View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 A.M., E.S.T.
February 2, 1987

Statement by
Paul A. Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Joint Economic Committee

February 2, 1987

I am pleased to appear once again before this Committee
to discuss the economic situation.

As you know, the Federal

Reserve will be submitting its semi-annual report on monetary
policy to Congress later this month.

My testimony at that

time will provide a full account of recent monetary developments and will report on the decisions to be made by the
Federal Open Market Committee regarding money and credit
targets /for 1987.

Therefore, in my statement today I will

be emphasizing more general considerations of domestic and
international economic policies.
The economy is now in the fifth year of expansion,
making it among the longest.

During this time about 11-1/2

million jobs have been created, and the unemployment rate
has fallen more than 4 percentage points from its peak in
1982, reaching 6-3/4 percent in December.

In contrast to

the experience of the 1970s, real incomes of households have
risen steadily in recent years.




In the business sector,

— 2—

after tax profits have recovered both absolutely and relative
to overall GNP.

Interest rates, in contrast to the usual

cyclical pattern? are lower today than when the expansion
started.
These substantial economic gains were accompanied by
and I believe fundamentally dependent upon —

—

consistent progress

toward the objective of overall price stability.

Consumer prices

rose a scant 1.1 percent last year and producer prices actually
declined —

a performance unrivaled since the early 1960s.

We knowf of course, that that extraordinary progress
reflected, in large measure, the transitory influence of the
sharp drop in oil prices that occurred early last year; that
movement has been partially reversed recently.

Moreover,

given the size of the fall in dollar exchange rates against
other leading industrialized countries, increases in some
important import prices are occurring.

Because of those factors,

we cannot reasonably expect so satisfactory a statistical result
in 1987.




There is, however, encouraging evidence of continuing

-3restraint on costs and in pricing behavior.

Most significantlyf

the trend toward moderation in nominal wage and salary increases
has continued in almost all sectors of the economy and
productivity gains in manufacturing (if not in other sectors)
have been sizable during the expansion.
My purpose, however, is not to express satisfaction
or complacency over past performance.

What will count is

whether we can build upon and sustain that progress.

And

the obstacles and roadblocks are evident.
You are all too familiar with regional and sectoral
disparities in performance.

Manufacturing has been relatively

sluggish for two years or more.

Much of agriculture is

depressed despite massive federal assistance.
industry has been hard hit.

The energy

Conversely, employment in

services and finance has been rapidly expanding.
Overall, it is higher levels of consumption that have
been driving the economy over the past two years, while investment
and domestic savings have lagged, hardly a sustainable combination,




-4The exuberance of financial markets and the rapid pace
of debt creation have been accompanied by evident pressures
on some sectors of the financial system, rising loan losses,
and the risks implied by greater leveraging of many businesses.
Plainly, in their particulars, many of the strains and
imbalances in our economy can be traced to specific circumstances
beyond the reach of broad fiscal or monetary policies.

For

instance, there is a worldwide tendency toward growing
surpluses of basic agricultural commodities.

The sharp break

in oil prices has also been an international market event.

Both

of those circumstances have contributed to the strains on
some lending institutions.

But through it all, two disturbing

(and partly related) currents run strongly —
budget deficits.

Those are matters that must be addressed

indeed can only be constructively addressed —
national policies.

our trade and

by appropriate

And if we delay, the adjustments become

even more difficult, compounding the risks for the future.




—

-5The direct effects of the trade deficit are clear
enough.

Burgeoning imports over several years, while exports

in real terms have risen much more slowly, largely account for
the overall sluggishness of manufacturing.

With capacity

ample, that sluggishness feeds back on spending for plant
and equipment.
The effects of the budget deficit, in current
circumstances, may be less obvious —

after all, as many

have noted, interest rates have fallen while the deficits
have been so large, the huge new issues of Treasury securities
have found a market, and private debt creation has been high as
well.

How is that possible when, to take one simple benchmark,

our federal deficit has averaged about two-thirds of the
net savings generated by our economy over the past four years?
In effect, the answer is that we are drawing on the
savings of others —

in 1986, the net influx of foreign capital

appears to have exceeded all the savings generated by individuals
in the United States.

That capital influx is the mirror image

of the deficit in our current account —



we cannot, at one

-6and the same time, borrow abroad (net) to cover a domestic
investment-savings imbalance and run a balanced current account*
In a sense we have been fortunate.

We have been able

to increase consumption rather rapidly, sustain overall growth
and reduce inflation and interest rates even in the face of a
large federal budget deficit by calling upon other nations1
savings —

which they have readily provided*

But the cost has

been a rising trade deficit and increasing international
indebtedness, strong pressures on manufacturing in the here
and now, and an unsustainable pattern of economic activity for
the future fraught with political as well as economic risks.
Stated simply, we are living beyond our means —

indi-

viduals, businesses, and government have collectively been spending
more than we produce.

That might be acceptable JL£ we were

matching the foreign borrowing with a surge in productive
investment in the United States.

That's been the case at

times in the distant past in the United States and in other
countries more recently.
now —



But we are not making that match

it's consumption that's been leading the economic parade.

-7In that context, the challenge for economic policy
over the next few years is clear enough.

We have to work

toward better external and internal balance at the same time.
The adjustments required are large.

Given our extended position,

the difficulties and risks are substantial.

We don't want to

achieve the needed external adjustments by recession nor can
we reasonably float off our debts by rekindling inflation

—

and I don't think it's realistic to think we have the option
of trading one of those possibilities for the other.
That may sound like abstractions.

I will be more

specific.
One requirement is progress in reducing our trade
deficit.

That, on the face of it, will bring benefits to

manufacturing in the United States.

The potential is huge

—

to close our $150 billion trade deficit by increased manufacturing
(and I don't see any other practical avenue) implies a 15 to 20
percent increase in industrial output over the coming years
above and beyond that required to support domestic growth.




-8While a surge of that kind would be welcome in many respectsf
the challenge is to achieve it without renewed inflationary
pressure in that sector.

That will require continuing restraint

on costs, more modernization, and in time more capacity, which
in turn will require both money and real resources.
By definition, as we close the current account deficit,
those funds and real resources will no longer be available from
abroad.

So we will have to increase our own savings or reduce

other demands on savings at home.

The obvious candidate

—

again, as a practical matter, it must be the largest "contributor11
is a reduction in our federal budget deficit.

And, unless

productivity in the economy as a whole is to dramatically
increase above the recent trend of 1% or so —
there is no solid evidence for that —

and unhappily

we will not be able to

close the gap in trade and meet our domestic investment needs
without slowing the growth in domestic consumption well below
the 4% pace it has averaged during the current expansion.




—

-9In concept, all those things are "doable.11

They

provide the outline of an appropriate economic strategy.

The

result would be a more balanced economy, greatly enhancing
the prospects for sustained growth and greater exchange rate
and financial stability.
In fact, I believe we are beginning to make progress
in the required directions.
only set the stage.




But in a sense, we have so far

Many difficult decisions lie ahead.

In the current fiscal year, some significant
progress toward reducing the extraordinary
budget deficit appears to be underway.

But

as you well know, sustaining that progress will
require still more difficult decisions this year,
and for the years beyond.

The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings

targets have signaled your intentions, but more
important than those numerical targets is specific
action by the Congress to ensure that the deficit
will in fact continue to decline year by year.




-10Without that progress, it's difficult to see
how we could manage to reduce the trade deficit -and with it the net capital flow from abroad

—

without jeopardizing growth, progress toward lower
interest rates, and financial and price stability
at home.
The large realignment of exchange rates over the
past two years should enable our industry to compete
much more aggressively with other major industrialized
countries.

But that constructive development should

not obscure the fact that a declining dollar at some
point has high costs and risks as well.
inflationary pressures.

It generates

Uncertainties about the

future direction of currency values could dampen the
willingness of others to place or maintain funds
in the United States —

funds upon which, for the

time being, we are utterly dependent to finance
internal needs.




-11A self-generating cumulative process of
currency depreciation and inflation serves no
one's interest.

Economic history is littered

with examples of countries that acted as if currency
depreciation alone could substitute for other action
to restore balance and competitiveness to their
economies.
That history emphasizes the need for national
policy to remain strongly oriented toward
maintaining greater price stability.

As I

indicated earlier, the good performance of the
key price indices in 1986 probably can't be
matched this year as we absorb higher import
prices and oil prices no longer fall.

But

monetary policy, in particular, must remain
alert to the need to avoid any sense of cumulating
inflationary pressures.




-12Over the past year or more* as inflation has
subsided and with limited economic growth* the
Federal Reserve has been able to accommodate a
rapid growth in money and the discount rate has
been reduced on several occasions*

Clearly,

renewed inflationary pressures and weakness in
the dollar externally would be factors limiting
our flexibility.

In that context, your efforts to

deal with the budget deficit are even more central
to the financial and economic outlook*
In the end, the efficiency, competitiveness,
and salesmanship of U.S. industry, and its
ability to resist cost increases, will be
critical.

As I indicated earlier, there are

encouraging signs of improved productivity in
manufacturing.

As a result, profits and cash flow

have been reasonably well maintained even as prices
of goods have remained virtually stable.




-13All that has been achieved during a period
of intense competitive pressure from abroad and
at a time of little growth.

The challenge will

be to maintain that performance as prices of
competitive imports increase, as export markets
improve, and as new needs for capacity arise*

If

not, the gains from the realignment of currencies
will be frittered away.
The point has often been made that despite the
longer-run benefits for the economy as a whole,
recent tax changes may tend to inhibit plant and
equipment spending in some industries.

On the

other hand, the buoyancy of the financial
markets should reduce the cost of capital and
provide fresh opportunities for consolidating
financial resources and balance sheet strength.
Those opportunities should be used constructively
and not be dissipated in excessive leveraging and

-14financial risk-taking that could in the end
jeopardize our stability.
The burden of my comments is that there are gross
distortions and imbalances in the economy that we must deal
with forcibly and effectively.
which to build.
clear enough.

But we also have a lot upon

The outlines of an effective approach are
Major elements of that approach are in place.

But we will also need time and patience —

and they are in

short supply.
For instance, the deterioration in our trade balance
appears to have ended, but signs that the corner has been
turned are not yet decisive.

Meanwhile, the inevitable

adjustments in the energy industry, in agriculture, and in
commercial building are continuing to work against economic
growth in many areas.

In these circumstances, stronger growth

in 1987, as well as more sustainable growth over time, is
heavily dependent on realization of significant gains in trade,




-15One temptation is to try to speed that process —

and

to vent our understandable frustration about restrictive trade
policies of others —

by resorting to broad-brush protectionism.

But such a course, it seems to me, would invite almost certain
failure.

The lesson of experience is that world trade and

economic activity would be depressed together.

Indeed,

given the greater degree of economic and financial interdependence of nations today, the risks and potential losses
are all the greater.
At the same time, that very interdependence means
that we cannot be successful unless other countries are
taking constructive complementary actions to maintain their
own growth, to keep their markets open, and to deal with
legitimate complaints of unfair trading practices.
The United States and its currency are a major force
in the world economy and financial system.

In that context,

I can readily understand the concern expressed abroad about
instability in the dollar exchange markets and about the potential




-16impact on their own economies.

At a time of rather sluggish

growth among the main industrialized countries, abrupt further
changes in the dollar could undercut business planning and
investment.
to gain —

We in the United States obviously have nothing
and a great deal to lose —

from any interruption

in growth abroad.
But it is equally obvious that the needed improvement
in our trade position must be matched by others absorbing
increased imports and facing stronger export competition

—

logically and constructively, those changes should be borne
primarily by countries with huge external surpluses.

For

countries that have been dependent on large export surpluses
to support growth, that poses difficult adjustment problems,
the mirror image of ours.

In those cases, the plain need

is to encourage domestic growth, while also maintaining the
kind of open markets and receptivity to imports that are a
necessary part of achieving better international balance in
a framework of world growth.




Naturally they, too, want to

-17maintain and consolidate greater price stability.

But with

their currencies appreciated, the opportunity to do so
consistent with more rapid growth will be enhanced by
cheaper and more available imports*
Sometimes, and I think unfortunately, that need for
complementary adjustment abroad is framed in political terms as
a request for "help" by the United States to resolve our own
v

problems.

But what is at issue is not a narrow concept of

help for us or any single country? rather it is what is
required to achieve, in an interdependent world, the sustainable
world growth and stability we all want.

In that respect, no

country heavily dependent on trade is an island. Sooner or
later, the necessary adjustments in trade will be made.

The

issue is whether they will be made in an orderly way, in a
framework of open markets and growth, or with excessive currency
instability or protectionism or both.
Our own responsibilities in that connection, as I have
outlined, are unmistakable.




But those measures inevitably

-18impact others, and a better international balance cannot be
achieved, in the interests of the United States and its
trading partners, without constructive complementary policies
abroad.
Moreover, such responsibilities extend beyond the
main industrialized countries to others, particularly in
the Far East, that have achieved rapid growth largely by
penetrating foreign markets open to them, most of all in
the United States,

To the extent some of those countries

have large and growing external surpluses, the time has
clearly come for them to open their markets more broadly.
In doing so, the benefits of their growth to their own consumers
will be enhanced, even as they contribute to easing the problems
of worldwide adjustments*
I want to emphasize, too, that all these actions —

by

the United States, by other industrialized countries, and by
certain newly industrialized countries —

are a necessary part

of achieving the healthy economic environment essential for other




-19developing countries to constructively deal with their problems.
The heavily indebted countries, in particular, must be able to
penetrate export markets outside of the United States.
What I have tried this morning to outline is the broad
directions that I believe U.S. policy must take —
taking —

during 1987 and the years ahead.

is in fact

And I think there

are signs as well that the need for complementary policies
abroad is increasingly well understood.
Plainly, much more remains to be done.
underestimate the difficulties.

I do not

Right now, our own growth

is hesitant, and the indicators of economic activity abroad
have not been entirely reassuring.

The general ebullience

of financial markets masks some strains and weaknesses that
will need continuing attention.

Despite the progress of the

past, the cooperative effort to deal with the acute debt problems
in Latin America by the countries themselves, by the international
financial institutions, and by leading banks needs fresh impetus.




-20With oil and commodity prices now stable or even rising, maintaining the sense of progress toward general price stability
will be more difficult, particularly in the United States•
Needed policy changes, here and abroad, even when accepted
conceptually, are hard to implement with the needed vigor.
At the same time, I think we should be encouraged
by the degree to which some of the needed policies are in
place*

There is some evidence that the needed economic

adjustments are beginning.

What seems to me important, as

we assess progress in 1987, is not so much whether we in
the United States —

at least within some reasonable range

reach some specific rate of overall economic growth*

—

Rather,

our emphasis In policy-making should be on whether the necessary
adjustments are clearly underway and will in fact be sustained*
We won f t eliminate the budget deficit or the trade
deficit easily or quickly and certainly not in 1987.

By the

same token, we cannot expect to achieve an appropriate balance
in our internal savings and investment in so short a period of




-21time nor sharply improve productivity.

As a practical

matter# a sudden spurt in growth abroad won't be a solvent
for our problems*
What we collectively can do —

and what we must do

—

is act with force and conviction in the necessary directions.
In doing so we will lay the base for sustained noninflationary
growth not just in 1987 but for years beyond.




*******