View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Fororelease on delivery

PStiP.M., E.D.T.

1385

Statement by

Paul A. Vclcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Subcommittee on Telecommunications, Consumer
Protection and Finance
of the
Committee on Energy and Commerce
House of Representatives

June 26, 1985

I appreciate this opportunity to present the views
of the Federal Reserve on regulation of the market for
Treasury and Federally sponsored agency securities.

My

remarks will be relatively brief, Mr. Chairman, because
your Subcommittee is already well informed about the developments that have prompted consideration of the need for formal
regulation of these markets.
I

By way of background, however,

should emphasize two points.
First, the problems that have arisen recently have not

substantially affected the core of the government securities
market —- that is, the dealers accounting for the bulk
of trading activities, engaging more or less continuously in
market-making, and participating regularly in the distribution
of new Treasury securities.

Consequently, the market has

continued to function with a high degree of efficiency and
liquidity.
Second, the failure of some dealers operating at the
periphery of the market, boch in recent months and in earlier



-2incidents^ did have severe adverse repercussions for some
customers•

The insolvency of a number of thrift institutions

was precipitated, while other institutions involved in financing
or servicing the fringe dealers were placed in some jeopardy.
In our highly interrelated and interdependent financial markets,
these developments carried at least the seeds of more widespread
systemic problems.
In reviewing these circumstances, we have concluded that
legislative authority providing for registration, appropriate
record-keeping, and inspection of those representing to deal
in government and federally sponsored agency securities is
desirable, and certain minimal regulatory authority should be
provided with respect to certain trading practices*

We also

believe, however, that the legislation should be framed in a
manner to avoid unnecessarily detailed and costly regulation
and supervision—that the mandate given to the regulatory body
or bodies should provide only limited powers directly related
to the integrity of trading practices.




-3As you know, the Federal Reserve already exercises
a degree of surveillance over the government securities
markets as an integral part of our responsibilities for
conducting open market operations, for monetary policyf and
for acting as fiscal agent in the sale and transfer of Treasury
and certain sponsored-agency debt.

That surveillance activity

has centered particularly on the so-called primary dealers—those with whom we have (or are contemplating) a business
relationship.

It is aimed in the first instance at informing

ourselves of the financial condition of our counterparties in
transactions.

That surveillance also encourages the maintenance

of liquid markets for our open market operations and the Treasury's
sales of securities.
Rather close surveillance of those with whom we d e a l tine 36 so-called primary dealers-~is' a. natural outgrowth of our
business relationship.

It has appeared to work effectively,

and is not dependent on legislation.

In all our considerations

of the need for legislation, we, the Treasury, and the SEC,
have assumed this surveillance of the primary dealers by the



-4Federal Reserve will be maintained in essentially the current
mode*
While the primary dealers account for the bulk
of dealer participation in the government and "agency"
markets, activities of others have apparently been expanding.
In response, the Federal Reserve began to gather data, on a
voluntary basis, from dealers with which we do not trade.
We have taken other steps, such as suggesting capital adequacy
guidelines and educating investors and lenders in appropriate
techniques, to protect the integrity of the marketplace.
However, developments also suggest the inherent limitations
of such a voluntary approach.

The Federal Reserve has no

authority over the "fringe" dealers, cannot examine them,
and does not have a business relationship with them.

Under

those conditions, a dealer wishing to avoid official scrutiny
or surveillance can do so.

Consequently, our present approach,

for other than primary dealers, cannot be counted on to minimize
fraudulent behavior or excessive risk-taking at the expense
of third parties.



Indeed, a purely voluntary surveillance

•" D ""

program runs the risk of seeming to offer more assurance
to customers of these dealers than in fact it can deliver

—

a position in which we do not wish to find ourselves.
The SEC has reviewed with you steps taken by other
regulatory and advisory bodies and investors to help further
assure the integrity of the marketplace.

These steps are

constructive, and if maintained, will certainly help greatly
to guard against a repetition of recent problems.

We

support those efforts.
At the same time, we recognize that, contrary to our
own earlier expectations, this kind of market and regulatory
response after previous problems materialized did not prove
fully adequate.

Nor can new legislative authorities or

regulatory approaches provide assurance against all fraud,
excessive risk, or new weaknesses in trading practices.
Nonetheless,, we now believe the balance of consideration does
point to a more formal process of registration,, inspection,
and regulation for all government securities dealers, provided
such official intrusion is limited only to areas at the core

http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/ of our
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

concerns•

-6The potential costs of highly detailed and expansive
regulations are real.

We want to preserve the extraordinary

liquidity and resiliency of the largest financial market in
the world•

Those characteristics help make Treasury securities

a unique investment vehicle for both domestic and foreign
holders, and an efficient market is essential both to the
Treasury in selling its securities and to the Federal Reserve
in conducting monetary policy.

We want to preserve free entry

and to avoid imposing heavy operating costs.

Registration

and rule-making need not deal with the complexities of other
markets involving many different issuers and less standard
financing instruments.
In our view, any structure of regulation for the Treasury
market should embody—and be confined to—three principal
elements.
First, it should provide for registration of dealers
and for authority to bar or limit the participation of those who,
through violations of securities laws or otherwise, have clearly
demonstrated that they should not be allowed to occupy a position



of trust in the government securities markets.

While a

registration requirement can raise difficult issues, including
the necessity to define a dealer, it is important that those
who have been disciplined in other markets not be allowed to
find refuge in trading government securities—the verysecurities investors turn to for assurance of relative safety
and liquidity.
Second, registration implies the need for certain
minimum guidelines for record-keeping and auditing so that
continued adherence to the standards established for registered
dealers can be monitored*

To assure the accuracy of these

reports and conformance to standards, legislation should
include the authority to inspect registered dealers on a
regular basis and when problems are suspected.
Finally, there should be some mechanism for writing
and enforcing rules to foster the financial soundness of
government securities dealers and to encourage, in a limited area,
market practices consistent with the safety and. efficiency of the




— Q —

market.

Obvious cases in point are guidelines with respect

to capital and such practices as the collateralization of
RP's.

Legislation might permit regulation of certain other

practices—such as appropriate margins or when-issued trading—
if needed, but authority should be confined to areas that
involve a direct threat to the integrity of the marketplace.
Inevitably, even such limited regulation as we would
contemplate would entail some costs.

There would be expenses

arising directly out of the process of writing, enforcing, and
complying with the regulations.

These would be borne by

dealers and their customers in a manner that is not easily
identified.

But these administrative costs would appear to

be quite modest, relative to the size of the market.

Provided

the basic efficiency and liquidity of the market is not impaired,•
interest costs should not be affected.

It is concern over the

latter possibility that militates against the degree of regulation
characteristic of other securities markets.

Within the limited

framework proposed, regulation could reinforce the performance
of, and confidence in, the market


-9Failure to regulate may itself have costs.

Savers

and taxpayers in Ohio and Maryland can testify that difficulties in the Government securities market can have costly
repercussions beyond the parties directly involved in the
securities transactions themselves.

More generally, loss

of confidence as a result of failures in sectors of the
market could affect other soundly operated, capitalized, and
financed dealers, and potentially affect trading conditions
generally.
With respect to the specific structure of rulemaking
and oversight, we believe that the approach of HR 2032 would
point to overly detailed regulation•

We have sympathy for

the concept of using a self-regulatory organization to write
rules and of employing existing regulatory bodies or SROs to
enforce them.

However, we do not believe the Municipal

Securities Rulemaking Board (MSRB) provides an appropriate
base for such an entity.

Its traditions and methods of

approach, are inappropriate to the government securities
market, and the giant of authority provided by HR 2032 is



-10overlyabroad.

We also question whether the SEC, acting alone,

is the most suitable agency to exercise ultimate oversight
authority over the market for Treasury and sponsored-agency
securities.
There are large differences between the tax-exempt and
taxable government markets.

The former deals with a multitude

of issuers of varying credit quality, underwriting is usually
done by syndicates of dealers with securities frequently
awarded on a negotiated rather than competitive bid basis,
and a much higher proportion of final sales are to relatively
small individual investors.

Those circumstances may well

warrant a comprehensive set of regulations governing many
aspects of dealer behavior, as the MSRB has issued.

But

those regulations, by and large, do not provide an appropriate
starting point for regulating the government securities market,
and would, in fact, impose unnecessary and excessive burdens.
For example, in the context of the limited number of issuers and
issues and the sophistication of customers in the Treasury and
agency markets, detailed rules in such areas of MSRB concern as



-11customer suitability, competitive practices and dealer
education do not appear necessary*

On the other hand, the

MSRB has no experience in regulating RP's—a first priority
of rulemaking in the Treasury market—since this form of
financing is not so commonly used in the municipal market.
If an SRO were to be established as the appropriate
rule-making body for the government and agency securities
markets, we believe its responsibilities should be limited
to those unique markets.

Moreover/ the Federal Reserve has

a body of expertise and substantive concerns that, in our
view, suggests more than a consultative role in overseeing an
SRO.

The interests of the Treasury and SEC would also need to

be taken into account.
Last week, Chairman Shad described to you a proposed
regulatory structure emerging from discussions among the
Federal Reserve, Treasury, and SEC.

That approach provides

an acceptable alternative framework to an SRO.

The elements

we consider essential for legislation are included:

registration^

inspection? and provision for limited regulation of financial



-12standards and key market practices.

Properly implemented,

the principal benefits of regulation could be captured at low
cost.
Some legislative proposals would empower the Federal Reserve,
to inspect and enforce regulations for primary dealers.

We

will in any event need to continue our surveillance of all
primary dealers through the Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
and I do not believe we need any new or special legislative
base for that effort.

We will continue to insist that primary

dealers play an active role in Treasury financing operations
and will continue to collect data from them that we need on
a regular and frequent basis.

And we would anticipate that

they will continue to meet high financial standards, even
beyond those required of other dealers.
In conclusion, Mr. Chairman, the Federal Reserve supports
legislation providing for registration, inspection, and limited
regulation of dealers in government and sponsored-agency
securities.




However, we share the concerns expressed by

-13others that HR 2032, as draftedf does not provide an appropriate
framework for such regulation.
We do find the joint Treasury-SEC-Federal Reserve plan
acceptable for these purposes.

We do not exclude the possibility

that other regulatory structures—including a SRO rule-making
body—could work as well, or even better.
We would, of course, be glad to work further with the
Subcommittee in developing these concepts into appropriate
legislation.




* * * * * * *