View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
9:30 AM EST
Tuesday, February 23, 1982

Statement by
Paul A. Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Committee on Ways and Means
House of Representatives

February 23, 1982

I appreciate this opportunity to participate in your
hearings on the President's economic program.

The responsibilities

of the Federal Reserve are, of course, limited to monetary policy,
but we must necessarily recognize the broad interrelationships
among monetary and other policies bearing upon national economic
performance.

Your Committee has particular responsibility for

initiating specific revenue and spending measures; in reaching
your decisions, you must also take into account their implications
for the overall fiscal position of the government and the implications for financial markets.

It is at that point that our

concerns intersect, and my comments this morning will be largely
directed to that area.
I have often expressed my concern about the critical
need to break the inflationary momentum that had come to grip
the nation in the 1970's and spoken of the indispensable role
that monetary policy has to play in that effort.

At the same

time, I have emphasized the extra difficulties that result from
placing too heavy a burden on monetary policy alone in the fight
on inflation -- difficulties manifested in exceptionally heavy
pressures on financial markets and interest rates, and therefore
on credit-dependent sectors of the economy.
Current developments both reflect needed progress on the
inflation front and reinforce my concern about the burdens placed
on monetary policy to bring about and sustain that progress.

In

the best of circumstances, ending an inflation, once it has become
embedded in behavior and expectations, can be painful in the short
run, however necessary that effort is to our future strength and



- 2 -

prosperity.

The hard fact is the economy is now in the grips

of a second recession in as many years.

Recent developments

have some of the characteristics of earlier cyclical downturns.
But the current recession has been superimposed on a pattern of
stagnation extending over a number of years -- years characterized
by a rising trend of unemployment, lagging productivity, and
particularly strong pressures on the older industrial sectors
and regions.

And, even now, after months of rising unemployment,

interest rates have remained painfully high, delaying recovery
in some important sectors of the economy.
In broad terms, I don't think there is any great mystery
as to why the economy and financial markets have behaved in this
way.

During the 1970's, inflation increasingly became viewed

as a way of life, and in the process economic incentives were
distorted and our productive energies sapped.

As we lost our

most important financial yardstick -- a stable dollar -- interest
rates rose and became highly volatile.

As monetary policy moved

to deal more forcefully with the inflation -- particularly in a
context of fiscal imbalance -- the strain on financial markets

became more acute.

But the alternative course of trying to

accommodate to inflation by providing excessive monetary growth
would offer no lasting relief -- and probably little respite
even in the short run -- for that approach would only feed
inflationary expectations and reinforce the reluctance of lenders
to commit funds for any substantial period of time ahead.




Now we can see clear signs of progress on the inflation
front.

A reversal of the pattern of the inflation rate ratcheting

higher in each successive economic cycle would be an event of
profound importance, not least in encouraging a return to much
lower and more stable interest rates.
we have yet turned that corner.

We cannot "prove" that

Indeed, some of the progress

against inflation reflects the more immediate and temporary
effects of recession-weakened markets, the pressures of extraordinarily high interest rates on commodity and other sensitive
prices, and recent surpluses in petroleum and grain production.
But we are also seeing signs of potentially more lasting changes
in attitudes of business and labor toward pricing, wage bargaining,
and productivity.

Not surprisingly, the effort is most clearly

apparent in industries where costs and wages have been most out
of line, where international competitive pressures are particularly
intense, or where regulatory change has encouraged greater price
competition.

But, I believe the pattern is likely to spread,

"building in" lower rates of increase in nominal wages and prices
over time.

And, as the inflationary and cost pressures ease, the

economy can resume a healthy growth pattern, with greater job
opportunities, increasing productivity, and higher real wages.
But if that bright prospect is to be achieved, we simply
cannot afford now -- just as the disinflationary process is
beginning to take hold and beginning to be believed -- to abandon
our monetary vigilance.

Past failures to "carry through" have

left a legacy of skepticism and uncertainty among workers and




-4-

businessmen, among consumers, and among participants in financial
markets where lenders demand "inflation" and "uncertainty" premiums
when committing their funds.

Credibility in dealing with inflation

will have to be earned by performance and persistence over time.
Prudent fiscal and other policies must help in achieving that
credibility.

But I believe it is broadly and rightly recognized

that, whatever those other policies, appropriate restraint on the
expansion of money and credit will continue to be fundamental to
restoring price stability.
As you know, I testified two weeks ago before the House
and Senate Banking Committees to report the Federal Reserve's
specific intentions with respect to money and credit growth for
1982.

Without repeating the details, I'd like to highlight a

few of the major points.
Developments during 1981 were broadly consistent with
the continuing effort to reduce growth of money and credit to
non-inflationary levels over time.

There were, to be sure, seme

divergent movements among the various monetary and credit aggregates
that we target.

Those movements are largely explicable in terms

of technological and regulatory change -- the introduction of
NOW accounts nationwide, the enormous growth of money market
funds, and other factors affecting the preferences of the public
for different types of financial assets.

Specifically, Ml-B growth

(adjusted for the estimated shift of funds into NOW accounts)
decelerated further last year, averaging, over the year as a whole,
a little more than 1 percent below the previous year --




the third

-5-

consecutive year of lower growth.

From the fourth quarter of 1980

to the fourth quarter of 1981, Ml-B growth (adjusted) w a s

2.3 per-

cent, a little more than 1 percentage point below the lower end of
the target that we had indicated was desirable at mid-year.

The

growth of the broader aggregate M2 -- about 9-1/2 percent over the
four quarter period -- was a bit higher than in 1980, partly
reflecting the extraordinary growth in money market funds.
As you know, che money supply increased particularly
sharply in the early weeks of 1982, following fairly large
increases in November and December.

Increases of that size

are unusual when production and incomes are weak, and the
recent rise appears to be related in considerable part to the
desire of individuals to place marginally more of their assets
in highly liquid form.

Interest rates, after falling sharply

last fall, retraced part of that decline in January and early
February, partly because the rising money supply was reflected
in renewed pressure on bank reserve positions.

More recently,

monetary growth appears to be moderating, and bond markets have
rallied.
These recent movements, in my mind, emphasize again two
relevant points in assessing our monetary targets and their
implications.

First, in a large and complex economy, short-term

fluctuations in money supply data -- for a month or even a quarter,
and much more so from week to week -- can be anticipated as consumers
and businesses adjust their cash holdings.




So long as the trend

is appropriate, those short-term fluctuations should have no
important implication for economic activity or inflation.
Second and more fundamentally, our targets are, by design,
limited to amounts necessary to finance real growth in a framework of declining inflation.

The stronger the inflationary

momentum, and the more pressure on credit markets from other
directions, the greater the risk that high interest rates will
squeeze out housing, investment, and other private activity
supported by borrowing.
We believe the targets for 1982 established this month
(reaffirming tentative targets set out last July) will be consistent with recovery in business activity over the second half
of the year.

Our target range for Ml of 2-1/2 to 5-1/2 percent

is consistent with growth in money over the year as a whole
larger than during 1981, and the Federal Open Market Committee
has suggested that, as things now stand, growth in the upper
part of the range would be acceptable.

The FOMC also suggested

M2 growth toward the upper end of its 6-9 percent range (the
same as last year) would also be acceptable.

But these ranges

also imply a "tight fit," in the sense they are predicated on
the assumption and prospect of a further decline in the rate of
inflation.
The fact is that consolidating and extending our progress
on inflation will require continuing restraint on monetary growth,
and we intend to maintain the necessary degree of restraint.




-7-

That restraint, by providing assurance that inflation will
continue to decline, should over time be a powerful influence
in bringing down interest rates as well, particularly in the
long-term area.

Indeed, prospects for any lasting relaxation

of interest rate pressures would be dim without the continuing
monetary discipline that success against inflation requires.
For the more immediate future, interest rate prospects
depend crucially on other factors as well, and I am fully
aware that interest rates are vitally important to the timing,
strength, and sustainability of economic recovery.

The most

important of those "other" factors is surely the outlook
for the Federal deficit, and it is a factor directly within your
own purview.
As you know, this year, fiscal 1982, we will have a
very large Federal deficit -- on the order of $100 billion.
To a considerable extent, that deficit is a reflection of the
recession, as it reduces revenues and raises outlays.

In the

particular circumstances of today, the current deficit, to a
large degree,' acts as an "automatic stabilizer" for the economy.
The financing load should be manageable in a context of reduced
credit demands by other sectors.
As we look ahead to 1983 and beyond, the situation is
quite different, and that is the source of my concern about the
budgetary situation.

What is so disturbing is that the current

services budget (taking account of the Administration's defense
program) shows a sharply rising deficit, even if we assume revenues




- 8 -

are lifted and spending restrained by rather strong recovery.
All the estimates before you, by the Administration, by the
Congressional Budget Office, or by private forecasters, point
in the same direction.

In the absence of action to close the

potential gap, the deficit will rise to about $150 billion or
more in fiscal 1983, and to still larger amounts in later years.
Looking at the same situation in another way, even if we assumed
the unemployment rate would soon drop back to six percent or so -about the level of the best recent years

-- we would be faced

with large and rising deficits unless strong new measures are
taken to contain them.
In recognition of this outlook, the Administration has,
as you know, proposed substantial measures to reduce the potential
deficit for fiscal 1983, and the years beyond.

The emphasis is

on spending reductions, but some revenue measures are also proposed.

That program is estimated to reduce the projected fiscal

gap by $56 billion in 1983 and $84 billion in 1984.

If enacted,

as proposed, it would go a very considerable way toward dealing
with the fiscal problem.
As you consider those and other proposals, I must emphasize
the threat that, unless substantial budgetary actions are undertaken, private borrowers would be squeezed out of the market, with
adverse consequences for homebuilding, for business investment,
and for other credit-dependent sectors.

In other words, the

budgetary outlook, as it stands, does not seem to me consistent
with the expansion in private investment we seek, and have sought
to encourage through tax reduction and other measures.




The problem is not simply one for the future -- for
1983 and 1984 and beyond.

Financial markets constantly look

ahead -- any lender or borrower tries to anticipate and "discount"
what lies ahead.

Anticipations of a future "squeeze" are trans-

lated into present high interest rates, into a desire to "stay
short" in lending, into a reluctance to set into motion plans
to build and to invest.

Moreover, the deep-seated public instinct

that sustained large deficits will lead, sooner or later, to
pressure to create more money to finance those deficits, or will
otherwise stimulate inflation, undercuts the effort to restore
stability.
I would also point out that, even with measures as large
as those proposed by the Administration, we would be left with
historically high deficits

in relation to GNP or our probable

savings potential, as the projected recovery proceeded.

And

those projections have little margin for misjudgment of the
underlying trend in spending or revenues, in interest rates,
in the inflation rate and the like -- areas where any projection
has an element of uncertainty.

I note, in that respect, that

projections of the existing budgetary gap by the Congressional
Budget Office run somewhat higher than those of the Administration.
The potential for continuing squeeze on financial
markets could be alleviated by increases in business and personal
saving.

Such saving has been abysmally low in recent years.

Greater price stability, positive real interest rates, and the
tax measures introduced last year, all should work in the direction
of greater savings.




But to count on a dramatically large increase

-10-

in savings to "bail" us out of the budgetary problem would be
to miss the point, at best.

We need larger saving to finance

higher levels of business investment and housing construction;
we cannot afford to have it dissipated in financing prolonged
excessive budget deficits -- deficits that, as matters stand,
would absorb, or more than absorb, a reasonable projection of
increased savings.
Given the nature of the problem before us, and the clear
risks of underestimating the size of the budgetary problem, I
can only conclude that the Congress should set its sights for
still larger budgetary savings, keeping in mind the widening
gap now projected beyond fiscal 1983.
Credible steps to assure substantially declining
Federal deficits as the economy expands, looking toward balance
as we restore satisfactory levels of unemployment, would be
enormously helpful in resolving some of the problems in our
financial markets today.

Indeed, such action could have a

galvanizing effect in bringing about lower interest rates
because it is concern about the budgetary prospects that preoccupies the thinking of many potential investors in the market
today.
In carrying the primary responsibility for originating
tax legislation and for certain large spending programs, your
Committee has the excruciating job of translating general
budgetary objectives into concrete legislation.

You must make

choices involving social, national security, and programmatic
considerations far beyond the purview of the Federal Reserve or




-li-

my competence.

As a purely economic matter, I do believe that,

in general, lower taxes -- particularly lower marginal income
tax rates -- will permit the private economy to perform more
effectively, tending to increase incentives and to reduce distortions.

From that standpoint, spending control clearly deserves

priority.

But to the extent the needed job cannot be done by

expenditure control alone, I see no alternative to considering
new sources of revenue.
The difficult economic circumstances of today should
not blind us to the fact that we have much upon which to build.
We can see the tangible progress against inflation.

The Adminis-

tration and the Congress have taken action to spur productivity,
work, and savings through the tax system.
trend in spending has been bent lower.

The inexorable upward

Regulatory reform is

underway.
From that perspective, what we need is not any basic
change in direction, but a sense of urgency and persistence
in "carrying through."

That has clear implications for continued

discipline in monetary policy.

And it has direct implications

for dealing with the budgetary problem that looms so large
before you.
Seldom, in my experience, has the challenge been so
clear for all to see.

And seldom has there been so strong a

consensus on the need to meet it with bold measures.

It is

those facts that give me confidence that you and your colleagues,
working with the Administration, will find the way to reconcile




-12-

the competing: priorities among the particulars of spending
and revenue decisions in a way consistent with needed reduction
in the deficit.

The quicker that can be done, the brighter, in

my judgment, will be the outlook for the economy.




For use at 10 a.m., E.S.T.,
February 10, 1982

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

.-•'of

Monetary Policy Report to Congress
Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978

February 10, 1982




Letter of Transmittal

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Washington, D.C., February 10, 1982
THE PRESIDENT OF THE SENATE
THE SPEAKER OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES.
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report to the Congress pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely,
Paul A. Volcker, Chairman




TABLE OF CONTENTS
Page
Section 1:

Monetary Policy and the Performance of the
Economy in 1981

1

Section 2:

The Growth of Money and Credit in 1981

10

Section 3:

The Federal Reserve's Objectives for the Growth of
Money and Credit

19

The Outlook for the Economy in 1982

23

Section 4:




- 1 -

Section 1:

Monetary Policy and the Performance of the Economy in 1981

The economy was growing rapidly as 1981 began, continuing the sharp
cyclical rebound that started in mid-1980.

Activity leveled out during the

spring and summer, however, and it fell in the final quarter of the year.

As

a result, the rate of production of goods and services—real G N P — w a s only
slightly higher at the end of 1981 than it had been a year earlier.

With the

weakening of output late in the year, the margin of unutilized plant capacity
widened and the unemployment rate rose sharply to near postwar record levels.
While economic activity was disappointing last year, there were
emerging signs of progress in reducing inflationary pressures.

The rate of

price inflation slowed from the extremely rapid pace of the preceding two
years, and as 1981 progressed there also were indications of an easing in the
rate of wage increases, particularly in some key pattern-setting industries.
Confidence in the restoration of reasonable overall price stability is needed if economic growth is to be resumed on a sustained basis.

The

accelerating inflation of earlier years had been eroding the foundations of
the nation's economy:

capital formation had slowed; productivity was sagging;

the functioning of basic market mechanisms was being impaired; and inequitable and capricious transfers of wealth were harming many of the weakest
among us.

The task of reversing the inflationary trend of earlier years was

made more difficult because a decade of escalating prices and unsuccessful
anti-inflation policies had led to firmly held expectations of continued
h i g h — i f not accelerating—rates of inflation.

Thus, it was recognized that

reducing inflation would take time and that anti-inflation policies would







Gross Business Product Prices
Change from Q4 to Q4, percent

Fixed-Weighted Index

1977

1978

1981

1979

Q1

10.5

Q2

8.2

Q3

9.9

Q4

7.1

1980

— I 12

1981

Real GNP
Change from Q4 to Q4, percent

1972 Dollars
1981

Q1

8.6

Q2

— 1.6

Q3

1.4

Q4

—5.2

+
0

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

Interest Rates
Percent

16

12

Home Mortgage

3-Month Treasury Bill

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

- 2 -

have to be applied with persistence if they were to be effective in altering
expectations and slowing the rate of price increases.
While fiscal policy and decisions made in the private sector have
much to do with the course of economic developments, economic theory and
experience alike indicate that progress toward price stability cannot be
obtained without adequate restraint on the growth of money and credit.
tary policy was conducted in 1981 with this crucial fact in mind.

Mone-

The Federal

Reserve set objectives for the growth of the monetary aggregates that it
believed would help to damp inflation and would lead to movement over time
toward trend rates of monetary expansion consistent with the growth of potential output at stable prices.
Short-term market rates of interest began 1981 at record levels, as
rapid growth of economic activity in the second half of 1980 had pushed up
the demand for money and credit faster than could be accommodated within the
target ranges for growth of the monetary aggregates and bank reserves.

Early

in 1981 these demands began to subside, pressures on bank reserve positions
were relieved, and money market rates declined for a time.

A bulge in money

demand early in the second quarter was steadily resisted by restraining the
supply of reserves, and in the process short-term interest rates moved back
to their earlier highs.

By midsummer, short-term interest rates were declin-

ing, as demands for money and credit slackened while the Federal Reserve
expanded nonborrowed reserves in an effort to maintain adequate monetary
growth.

Those interest rate declines accelerated in October and November

as the recession took hold.
On balance, short-term interest rates—although volatile—moved
down considerably over the course of 1981.




In contrast, long-term rates

-3-

rose substantially over the period, despite declines in the last quarter of
the year.

The pressure on long-term rates appeared to reflect a combination

of factors.

Anticipations that continued large federal budget deficits would

clash with private credit demands particularly as the economy expanded, putting strong pressures on credit markets, were a continuing strong investor
concern.

Despite reductions in the growth of many federal spending programs,

federal borrowing in calendar year 1981 siphoned off roughly a quarter of the
total funds available to domestic nonfinancial borrowers.

In the background

were continuing doubts and skepticism that anti-inflation programs would be
carried through.

Moreover, the volatility of the markets may have inhibited

aggressive buying of longer-term securities.
The tensions in credit markets in 1981 had their greatest impact
on business and household capital formation.

Housing construction fell to

its lowest level in the postwar period; only 1.1 million new housing units
were started in 1981.

The weakness in real estate markets last year reflected

a number of influences.

Of paramount importance, in the short run, was the

cost of mortgage funds.

The average rate on mortgages closed for new homes

was 15.3 percent in the fourth quarter of 1981, up from 12.6 percent a year
earlier.
demand:

But it was not higher mortgage rates alone that cut into housing
high prices also adversely affected the ability of those seeking

new homes to afford the monthly payments.

Although house prices changed

little in 1981, over the preceding 5 years prices of new and existing homes
had risen half again as fast as the overall rate of inflation.

As a result,

the share of average family disposable income needed to service the monthly
payment on a typical new mortgage rose from 21 percent in 1976 to nearly 40
percent last year.




-4-

Slow income growth and rising unemployment, along with the increased
cost of credit, combined to damp consumer spending in 1981—particularly for
more discretionary, large ticket items such as autos, furniture, and appliances.

Since the mid-1970s, household real after-tax income has only been

rising at a 1/2 percent annual rate, compared with a long-run trend of 2 percent.

At the same time, the prices of essential items such as food, gasoline,

heating fuel, utilities, and medical services—as a group—have been rising
faster than the overall inflation rate, and the share of disposable income
devoted to these items has been increasing.

The resulting squeeze on family

budgets led many households to overextend themselves during the last half of
the 1970s, taking on more and more debt to finance their purchases.
With household balance sheets debt-laden and credit costs rising, a
retrenchment in consumer borrowing began in 1980, and continued through 1981.
As the year progressed, it appeared that household balance sheets were improving.

Consumer debt burdens (the ratio of monthly debt repayment obligations

to income) declined to their lowest level in more than five years.

Moreover,

partly in response to the higher after-tax income following the tax cut on
October 1, the saving rate rose from about 5 percent in the first three
quarters of 1981 to 6 percent in the fourth quarter.
In real terms, personal consumption expenditures rose 1-1/4 percent
over the four quarters of 1981.

The gain was concentrated in the early months

of the year as real consumer spending fell, on balance, over the final three
quarters of 1981.

Purchases of new automobiles were hardest hit.

Sales of

domestically produced cars totaled 6.2 million units in 1981, the poorest performance in 20 years.




The depressed conditions in the auto sector were related,

-5-

in part, to the typical cyclical volatility in the demand for motor vehicles
and to credit market conditions, which affected the cost of financing new car
and truck purchases.

However, the current problems in the industry appear to

be related mainly to longer-term trends in automotive demand.

These include:

the rapid increase in the price of new cars, high gasoline and other operating costs, sluggish real income growth, intense foreign competition, and
government regulations that have necessitated large investments to comply with
emission control standards and to improve fuel efficiency.

As 1981 was ending,

it appeared that the auto industry was taking aggressive actions to reduce
costs and to improve the competitiveness of its products.
Business firms, like households, restrained their spending on investment goods in 1981.

Demand was damped by a substantial degree of excess capa-

city and by the rising trend in corporate bond rates throughout much of the
year, which boosted the real cost of capital.

In real terms, expenditures for

new plant and equipment rose only 1-1/2 percent over the four quarters of 1981.
Although spending for new structures increased during the year, real equipment
outlays fell for the second year in a row; the biggest declines were for electrical machinery and transportation equipment, while spending for most other
capital goods remained weak.
In contrast to fixed investment outlays, sizable unintended inventory accumulation boosted business financing requirements.

As the year went

on, unexpectedly weak demand led to a build-up of excess stocks in several
industries.

The most pronounced problem was in autos, but other manufacturers

and retailers also found their inventory levels uncomfortably high relative
to sales.

On balance, total nominal business capital spending—fixed invest-

ment and inventories—rose about 20 percent above the 1980 average.




- 6 -

Early in 1981, strong economic growth helped boost corporate internal funds, greatly reducing corporate needs for external financing.

But as

the economy slowed, corporate profits turned sluggish and businesses were
forced to rely more heavily on credit markets to satisfy their rising capital
needs.

The bulk of business borrowing last year was in short-term markets,

as most firms felt it best to defer making long-run commitments in the current
financial environment.

With the accumulation of additional short-term debt,

however, corporate balance sheet positions deteriorated further, and the ratio
of short-term to total debt of the nonfinancial corporate sector rose to a
record high.
Real purchases of goods and services at all levels of government
rose only moderately during 1981 as a sharp increase in purchases by the
federal government was partly offset by curtailed spending at the state and
local level.

The rise in federal spending on goods and services reflected

another large increase in defense purchases, while federal payroll reductions
helped to contain increases in nondefense outlays.

At the state and local

level, real purchases fell 2 percent owing to a combination of the withdrawal of federal support for many activities, the continued impact of tax
limitation measures, and the effects of a sluggish economy on tax revenues.
The weighted-average value of the dollar against major foreign
currencies* rose by nearly one-fourth during the period from January to
August.

The dollar eased somewhat in the last part of 1981, but at the end

of the year still remained well above its year-earlier level.

The improve-

ment in the inflation outlook in the United States was a factor in the appreciation of the dollar.




Moreover, at various times during the year changes in

-7-

the differential between interest rates on dollar assets and rates of return
on foreign currency assets also had a noticeable impact on exchange rates.
Real exports of goods and services increased in the first quarter
of 1981, in part because of strong GNP growth in one of our major trading
partners, Canada.

But for the next three quarters, real exports declined in

response to a slowing of economic growth abroad and the effect of the appreciation of the dollar in 1980 and 1981.

The volume of imports, other than

oil, rose fairly steadily throughout the year.

The current account, reflect-

ing this weakened trade performance, shifted from a surplus in the first
quarter to a deficit by the fourth quarter.
Employment grew at a moderate rate during the first three quarters
of 1981 and the unemployment rate edged down.
in the service and trade sectors.

Job increases were strongest

As economic activity began to contract in

the autumn, the demand for labor fell sharply and the unemployment rate
climbed to 8.8 percent in December—only fractionally below its postwar high.
Layoffs in the durable goods and construction industries accounted for much
of the drop in employment.

As a result, the unemployment rate of adult m e n —

who tend to be more heavily employed in these industries—jumped to a postwar
record of 7.9 percent in December of 1981.
Labor productivity (output per hour worked) showed considerable
fluctuation during 1981, reflecting the course of economic activity.

Produc-

tivity rose at a 1-1/4 percent annual rate in the first three quarters of
1981.

However, as often happens at the beginning of a cyclical downturn, out-

put fell more than employment in the fourth quarter and productivity declined,
offsetting the gains earlier in the year.




Averaging across short-run cyclical

- 8 -

movements, productivity has shown little improvement in recent years, and thus
has provided virtually no offset to the impact of rapidly rising compensation
on unit labor costs.
Compensation and wage increases did decelerate during 1981—with
continuing progress observed throughout the year.

But the slowing was moder-

ate, reflecting the basic inertia of the wage determination process, where
many union contracts last three years or more and nonunion wage agreements
usually are set annually.

By the second half of 1981, however, some changes

in those traditional wage-setting practices were under way in several important industries:

management and workers alike began to reconsider planned

wage adjustments, some expiring contracts were renegotiated well in advance
of termination dates, and labor agreements at a number of firms were modified
in an effort to ease cost pressures and to enable them to compete more effectively.

These adjustments, coupled with the progress seen in reducing infla-

tion during 1981, suggest that the nation's anti-inflation policies have set
the stage for a sustained unwinding of wage and price increases.
The trend in inflation improved noticeably during 1981, and by yearend virtually all aggregate price indexes were advancing well below doubledigit rates for the first time since 1978.

The consumer price index rose 8.9

percent over the course of 1981, down from the nearly 13 percent average rate
in 1979 anci 1980.

Important factors in the slowing of inflation were excep-

tionally favorable agricultural supplies and declines, after the first quarter,
in world oil prices.

Inflation in areas other than food and energy—particu-

larly consumer commodities and capital equipment—also began to abate, although
price pressures persisted in the consumer service sector, notably for medical




- 9 -

care.

As the year progressed, surveys of consumer expectations suggested that

the inflationary psychology, which had increasingly permeated many aspects of
economic behavior in earlier years, appeared to be subsiding.




-10-

Section 2:

The Growth of Money and Credit In 1981

The Board of Governors in its report to Congress last February indicated that the System intended to maintain restraint on the expansion of money
and credit in 1981.

The specific ranges chosen by the Federal Open Market

Committee (FOMC) for the various monetary aggregates anticipated a deceleration in monetary growth that would encourage further improvement in price performance.

Measured from the fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of

1981, and abstracting from the effects on deposit structure of the authorization of NOW accounts nationwide, the ranges adopted were as follows:

for Ml-A,

3 to 5-1/2 percent; for Ml-B, 3-1/2 to 6 percent; for M2, 6 to 9 percent; and
for M3, 6-1/2 to 9-1/2 percent.

The associated range for commercial bank

credit was 6 to 9 percent.
In formulating its objectives for 1981, the FOMC knew that the growth
rates of the narrow aggregates would be affected markedly by shifts into NOW
accounts which for the first time became available on a nationwide basis in
January.

Transfers into NOW accounts, which are included in Ml-B, from savings

deposits and other asset holdings not included in Ml were expected to be particularly large in the early months of the year.

Thus, in order to avoid confu-

sion about the intent of policy and to facilitate comparisons with previous
years, the objectives announced for Ml-B abstracted from such shifts.1

Even

after accounting for such shifts, however, the FOMC anticipated that the growth
rates of the various aggregates were likely to diverge more than usual, reflecting the rapid pace of institutional change in financial markets.

The FOMC indi-

cated that if Ml-B growth (adjusted for shifts into new NOW accounts and other
1. The shift adjustments were estimated on the basis of survey evidence and
were published regularly over the past year.




-11-

checkable deposits) was about in the middle of its annual range, the growth
of M2 was likely to be in the upper part of its range, given the popularity
of the nontransactions components of M2 that pay market-related interest
rates.

It also was noted that the relationship of M3 and bank credit to their

respective ranges would be influenced importantly by the pattern of credit
flows that would emerge, and particularly by whether financial conditions
would be conducive for corporations to refinance short-term borrowing in the
bond and equity markets.
It soon became apparent as 1981 unfolded that the behavior of the
aggregates was turning out to be even more divergent than had been anticipated.
Growth rates of the shift-adjusted narrow aggregates were low in the opening
months of the year, a development that was welcome following rapid growth in
the latter part of 1980.

A strong surge in April was offset by weakness over

the remainder of the second quarter.

On the whole, average growth in adjusted

Ml-B over the first half of 1981 was well below that which would have been expected on the basis of historical relationships among money, GNP, and interest
rates.

On the other hand, despite the weakness in Ml-B, the broader aggre-

gates expanded quite rapidly in early 1981.

M2 growth over the first half was

near the upper end of its annual range, while the expansion of M3 placed this
aggregate above the upper bound of its range at midyear.
After reassessing its objectives for 1981 at midyear, the FOMC
elected to leave unchanged the previously established ranges for the aggregates over the remainder of the year.

However, in light of the reduced

growth in Ml-type balances over the first half of the year, indications that
this weakness might reflect a lasting change in cash management practices of




-12-

individuals and businesses related to the growth of alternative means of holding highly liquid funds, and given the relatively strong growth of the broader
aggregates, the FOMC anticipated that growth of the narrow aggregates might
likely and desirably end the year near the lower bounds of their annual
ranges.

Even so, given the sluggishness early in the year, this decision

implied that growth of Ml-A and Ml-B would accelerate over the balance of the
year.

At the same time, the FOMC indicated that M2 and M3 might well end the

year around the upper ends of their ranges.

This expectation also reflected

in part the possibility that regulatory and legislative actions as well as
the popularity of money market mutual funds might intensify the public's
preference to hold the type of assets encompassed in the broader aggregates.
Although growth of narrow money in the second half of the year was
on average about the same as in the first half, Ml-B strengthened appreciably
in the final two months of the year.

This acceleration appeared to reflect

in part a lagged response to large short-term interest rate declines in the
summer and fall and in part a shift in preferences for very liquid assets in
an environment of heightened economic and financial uncertainty.

Similarly,

M2 growth in the second half was about in line with expansion in the first
half, although growth in this measure also picked up at the end of the year.
The expansion in M3, on the other hand, decelerated from the rapid pace of
the first half, as sales of large CDs slowed in concert with a slackening in
bank credit growth and stronger growth in core deposits.
Measuring growth for the year from the fourth quarter of 1980 to
the fourth quarter of 1981, Ml-B growth adjusted for shifts into NOW accounts
was about 2-1/4 percent—1-1/4 percentage points below the lower end of its




Growth Ranges and Actual Monetary Growth
M 1 - A Shift A d j u s t e d *
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of G r o w t h
Range adopted by F O M C for

1 9 8 0 Q 4 to 1 9 8 1 Q 4
5 Vi %

1 9 8 0 Q 4 to 1 9 8 1 Q 4

410

1.3 Percent

400

390

J

1981

1980

M1 - B Shift Adjusted *
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of G r o w t h
Range a d o p t e d by F O M C for
450

1 9 8 0 Q 4 to 1 9 8 1 Q 4

1 9 8 0 0 4 to 1 9 8 1 Q 4
2 . 3 Percent

440
3 '/2 %
430

420

410
I

I

F

I

I

A

I

I

1980

J

I
I
1981

M1-B
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of G r o w t h
Range adopted by F O M C for

8

1 9 8 0 0 4 to 1 9 8 1 0 4 *

72 %

1 9 8 0 0 4 to 1 9 8 1 Q 4
5 . 0 Percent

1980

*

1981

A d j u s t e d lor impact of n a t i o n w i d e N O W a c c o u n t s




Growth Ranges and Actual Monetary and Bank Credit Growth
M2
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of Growth
Range adopted by FOMC for
1980 Q4 to 1981 Q4

1980 Q4 to 1981 Q4
1800

- 6%

9.4 Percent

1750

1700

1650

J_L
1981

1980

M3
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of Growth
Range adopted by FOMC for
1980 Q4 to 1981 Q4

9'/! %

2150

1980 Q4 to 1981 Q4
11.4 Percent

2100
6 72%

2000
1950

1981

1980

Bank C r e d i t *
Billions of dollars
Annual Rate of Growth
Range adopted by FOMC for
1 9 8 0 Q4 to 1 981 Q4

9% —

•6%

1980 Q4 to 1981 Q4
1350

1300

1250

1200
I
1980

A

I

l

J

l
1981

I

A

I

I o I

I d

"^"Data prior to F e b r u a r y are a d j u s t e d for d i s c o n t i n u i t y in s e r i e s . O e c e m b e r figure is a d j u s t e d
for shift of a s s e t s into I n t e r n a t i o n a l B a n k i n g Facilities.




8.8 Percent

targeted ranged

Growth rates, of course, are affected by the particular

pattern of variation that develops over the course of the year.

Measuring

expansion from December to December, "adjusted" Ml-B growth in 1981 was at a
3-1/2 percent rate.

On a yearly average basis, which reflects movements

through the year as a whole relative to the level of the previous year, the
increase was at a 4-3/4 percent rate.

At the same time, measured from the

fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of 1981, growth of M2 was 9.4
percent, 0.4 percentage point above the upper limit of its range.

Also,

growth of M3 exceeded the upper end of its range by 1.9 percentage points,
while bank credit growth was just inside the upper end of its annual range.
The table on page 14 puts the performance of the aggregates during
1981 into a somewhat longer-term perspective, showing two measures of annual
growth.

No matter which of the measures of annual growth is used, a marked

deceleration in Ml-B is apparent since 1978.

The table also clearly illus-

trates that growth rates for the broader aggregates have been maintained
around a higher level, and larger divergences have developed from Ml-B
growth.

In considerable part, these differences can be explained by struc-

tural changes in financial markets.
As noted earlier, it was already obvious last February when the
FOMC was meeting to set its objectives for 1981 that shifts into NOW accounts
following their nationwide authorization at the beginning of 1981 would alter
the behavior of the narrow aggregates.

Data for early January had pointed

to a very large movement of funds at the beginning of the year.

However,

1. Unadjusted for shifts into NOW accounts, Ml-B increased 5.0 percent from
the fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of 1981.




-14-

Growth of Money and Bank Credit
(percentage changes)

Bank
Credit^

Ml-B 1

M-2

M-3

1978

8.3

8.3

11.3

13.3

1979

7.5

8.4

9.8

12.6

1980

6.6

9.1

9.9

8.0

1981

2.3

9.4

11.4

8.8

1978

8.2

8.8

11.8

12.4

1979

7.7

8.5

10.3

13.5

1980

5.9

8.3

9.3

8.5

1981

4.7

9.7

11.5

9.4

Fourth quarter to
fourth quarter

Annual average to
annual average

1. Growth rates for 1980 and 1981 adjusted for shifts to other checkable
deposit accounts since the end of the preceding year.
2. December level used for calculating these 1981 growth rates incorporates
an adjustment to abstract from the shifting of assets from domestic banking
offices to International Banking Facilities.




-15-

the pattern and magnitude of subsequent movements could not be predicted with
any certainty.

As events unfolded, the shifts into NOW accounts were more

concentrated in the early part of 1981 than was anticipated by the working
assumptions of the Board's staff.

Through June, the adjustments made to the

aggregates to correct for such shifts had the effect of raising Ml-A by $28
billion and lowering Ml-B by $9-1/2 billion.

Over the second half of 1981,

further adjustments for shifts into NOW accounts raised Ml-A by only another
$6 billion and lowered Ml-B by about $2-1/2 billion more.

While these adjust-

ments are imprecise and based on evidence from a variety of sources, data on
the number of NOW accounts coupled with other available information confirm
that the shifting of funds from demand deposits to new interest-bearing checking accounts tapered off considerably by the fall.

A surge in NOW account

balances near the end of the year and early in 1982 appeared to reflect primarily the precautionary savings behavior noted above rather than shifting
of funds into new accounts.
As was indicated above, the growth of the narrow aggregates adjusted
for shifts into NOW accounts was low in 1981 compared with the other aggregates
and also relative to past relationships with income and interest rates.

Con-

tinued high interest rates provided a substantial incentive for businesses to
intensify efforts to pare narrow money balances and to make increasingly widespread use of sophisticated cash management techniques.

At the same time,

explosive growth of money market mutual funds (MMMFs), many of which offer
check-writing or other third party payment services comparable to conventional checking accounts, appeared to induce some households to minimize
checking account balances.




Also, the broader availability of NOW accounts

-16-

may have stimulated households to reconsider in a more general way their
habits of cash management.
Likewise, the strong growth of M2 over the past few years reflected
changing financial practices.

Money market funds and instruments offered by

depository institutions that pay market-related interest rates have been
accounting for an increasing proportion of M2, as such assets have become
much more competitive with open market instruments.

Indeed, the attractive-

ness of small time deposits was enhanced last year by the liberalization of
the interest rate ceilings on small savers certificates and to a limited
extent by the introduction of all savers certificates.

Even so, three-fourths

of the increase in the nontransactions components of M2 was accounted for
by MMMFs which grew 140 percent last year.
The distortions in the aggregates resulting from the expansion in
MMMFs are difficult to quantify.

Surveys of household behavior and data on

account turnover suggest that most shareholders of money funds have made
little or no use of their accounts for transactions purposes.

Thus, the

direct substitution effect of MMMFs on the growth of Ml has appeared small,
perhaps on the order of 1 percentage point on the rate of growth for the
year.

However,' indirect effects may have been larger as the potential avail-

ability of such a highly liquid asset may facilitate holding less funds in
demand and'NOW accounts.
The direct effect of MMMFs on M2 appears more substantial in dollar
terms.

Presumably, the great bulk of the $20 billion inflow in 1981 to MMMFs

catering only to institutional investors was funds that otherwise would have
been invested in assets not included in M2.




In addition, it seems likely




-17-

that a small portion of the $90 billion growth in other types of MMMFs also
reflected diversions from assets not in M2.
In light of the sizable distortions created by the growth of institution-only MMMFs, M2 has been revised to exclude such funds but they will
continue to be a component of M3.
retail RPs.

In addition, M2 has been revised to include

Retail RPs, which previously had been a component only of M3,

were promoted on a substantial scale in 1981, likely attracting funds mainly
from household small time deposits and MMMF holdings and thus resulting in a
downward bias on M2 growth.

The net effect on M2 growth of reclassifying

institution-only MMMFs and retail RPs, along with other minor revisions, was
small.
M3 increased more rapidly than M2 last year largely because of the
substantial expansion in large CDs, particularly over the first half of the
year.

With growth of core deposits weak on balance over the year, depository

institutions increased their managed liabilities to support expansion in
loans and investments.
Bank credit growth accelerated somewhat in 1981 but stayed just
within the upper end of its annual target range.
growth was concentrated in business loans.

The pick-up in bank credit

Growth in this category was bol-

stered by the high level of corporate bond rates through most of the year,
which tended to focus business credit demands on short-term borrowing such as
bank loans and commercial paper.

Although merger activity contributed signifi-

cantly to the growth of loan commitments over the year, actual takedowns for
this purpose influenced loan growth only slightly.

Real estate loans at banks

in 1981 grew at about the same moderate pace as in the prior year, while

-13-

consumer lending strengthened a little from 1980.

Security holdings at banks

grew somewhat more slowly than loans in 1981.
The bank credit data in December were affected by the shifting of
assets to accounts in the newly authorized International Banking Facilities
(IBFs).

It is estimated that about $22 billion of loans to foreign customers

were shifted from U.S. offices to IBFs in December.
report are adjusted for this shift.

The data presented in this

Without this adjustment, the increase in

bank credit from the fourth quarter of 1980 to the fourth quarter of 1981 was
8-1/4 percent, one-half percentage point less than shown by the adjusted
data.
Broader measures of credit flows reflected the slowing pace of production and income in 1981 and the effects of high interest rates.

Households

and businesses continued to increase their borrowing over the first three
quarters, but their use of credit contracted in the fourth quarter in response
to the weakening of the economy.

In view of the high level of long-term

interest rates during most of 1981, virtually all of the increase in funds
raised was in short-term debt instruments.

Overall, net funds raised by

nonfinancial sectors rose 7 percent in 1981 and continued to fall relative
to GNP for the third consecutive year.




-19-

Section 3:

The Federal Reserve's Objectives for the Growth of Money and Credit

The Federal Reserve remains committed to restraint on the growth of
money and credit in order to exert continuing downward pressure on the rate of
inflation.

Such a policy is essential if the groundwork is to be laid for

sustained economic expansion.
There was a distinct slowing of inflation during 1981, and the prospects for further progress are good.

Failure to persist in the effort to

maintain the improvement would have long-lasting and damaging consequences.
Once again, underlying expectations would deteriorate, with potentially adverse
effects on financial markets, particularly long-term rates.

The result would

be to embed inflation even more deeply into the nation's economic system--with
the attendant debilitating consequences for the performance of the economy.

A

failure to continue on the current path would mean that the next effort would
be associated with still greater hardship.
Progress toward price stability can be achieved most effectively
and with the least amount of economic disruption by the concerted application
of monetary, fiscal, regulatory and other economic policies.

But it is quite

clear that inflation cannot persist over an extended period unless financed
by excessive growth of money.

Thus, a policy of restraint on the growth of

the monetary aggregates is a key element in an anti—inflation strategy.
Targets for the monetary aggregates have been set with the aim of
slowing the expansion of money over time to rates consistent with the needs
of an economy growing in line with its productive potential at reasonably
stable prices.

The speed with which the trend of monetary growth can be

lowered without unduly disturbing effects on short-run economic performance
depends, in part, on the credibility of anti-inflation policies and their




-20-

effects on price expectations as well as on other forces influencing interest
rates and credit market demands, including importantly the fiscal position of
the federal government.

More technically, financial innovation or other fac-

tors affecting the demand for specific forms of money need to be monitored.
In its deliberations concerning the target ranges for 1982, the
Committee recognized that the recent rapid increase in Ml placed the measure
in January well above the average level during the fourth quarter of 1981, the
conventional base for the new target.

Experience has shown that, from time to

time, Ml growth can fluctuate rather sharply over short periods, and these
movements may be at least partially reversed fairly quickly.

The available

analysis suggested that the recent increase reflected in part some temporary
factors of that kind, rather than signalling a basic change in the amount of
money needed to finance nominal GNP growth.
In the light of all these considerations, the FOMC reaffirmed the
following ranges of monetary expansion—tentatively set out in mid-1981—for
the year ending in the fourth quarter of 1982:

for Ml, 2-1/2 to 5-1/2 per-

cent; for M2, 6 to 9 percent, and for M3, 6-1/2 to 9-1/2 percent.^

The FOMC

also adopted a corresponding range of 6 to 9 percent for commercial bank
credit.

These ranges are the same as those agreed to in July and reaffirm the

1. The objective for growth of narrowly defined money over 1982 is set in
terms of Ml only. Last February, when the FOMC set its targets for narrow
money, it was recognized that regulatory changes allowing for the establishment of nationwide NOW accounts would distort the observed behavior of Ml-A
and Ml-B. Accordingly, the targets were set on a basis that abstracted from
the shifting of funds into interest-bearing checkable deposits. Based on a
variety of evidence suggesting that the bulk of the shift to NOW accounts had
occurred by late 1981, the Federal Reserve reaffirmed in December its previously
announced intention that starting in January 1982 shift adjustments would no
longer be published and only a single Ml figure would be released with the
same coverage as Ml-B.




-21-

Federal Reserve's commitment to reduce inflationary forces.

As has been

typical in the past, these changes are measured from actual fourth quarter
levels from the previous year.^
During 1981, Ml-B (shift-adjusted) rose relatively slowly in relation to nominal GNP.^

On the assumption that the relationship between growth

of Ml and the rise of nominal GNP is likely to be more normal in 1982, and
given the relatively low base for the Ml-B range, the Committee contemplated
that growth in Ml this year may well be in the upper part of its range.

At

the same time, the FOMC elected to retain the 2-1/2 percent lower bound for
Ml growth tentatively set last July in recognition of the possibility that
financial innovations—especially techniques for economizing on the use of
checking account balances included in M l — c o u l d accelerate, with restraining effects on Ml growth.
The actual and potential effects on Ml of ongoing changes in financial technology and the greater availability of a wide variety of money-like
instruments and near-monies strongly suggest the need for also giving careful
attention to developments with respect to broader money measures in the implementation of monetary policy.

The range for M2 growth is the same as in 1981

when actual growth slightly exceeded the upper bound of the range.

The Com-

mittee contemplated that M2 growth in 1982 would be somewhat below the 1981

1. Because of the introduction of International Banking Facilities, the bank
credit data after December 1981 are not comparable to earlier data. Thus, the
targets for 1982 are in terms of growth from an average of December 1981 and
January 1982 to the average level in the fourth quarter of 1982.
2. Ml-B velocity, before shift adjustment, rose at a rate closer to historical
experience. However, the shift of funds from savings accounts or other sources
of funds not included in measures of the narrow money supply temporarily
depressed that velocity figure, particularly early in the year.




- 2 2 -

pace, although probably in the upper part of the range.

However, should per-

sonal saving, responding to recent changes in tax law or other influences,
grow substantially more rapidly in relation to income than now anticipated,
or should depository institutions attract an exceptionally large inflow to IRA
accounts from sources outside measured M2, growth of M2 might appropriately
reach—or even slightly exceed—the upper end of the range.

The ability of

depository institutions to compete for the public's savings will, of course,
also be affected in part by deregulatory decisions that may be made by the
Depository Institutions Deregulation Committee.
The 1982 ranges for M3 and bank credit were left unchanged from
those for 1981.

These aggregates again will be influenced importantly by

the degree to which credit demands tend to be focused on short-term borrowing
and are funded at home or abroad.




-23-

Section 4:

The Outlook for the Economy in 1982

Economic activity still appears to be contracting; industrial production and employment certainly declined further in January, with the extent
of the fall worsened by exceptionally bad winter storms.

Demand in the key

sectors that had led the decline—housing and consumer spending—showed some
signs of leveling off as the year began, and the recent cuts in production
likely have helped to relieve some of the remaining inventory imbalances.
Recent weather-related disruptions may affect the incoming data for a time,
but it would appear that the economy is in the process of bottoming out, and
a perceptible recovery in business activity seems likely before midyear.
One element supporting final demands in the economy is the federal
government.

Part of the recent expansion in the deficit reflects the cushion-

ing effects of reduced taxes and increased government expenditures that result
from declining income growth and rising unemployment.

In addition, however,

the build-up in defense spending is a continuing source of stimulus.

The

second phase of the tax reductions that occurs in July will provide another
expansionary impetus to the economy.

At the same time, the deficit—particu-

larly if expected to continue at exceptionally high levels in later y e a r s —
adversely influences current financial market conditions.
The Federal Reserve's objectives for money growth in 1982 are consistent with recovery in economic activity.
concentrated initially in consumer spending.

The expansion is likely to be
Given the substantial margin

of excess capacity, outlays for business fixed investment may remain weak,
particularly if long-term interest rates continue to fluctuate near their
current high levels.




A continuation of high levels of long-term rates also .

-24-

would inhibit the recovery in residential housing, although demographic factors will continue to buttress demands in that sector.
The effort to deal with inflation is at a critical juncture.

The

upward trend in inflation clearly has been halted and the process of reversal
is underway.

There are signs that price setting, wage bargaining, and per-

sonal spending decisions are beginning to be made that over time will serve
to moderate, rather than intensify, inflationary pressures.

Nonetheless, the

behavior of financial markets and other evidence strongly suggests that there
continues to be considerable skepticism that progress in reducing inflation
will be maintained.

Lasting improvement in financial markets—particularly

for longer-term instruments—is dependent on confidence that progress against
inflation will continue; looming federal deficits have served to shake that
confidence.

Prospects for lower interest rates and for sustaining recovery

over a long period—indeed for the timing of recovery—are thus tied to prospects for a more stable price level.
How we emerge from the current recession will be crucial to further
curtailing inflation.

The recovery phases that have followed recent reces-

sions have sometimes been associated with an acceleration of inflation.

How-

ever, if monetary and fiscal policies are appropriately disciplined, this
pattern need not recur; and recovery from the current recession will be consistent with further progress towards achieving sustainable growth, price
stability, and lower levels of interest rates.
Given the current circumstances and in light of the monetary aggregate objectives for the coming year, the individual members of the FOMC have
formulated projections for economic performance in 1982 that generally fall




-25-

within the ranges indicated in the table below.

The members of the FOMC

expect inflation to continue to moderate in 1982.

At the same time, real

activity is expected to accelerate with most of the growth coming in the
second half of the year.

With inflation continuing to be substantial and the

prospect of the federal budget deficit remaining large even as the recovery
gathers momentum, demands for credit should intensify as the year progresses.
In these circumstances, the recovery is likely to be somewhat restrained,
with the result that unemployment probably still will be substantial at
year-end.

Economic Projections for 1982

Actual 1981

Projected 1982
FOMC members
Administration

Changes, fourth quarter to
fourth quarter, percent
Nominal GNP
Real GNP
GNP deflator

9.3
0.7
8.6

8 to 10-1/2
1/2 to 3
6-1/2 to 7-3/4

10.4
3.0
7.2

1.3

8-1/4 to 9-1/2

8.4

Average level in the
fourth quarter, percent
Unemployment Rate

The FOMC member's projections generally encompass those that underlie the Adminstration's recent budget proposals.

The consensus view of the

FOMC anticipates an improvement in inflation during 1982 comparable with the
Administration's as well as a similar outlook for the labor market.




The

- 2 6 -

Adrainistration's projection for real growth falls at the high end of the
FOMC consensus.

If, in the event, prices and wages should respond more

rapidly to anti-inflation policies than historical experience would suggest
or should more favorable productivity trends develop, then the recovery
could be faster without adverse pressures developing on prices, wages, and
interest rates.