parties, or whether they are held in the form of liabilities of
institutions inside or outside the United States.
Just why do people residing in one country hold the currency of
another country?

To answer that question, we must first back up a bit and ask

why people hold the currency of their own country.
have traditionally given to that question is:

The answer that economists

because money facilitates the

exchange of goods9 services, and assets; it serves as a unit of account, a
temporary store of purchasing power, and a medium of exchange.

The views I will be expressing are my own and, of course, do not necessarily
reflect the views of others in the Federal Reserve System.




- 2 -

Thus residents of the United States hold dollars because they are
readily accepted in payment for a vast array of items -- the total "turnover"
flow of U.S. output (a number several times larger than the U.S. gross
national product), plus all of the assets in the United States.

This last

factor -- assets, especially financial assets -- deserves special emphasis, because
it not only provides a motive for holding dollars, but also a means of
doing so, since most "dollars" are held in the form of liquid interestbearing assets.
Finally, because the dollar is so useful for purchasing things
in the United States, and because it is so convenient to hold, residents
of other countries are often willing to accept dollars in payment for goods,
services, and assets located outside of the United States.

Indeed, they

have even developed their own dollar financial markets, i.e., the Euro­
dollar market.

This in turn has led to something of a "feedback effect,V

making U.S. residents even more willing to hold dollars because they can also
be used to purchase items abroad.
The same reasons that explain why residents of the United States
hold dollars
dollars:

go a long way toward explaining why non-residents also hold

because they want some store of value that is readily accepted in

payment for a very large collection of items.
But why, we might ask, do not non-residents simply hold their own currencies
and then exchange them for dollars whenever they want to make payment in dollars?
One reason has already been alluded to:

because the

very large and open

dollar financial markets throughout the world make it very convenient to hold
dollars.

In addition there are two other reasons -- exchange-rate uncertainty

and foreign exchange market transaction costs -- each of which I will discuss
in turn,,
A non-resident of the United States who expects to purchase dollardenominated goods in the future might prefer to know with relative certainty




-

3

-

the quantity of dollar-denominated goods he has command over.
accomplish by holding dollar-denominated liquid assets.

This he can

If instead, he holds

liquid assets denominated in another currency, he is continually faced with the
uncertainty of not knowing how many dollars he can purchase with that currency
in the future, and, consequently, the quantity of dollar-denominated goods he
can purchase.
Ii, in addition, this non-resident regularly receives dollars in payment,
then he would also have a transaction cost incentive to hold dollars, i.e.,
instead of converting his dollar receipts into another currency and then converting
them back again when he wants to make payment in dollars, he can save the trans­
action cost twice by simply holding the dollars.

And of course if his government

places additional barriers in the way of exchanging currencies (i.e., if it has
exchange controls), then this gives him an even greater incentive to hold dollars.
Finally there is another important consideration that is relevant
to the decision of non-residents (or residents) to hold dollars —

the

difference between the expected rate of return on dollar-denominated liquid assets
and the expected rate of return on liquid assets denominated in other currencies.
This relative rate of return involves both the interest rate differential between the
United States and other countries (adjusted for differences in risk) and the expected
rate of appreciation (or depreciation) of the dollar relative to other currencies.
In this regard it is interesting to note that from one narrow
theoretical point of view a higher rate of inflation j>er se does not necessarily
make a currency less desirable as an international currency.

This is the cane

if (a) real interest rates are not affected by the rate of inflation, (b) nominal
interest rates adjust to incorporate a full inflation premium, and (c) currencies
depreciate or appreciate at a rate just sufficient to offset differences
in relative inflation rates.




- 4 -

However, in actual practice these perfect adjustments seldom
occur.

seem to

In particular when a country's rate of inflation increases, its exchange

rate seems to depreciate by more than is necessary simply to offset the higher
price level.

Perhaps this is because an increase in the inflation rate is

usually associated with a period of rapid rea.1 economic growth, and the latter
causes an increase in imports and a deterioration of the trade and current account
balances.

Or perhaps it is because people tend to form their expectations about

the future rate of inflation by extrapolating the rate of increase of the current
inflation rate; hence when the inflation rate rises, their expectations of the
future inflation rate rise even more.
In addition to affecting the exchange rate, a higher rate of inflation
also seems to lower the real rate of interest.
that higher rates of inflation increase

uncertainty about the future price level,

thereby increasing the riskiness of investment
rate of return.

One reason for this is probably

and lowering the risk-adjusted

Another reason is that, under current-accounting systems, inflation

causes the actual value of capital consumed in production to be understated and
hence profits to be overstated.

This in turn increases the effective tax rate

on real capital income, and decreases the after-tax return on investment.
Thus, for all of these reasons, an increase in the inflation rate in a given
country usually does lower the rate of return on liquid assets denominated in that
country1s currency, and thus makes it less desirable as an international currency.
To summarize the discussion up to this point, we should expect that
a given countryfs currency will tend to be used as an international currency,




a) to the extent that its flow of goods and services, and
especially its stock of financial assets, &re large relative
to the rest of the world (and, because of the

feedback effect,

we should expect the currency of the wealthiest country to
enjoy a particular advantage over the others),

- 5 -

b) to the extent that it allows non-residents to freely p u r ­
chase its g o o d s y services, and a s s e t s \ and,

c) to the extent that the expected rate of return on liquid
assets denominated in that currency, adjusted for risk, is
higher than in other countries.

These factors help explain why the dollar gradually came to replace
the pound sterling as the leading international currency.

They also suggest

that the dollar will likely remain the leading international currency for some
time to come.

The main reason for this of course is the very great size of the

U.S. economy, which is more than three times as great as that of Japan, the next
largest free world economy.

Of particular importance is the great breadth,

depth, and efficiency of U.S. financial markets, which make it extremely
convenient to hold liquid doliar-denominated interest-bearing assets.

Second

in importance is the almost complete openness of the U.S. economy -- there are
very few barriers to prevent non-residents from purchasing dollars or
using them to aequire goods, services, and assets in the United States.
Related to this factor is the low level of political risk associated with
investments in the United States.

Few countries in the world have such a deeply

ingrained and legally codified respect for property rights, such a long history
of political and economic stability, and such security from foreign conquest.
A few numbers may help to illustrate the present importance of the
dollar as an international currency:

about 4/5 of all official foreign exchange

reserves are held in dollars; about 3/4 of Euro-currency assets and liabilities
are in dollars; and about 1/2 of world trade is denominated in dollars.
However, over the last few decades the economies of some other major
countries have been growing more rapidly than has the U.S. economy, and, much




- 6 -

more recently, some have had more success in the battle against inflation.

These

two factors might lead one to expect that other currencies might gradually play
an increasing role as international currencies.

However, it should be noted

that few countries seem anxious to have their currencies used for this purpose,
and several have taken active steps to discourage non-residents from purchasing
their liquid financial assets.
This last point leads me to the second topic in my talk today:
costs and benefits from being an international currency.

the

Why is it that the

United States is willing to have its currency used as an international currency,
but other countries are not?

Is one of us incorrectly calculating the costs

and benefits associated with that role?
Let me begin this part of the discussion by emphasizing the fact that
the United States enjoys very little "seignorage gain11 in the traditional sense
in which that term is used, i.e., the gain that accrues to a government when
it issues paper money or token coins -- assets that cost only a fraction of their
face value to produce, which pay no interest, and which can be exchanged for
useful goods and services or other assets.

The vast majority of the "dollars11

held by non-residents are interest-bearing assets -- they consist of instruments
such as U.S. Treasury bills, certificates-of-deposit, and Euro-dollar deposits.
Thus the effect on the United States from the use of the dollar as
an international currency is essentially that of a capital inflow.

And the

classical theory of international factor movements tells us that this confers a
net welfare gain on both the United States and the rest of the world.

The

United States benefits because dollar interest rates are slightly lower than
they would be otherwise; the rest of the world benefits because it is able to
obtain an asset that offers a higher expected return in terms of yield,




- 7 -

liquidity, safety, and utility than does the closest available substitute.
From a more intuitive point of view it seems reasonable that both parties to
the transaction should gain, because the transaction is undertaken voluntarily.
And, as with any voluntary transaction, both parties must perceive a gain from
it, or otherwise at least one of them would not enter into it.
The costs to the United States resulting from the fact that the dollar
is used as an international currency are essentially dependence and vulnerability.
This is just a special case of the general principle that anyone who engages in
a voluntary exchange with someone else sustains the risk that the other
party might suddenly decide to stop exchanging.

For most transactions, most

people have concluded that this risk is well worth bearing, i.e., tnat it is
better to enjoy the gains from trade and incur the risk that the trade may
be cut off, rather than to cut off the trade yourself, thereby foregoing the
gains from trade and inflicting on yourself now the harm you fear someone
else may inflict on you in the future# The only significant exception to
this general conclusion involves items of military importance.
In the case of the dollar being used as an international currency,
the United States bears the risk that non-residents may suddenly decide, for
whatever reason, to hold fewer dollars than before, i.e., there may be air
incipient capital outflow from the United States.

If this should occur,

it would put upward pressure on dollar interest races and downward pressure on
the foreign exchange value of the dollar.

The latter would in turn tend to

lower the foreign currency price of U.S. goods, which, over time, would increase
the demand for U.S. goods from abroad.

The converse side of this risk is that

non-residents may suddenly increase their demand for dollars, putting down­
ward pressure on dollar interest rates and upward pressure on the dollar in the
foreign exchange market, with the latter causing a reduced demand for U.S. exports.




- 8 -

For the United States these "risk costs" do not appear large.

The

United States exports only about 7-8 per cent of its gross national product.
Hence a change in the exchange rate has only small effects on our levels of
prices and ouput.

The staff of the Federal Reserve Board estimates that a

10 per cent appreciation of the dollar against a weighted average of 10 major
/reign currencies would lower the U.S. price level over a period of several
years by only about 1-1/2 to 2 per cent, and it would have almost no effect
on U.S. real GNP.

And there is only a very small chance that the dollar would

depreciate or appreciate by as much as 10 per cent solely as a result: of
the fact that it is held by foreigners.
Another related concern is that the dollar holdings of non-residents
may be volatile, in the sense that they may go through large swings over short
periods of time -- swings that are later reversed.

This would presumably be

less troublesome for macroeconomic policy than large once-and-for-all capital
inflows or outflows, because it would have smaller net effects on the price
level and aggregate demand.

Nonetheless,

it would impose short run adjustment

costs, and it might be wise for the United States to cope with such reversible
flows -- if they could be recognized as such -- with offsetting intervention in
the foreign exchange market.
The costs and benefits discussed thus far have been limited to a
narrow economic context, the way economists conventionally analyze the gains from
exchange.

However, in a broader sense it might be argued that there are

additional costs and benefits associated with the dollar being used as an
international currency.

For example some people claim that this international

le for the dollar places restraints on the freedom of U.S. economic policy,
and that this in turn reduces ecqj^fnic ^el^jre.
This line of argument ;^|s ¿very difficult to analyze, for at least two
\- \

reasons»




' vv

First, it is not c 1e a r N ^ w much,

dollar!s role as an international

- 9 -

currency constrains U.S. policy, and, secondly, it is not clear that, to the
extent there is a constraint, it necessarily tends to reduce the economic
well-being of the American people.
To take a case in point, last November 1, U.S. domestic economic
policy became significantly more restrictive, partly in response to the substantial
depreciation of the dollar that took place in the weeks and months before that
date.

Was this a case of the dollarfs international role constraining U.S.

policy and reducing economic welfare?

I think not.

First, it is not clear

that the dollar fs role as an international currency caused the dollar to fall
significantly further and faster than would otherwise have been the case.
Second, and more importantly, it is even less clear that the actions taken on
November 1 will reduce the welfare of our citizens.
would I —

Many would argue —

as

that the high rate of inflation in the United States was distorting

and debilitating the U.S. economy and seriously reducing its efficiency,
and that the sharp depreciation of the dollar that occurred prior to November 1
contributed to modifications in the direction of policies that were in our own
best interest.
When all of these cost and benefit considerations are taken inta
account, it is my judgment that the benefits to the United States and the
rest of the world from the use of the dollar as an international currency
easily exceed the costs.

Thus if the United States were to discourage non­

residents from holding dollars, I think both the United States and the rest
of the world would be worse aff as a result.
On the other other hand I do not think that the United States should
artifically encourage non-residents to hold dollars.

If an alternative to the

dollar should emerge -- either another major currency, the European Currency
Unit, or the SDR —
development.




the United States should do nothing to hinder its natural

As with other international transactions, our guiding principle

- l O -

in this matter should be to allow individual transactors the maximum freedom
to act in their own best interest, free from government encouragement or dis­
couragement .
Similarly, with regard to the recent discussion of a possible IMF sub­
stitution account, the United States should carefully evaluate this innovation
in the context of the longer-term evolution of the international financial
system to ensure that it is compatible with the freedom of all countries to
pursue appropriate domestic economic policies and that it does not restrict
the free international flow of capital.
Finally, in closing, let me pose the question of why there is so
much interest at the present time in the role of the dollar as an international
currency.

In my judgment this is because many people associated the sharp

depreciation of the dollar that occurred from September 1977 through October
1978 with the fact that the dollar is widely held abroad.

This, I think, is

a misconception.
The staff of the Federal Reserve Board has recently estimated that
the gross total of identifiable dollar-denominated assets (not including direct
investments and intér-bank accounts) that were owned by foreigners at the end
of 1977 amounted to about $425 billion.

This is less than one-tenth of the

total stock of liquid dollar-denominated assets that are available for sale
against foreign currencies.

Indeed, it is not even necessary to hold dollars

in order to sell them; dollars can be borrowed, or they can be sold short in
the forward exchange market.

Thus, even if foreigners held no dollars at all,

there would be ample opportunity for both residents and non-residents to sell
dollars, should a decline in its value be anticipated.




- 11 -

In my judgment if we are concerned about a potential resumption of
the downward movement of the dollar that occurred before last November 1, then
we should not focus our attention on any particular class of dollar holders,
but instead should concentrate on the reasons why anyone -- resident or non­
resident -- should wish to sell dollars.

Several factors need to be watched:

the sharp widening of the U.S. trade and current account deficits over the last
two years and the increase in the U.S. inflation rate relative to other countries -both of which were mainly due to the more rapid economic expansion in the United
States than abroad,

In addition market perceptions of the trends in the U.S.

economy and its relative vulnerability to external shocks are also factors
causing a shift in the willingness of people to hold dollars.
The first two problems have lessened with the slowing of the U.S.
economy, and the other factors now appear to be favoring dollar holdings.

Thus

the pressure for a rising dollar value has replaced the downward pressures of
last fall.

But rapid movements in either direction are destabilizing to

internal and external trade and financial relationships, and therefore I hope
we can look forward to a future of greater dollar stability and less concern
about the role of the dollar as an international currency, however that role
may gradually evolve.




mm