View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For re lea s!8 >n delivery
February ..2J9 , 1984

Statement by
Paul A* Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
Committee on the Budget
United States Senate

February 29 , 1984

Mr. Chairman, and members of the Committee, I am pleased
to appear before you today as you focus on the first Concurrent
Budget Resolution for fiscal year 1985.

I shall address myself

briefly to the prospects and challenges that face us as we
consider both monetary and fiscal policies for the remainder
of 1984 and the years beyond*

I believe we have much upon

which to build in working toward long-lasting expansion.

But it

also seems to me evident that difficult decisions are necessary
now to make that prospect a reality.
Over the past two years inflation has slowed dramatically,
reaching the lowest rate in about a decade.
years was a period of serious recession.

The first of those

But 1983 was a year

of recovery stronger than most had believed was likely to occur.
The increase of almost 6-1/4 percent in real output during
1983 was roughly in line with the postwar recovery norm, and
the decline in unemployment has been even sharper than usual.
The fact that we were able to achieve vigorous recovery while
containing inflation is what is so promising for the future.
The pressures of recession, deregulation of some important
industries, and import competition have all contributed to a
greater sense of discipline and realism in pricing and wage
bargaining.

But we cannot, of course, claim success against

inflation until we can combine greater price stability with
prosperity over an extended period.
The chances of "building-in" greater stability will depend
heavily on workers having the opportunity for gains in real




-2-

earnings and on satisfactory corporate profits.

The past two

years have provided a more favorable setting in both respects.
The real income of the average worker has risen as price increases
slowed faster than wages.

After-tax economic profits have

recovered strongly and, relative to the GNP, are close to the
highest years of the 1970 f s.
If these gains are to be maintained, we shall need
productivity growth, we shall need a balanced expansion that
avoids bottlenecks, and we shall need to encourage competition
and investment.
There is some evidence that the dismal productivity trend
of the late 1970fs is changing for the better.

Some of that

evidence is qualitative or particular to one industry or another —
new efforts at cooperation between management and labor,
more flexible work rules, and less regulation.

On an aggregative

level, the evidence, while not yet conclusive, suggests that we
may be seeing not just typical cyclical gains in productivity
but also more lasting improvement.

Productivity gains from

here on are likely to be smaller than those seen in the initial
quarters of recovery.

But there is also reason to hope that

the skills of a more experienced work force, coupled with
management innovations and technological progress, can sustain
a somewhat more favorable trend over the years ahead.
That prospect is, of course, dependent in important part on
new investment -- as is our ability to avoid bottlenecks.

We

have, indeed, seen a rapid increase in some types of investment




-3during the recovery period.

But so far, rising business investment

has been largely concentrated in relatively short-lived equipment
rather than in long-lived plant or major machinery that would
add substantially to production capacity.
rebounded.

Housing has also

But, overall, net new private investment has remained

relatively low as a proportion of total GNP, as shown in Chart
I attached.
As we move from recovery to the expansion phase of economic
activity, business investment should rise over a broader front.
Changes in tax laws enacted in recent years should work in that
direction.

But the question remains whether we can, as a

nation, generate the supply of savings necessary to support
both rising investment and a huge government deficit.

That, it

seems to me, is the key policy issue before us.
The importance of dealing with that issue is highlighted
by several well-known facts.
too high —

Interest rates are already high •—

in absolute terms and relative to current price

trends, tending to restrain those types of investment where
interest costs loom large.

In at least a few industries

—

paper, certain plastic materials, some types of electronic
equipment -- capacity constraints are already looming, and long
lead times for investment mean that plans must be implemented
soon to avoid bottlenecks and threats to noninflationary expansion.
As the economy grows, more inventory investment will also be
needed, adding another demand to our limited supply of savings.




-4For the time beingF we have been able to supplement our
domestic savings by drawing on a large capital inflow from
abroad.

But, as I will discuss a little later, that development

carries risks and dangers of its own and cannot be sustained
indefinitely.
Monetary Policy
I have recently reviewed in some detail with the Banking
Committees our intentions with respect to monetary policy,
in summary, the Federal Open Market Committee essentially
reaffirmed the ranges for the monetary and credit aggregates
for 1984 that were tentatively established last July.

Those

ranges call for growth of the broader aggregates, M2 and M3,
between 6 and 9 percent and growth in Ml of 4 to 8 percent.
These ranges, shown on Table 1, which is attached to my
statement, are 1/2 to 1 percentage point below those for
1983.
The ranges for 1984 envisage that relationships between
monetary and economic activity and inflation —
the "velocity11 of money —

summarized in

will broadly follow more normal

trends and cyclical developments, after departing markedly from
past patterns in 1982 and early 1983.

On that assumption,

monetary and credit growth should be fully consistent with real
economic growth in 1984 in a range of 4 to 4-3/4 percent, provided
that inflation, as anticipated, does not accelerate markedly.
The gains in output are expected to generate a further expansion
of new job opportunities and the unemployment rate is expected
to decline to the area of 7-1/2 to 7-3/4 percent by year's end.
These economic projections, which are "central" tendencies of



-5projections of the members of the FOMC, are broadly consistent
with the short-term projections of the Administration and the
Congressional Budget Office,
We do intend, as the year progresses, to assess closely the
relationship between monetary and economic activity and inflation,
testing the assumptions and the analysis that suggest more
normal "velocity" relationships are returning.

In shaping

policy, however, we are strongly conscious of the need to avoid
any strong resurgence of inflationary pressures as the economy
expands.
Economic projections extending several years ahead are
necessarily more problematical.

Both the Administration and the

Congressional Budget Office have projected continuing growth,
reduced unemployment, and, in varying degrees, limited
further progress against inflation*

Projections of that sort,

as a basis for planning, seem to me reasonable.

But we should

not be deluded into mistaking a projection for a certainty
or even a probability —

—

unless we are willing to take the

measures reasonably necessary to achieve that end.

Specifically,

the way the final choices before this Committee are reached will
bear critically on the chances of meeting those economic
projections.
In this context, more rapid monetary and credit growth in
an effort to speed progress toward lower interest rates would
all too likely be counter-productive.

The economy, driven in

large part by the purchasing power implicit in the deficit, is




—b—

already growing at a satisfactory pace.

By feeding the concerns

about inflation, excessive monetary growth would, in the end,
have a perverse influence on interest rates.

The resultant

heightened fears of inflation and instability would only reduce
incentives to save and the willingness of firms to make long-term
commitments to productive investment*

The continuing flow of

funds from abroad, upon which we are dependent for the time
being, would be discouraged.

Depreciation of the dollar externally

as a result of inflationary policies would not, in the end,
help our exporters, or those competing with imports, because
that depreciation would be accompanied by inflated domestic
costs.
In a real sense, one key contribution that the Federal Reserve
itself must make to our lasting prosperity is to foster the
expectation —

and the reality —

won gains against inflation.

that we can sustain the hard-

In the end, that will set the

stage for further lasting reductions in interest rates and a
sustained, better balanced, expansion in economic activity
generally.
The Role for Fiscal Policy
What we in the Federal Reserve cannot do, by manipulating
the money supply, is to achieve a better balance between the
demand for, and supply of, savings.

That is the essential role

for fiscal policy.
The state of the federal budget affects both directly and
indirectly the demands on the economy.




The increase in the

deficit that was recorded last year helped account for the
speed of the rebound in economic activity, even though interest
rates, in historical terms, remained high.

The deficit, in

effect, increased purchasing power at a time when the economy
was still feeling the effects of recession.

However, as the

economy has grown, the adverse effects of the imbalance of
domestic savings and investment on credit markets and on our
external accounts have become more apparent.

And those imbalances

can only worsen if deficits of the magnitude projected by the
Congressional Budget Office and others —

deficits without

precedent during a period of economic expansion — a r e

permitted

to materialize in coming years.
The two charts I have attached to my statement illustrate
the sharp difference between the present budget trajectory and
previous periods of economic recovery and expansion.

The

first of those charts, summarizing sources and uses of available
savings, shows graphically how the deficit in 1984 will continue
to account for more than half of the demands for savings (net
of depreciation).

Those demands will, in fact, substantially

exceed our capacity to save domestically —

an amount that for

many years has fluctuated roughly between 6-1/2 and 8-1/2
percent of the GNP.

Consequently, we are forced to increasingly

look abroad for capital to supplement our domestic savings.
For some time, we have been able to draw upon foreign
savings relatively easily.

Funds have been attracted not just

by our interest rates and by our strong stock market, but by




-8relative confidence in our economic and political stability.
The effect has been to blunt some of the impact of the budget
deficit on our interest rates, and to help finance both the
deficit and investment.
But, over time, reliance on increasing amounts of foreign
capital is a tenuous and risky way to finance domestic growth
and capital formation.

It exacts a large cost in terms of

rising trade and current account deficits —
cannot be sustained indefinitely.

deficits that

Moreover, a steady and

growing flow of foreign capital is dependent on confidence in
our ability to properly manage our economic affairs, on relatively
high interest rates, or both.

To the extent our monetary or

fiscal policies fail to justify that confidence —

to the

extent inflationary pressures again appear to be ascendant or
our external financial position is steadily weakened by large
foreign borrowings —

the greater the risk that new capital flows

from abroad will come less freely, with adverse consequences
for the dollar and for interest rates.
The second chart underscores the extraordinary nature of
our present fiscal position.
period —

1975 —

In only one earlier recession

did the Federal Government absorb so large a

share of total credit flows, and in every postwar economic
cycle, borrowing by the Treasury diminished substantially as a
share of total credit flows during the second year of recovery.
In contrast, the fraction of credit going to the Treasury, at
35 to 40 percent, will not decline much, if at all, this year
from the unusually high level we saw in 1983.



-9To put the point another way, Treasury debt is expected
to increase about 17 to 18 percent this year.
grows about 10 percent this year —

Assuming credit

just above the mid-point of the

FOMC's range -- all other demands for credit could rise by some
8 percent, no more than in 1983 (the first year of recovery).
This would be an unusual cyclical pattern.
The Treasury is going to get the funds it needs to cover
the federal deficit.

The question is whether other sectors

will get enough funds, at reasonable interest rates, to support
the balanced, higher investment, expansion we want.

To some

extent, improved profits and cash flow, relative to other
recent expansions, could help forestall excessive pressures.
But the kind of expansion we and others forsee does imply more
business borrowing, and housing and consumer credit needs

—

increasing by 11 and 15 percent, respectively, over the last
half of the past year —

are already expanding rapidly.

In essence, the demands of the Federal Government limit
the rate of growth of other credit-absorbing sectors of the
economy.

The rationing device is interest rates held higher

than would otherwise be the case.

Under the circumstances,

the more rapidly the economy grows and generates private credit
demands, the greater the risk of rising interest rates.
We can, in concept, visualize an economic expansion that
continues despite financial strains -- an expansion characterized
by relatively high interest rates and by high consumption
supported by large deficits, but markedly sluggish investment




-10and a widening trade deficit.

That, in itself, is hardly

desirable, in terms of the staying power of the expansion
and future growth and productivity.

But we also have to be

conscious of the added risks such financial pressures would
pose —

to thrift and other financial institutions, to less

developed countries with heavy debt burdens, and their creditors
in the U.S. and elsewhere, and to the fabric of international
trade.

At some unknown point the sustainability of the expansion

itself would be jeopardized.
We cannot reasonably escape from these problems by
"monetizing" the Treasury debt through excessive expansion of
bank credit and the money supply. The Federal Reserve, could,
in concept, take an approach which inflated all the numbers,
but it cannot increase savings and reduce the savings-investment
imbalance by undermining confidence.
with the source of the problem —

What must be done is to deal

the excessive deficits.

While it

is already late to make significant changes for fiscal year 1984,
action now affecting fiscal 1985 and later years can only
work in the direction of moderating potential pressures; if
sufficiently forceful, the market could then well anticipate the
time the actions become effective.

At the least, the risks of

eroding confidence and new market pressures should be relieved.
I know you are aware of another reason why expeditious
action to reduce deficits is desirable:
being projected can be self-perpetuating.




the large deficits now

-11-

The direct effects are obvious.

Interest payments on

debt issued to finance this year's deficit add to the deficit
next yearf and interest payments on those deficits increase
exponentially into the future, making it more difficult to
reverse the momentum.
Let me illustrate the point somewhat differently.

The

Administration and the CBO's estimates of the Administration's
budget program differ in considerable part because of the
underlying economic assumptions used.

Specifically, the higher

deficit forecasts of the CBO assume that interests rates will
not decline as much as the Administration, compounding the
effects of higher deficits originating from other factors.
But, if we seize the opportunity to take stronger and early
positive action to reduce the deficit, and that action helps
encourage lower interest rates than projected by the CBO, then
the deficit can be placed on a trend more in accord with
Administration estimates.

In other words, procrastination

plainly exacerbates the problem, leaving us all with still more
difficult choices not very far down the road.
Somewhat less obvious may be new budgetary pressures
arising out of the attempts of various special interests
consumers, workers or firms —

—

to offset the effects of sustained

high deficits on our international competitive position and on
interest rates.




For example, the deterioration in the position

-12of our industrial and farm products in world markets is already
generating demands for subsidies, tax relief and special protections
for economic sectors as diverse as the family farm and the
steel industry.

The effects of high interest rates on construction

and housing costs call forth requests for new programs in those
areas.
I suspect all of this is, by now, familiar to you.

The

real obstacle to action is not intellectual, but the difficulty
of reaching a practical consensus on specific spending or
revenue measures to deal with the problem. In a sense, dealing
with the deficit seems to be everyone's second priority

—

the first is particular spending programs or measures of tax
relief that, viewed in isolation, have strong justification.
Decisions in those areas —
economic dimensions —
Federal Reserve.

with political as well as

are not within the competence of the

I can only urge that they be faced sooner

rather than later before we are enveloped with an atmosphere of
crisis, in financial markets and elsewhere.
Much has been achieved in these last few years to put
the economy on a sounder footing —
cost —

to see it all jeopardized now.

from our own actions —
make a real difference —
control —

or inaction.

The risks arise mainly
The amounts required to

to bring the trend of deficits under

are surely not beyond reach.

the past, and it can be done again.




too much, at too great a

*******

It has been done in

Table 1
Summary of Federal Reserve Monetary and Credit Growth Objectives
and Economic Projections for 1984

Objectives for Money and Credit Growth*

New ranges
for 1984 (%)

Tentative
ranges for
1984 set
in July 1983 (%)

Ranges
for 1983
established
in July 1983 (%)
7 to 10 2

M2

6 to 9

6-1/2 to 9-1/2

M3

6 to 9

6 to 9

6-1/2 to 9-1/2

Ml

4 to 8

4 to 8

5 to 9 3

Domestic
Nonfinancial
Sector Debt

8 to 11

8 to 11

8-1/2 to 11-1/2

It

Ranges apply to periods from fourth quarter to fourth quarter,
except as specified*
2. Range applies to period from February-March 1983 to fourth quarter
of 1983
3. Range applies to period from second quarter of 1983 to fourth quarter
of 1983.

Economic Projections for 1984
FOMC members and
other FRB Presidents
Range
Central tendency

Administration

Change, fourth quarter
to fourth quarter (%)
Nominal GNP
Real GNP
GNP deflator
Average unemployment
rate in the fourth
quarter (%)




8 to 10-1/2
3-1/2 to 5
4 to 6

9 to 10
4 to 4-3/4
4-1/2 to 5

9.8
4.5
5.0

7-1/4 to 8

7-1/2 to 7-3/4

7.7

Chart I

Demands on Available Saving (Net)
Percent

As a percent of GNP
~«® Federal Budget Deficit Plus Net Investment = Net Saving

Deficit

<» «s» Net Private Investment

I
1970

1975

I

I

1

1980

I

1983 1984

Sources of Available Saving (Net)
Percent

As a percent of GNP
«"•• Net Saving = Federal Budget Deficit Plus New Investment
- ~ Domestic Saving

Saving From Abroad

Net Investment Abroad

I
1970

1975

1980

Note: 1984 figures based on FOMC members' projections for the economy and estimates of the federal budget.
essentially* equals the current account deficit.




I
1983 1984
Saving from abroad

Chart E

Share of Total Credit Taken by U.S. Government4'
Percent

First Year of Expansion

50

Second Year of Expansion
40

30

20

10

+
0

10

20

1954-56

|

1958-60

|

1961-63

I

1971-72

I

1975-77

Percent

—

—

50

—

40

—

30

—

20

—

10

Current Recovery
-—

1983

1984
rr-rrTITTTP

Average of Previous Cycles

iL
# Net borrowing by U.S. Treasury as a percent of total credit flow to domestic nonfinancial sectors.


1

i

......