View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

release on delivery
AM, E.D.T.
28, 1982

Statement by
Paul A. Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on the Budget
United States Senate

July 28, 1982

I am pleased to have this opportunity to meet with
you again to review the monetary and budgetary situation in
the light of our economic objectives.

Just last week, I

testified at some length before the Banking Committees of the
Senate and House; instead of repeating that full statement this
morning/ I have attached it to my brief remarks today.
I do want to take this occasion to recognize particularly
the leadership of members of this Committee in pressing for the
budgetary savings reflected in the First Resolution.

Given the

nature of our budgetary problems, that step cannot be the last
if we are to bring the fiscal deficit under control.

But it

does represent, in most difficult circumstances, encouraging
evidence of the willingness and determination of the Congress
to undertake the necessary effort.
In presenting our monetary and credit "targets" to the
Banking Committees last week, I noted that the basic objective
of Federal Reserve monetary policy is the fostering of an environment conducive to sustained recovery in business activity, while
maintaining the financial discipline needed to restore reasonable
price stability.

In reviewing the appropriate means to those

broad ends, the Federal Open Market Committee at its recent
meetings concluded, in effect, that the quantitative objectives
for the various Ms set forth at the beginning of the year should
not be changed at this time, but that we would find an outcome
around the top of those target ranges fully acceptable.
In reaching that conclusion, we considered carefully
and explicitly the intent of the Congress, as expressed in the




-2-

First Budget Resolution, that the Federal Reserve "reevaluate
its monetary targets__in order to assure that they are fully
complementary to a new and more restrained fiscal policy."
In the light of that Resolution, as well as other factors,
we debated the appropriateness of the monetary targets for
1982.
Analysis of past experience suggested strongly that
the previously announced targets, particularly with growth
around the top of the range, should provide enough money and
liquidity to support moderate expansion over the remainder of
this year.

Pressing aggressively to reduce monetary growth well

within the ranges did not seem desirable at this stage of economic
developments, particularly in light of the evidence of a demand
for liquidity for precautionary —
purposes.

as opposed to transactions

—

A sizable increase in the ranges, on the other hand,

might imply a buildup of money and liquidity to the degree that
it would impair the effort needed to maintain and extend the
encouraging progress toward di&-inflation.
In reaching that judgment, we were conscious that the strong
liquidity demands evident in recent months could shift quickly as
the economy showed signs of recovery, and that raising the targets
could easily be misconstrued as a willingness to tolerate more
inflation.

At the same time, the Committee clearly recognized

that possible demands for liquidity in the current uncertain
economic circumstances would continue to require a degree of
flexibility and judgment in assessing appropriate needs for
money in the months ahead.




-3-

We could observe that, over the first half of the year,
the desire of individuar^and businesses to hold assets in
relatively liquid forms appeared to be extraordinarily strong,
apparently reflecting concerns about the business and financial
situation.

One reflection of that may be found in the large

declines in the "velocity" of money over the recession period

—

that is, the ratio of the gross national product to measures
of money.

That drop in velocity is particularly striking in

view of the persistence of high interest rates, suggesting a
heightened desire to hold money or liquid assets relative to
earlier trends.
While.velocity often fluctuates widely over short
periods of time, trends have been much more stable over time.
Assuming that velocity rebounds in the second half —
occurs early in a period of economic recovery —

as typically

the targets

established at the beginning of the year for the monetary
aggregates should be fully consistent with economic expansion
in a context of declining inflation.
points in that direction.

Postwar experience strongly

However, the Committee explicitly

considered the possibility that relatively strong precautionary
demands for money could persist.

In that event —

inevitably involve elements of judgment —

and it would

growth of the aggregates

somewhat above the targeted ranges would be tolerated for a time
as consistent with the FOMC's general policy thrust.
In looking ahead to 1983, the Committee has decided to
retain tentatively the existing targets.

The FOMC will review

the decision at the start of next year, taking account of, among




-4-

other things, the behavior of velocity over the remainder of
this year.

Since we expect that the monetary aggregates will

be near the upper ends of their ranges at the end of 1982, the
tentative targets for 1983 would be consistent with somewhat
slower money growth next year.

With inflation declining, the

tentative targets should be compatible with continuing recovery
at a moderate pace and an improvement in employment opportunities.
In approaching these policy decisions, I have been very
conscious of the fact that monetary policy, however important,
is only one instrument of economic policy*

The attainment of

our common objective of a strong and prosperous economy depends
also on appropriately complementary policies in the fiscal
sphere and in the private sector.
Relaxing discipline on money growth might seem attractive
to some as a means of alleviating stresses in financial markets.
Indeed, in circumstances in which inflationary expectations and
pressures are quiescent, the immediate effect of encouraging
faster growth in money might be to lower interest rates, particularly in short-term markets.

In time, however, an attempt to

maintain lower interest rates by excessive money growth would
founder.

The net result would be to imbed inflation even more

deeply into our economic system, and to make buyers of fixedinterest securities still more wary.

Sooner or later, public

and private demands for credit would reflect the higher price
levels, and savings likely would be discouraged.




Market pressures




-5-

would return in amplified force.

Put simply, inflationary

money creation provides no escape from the pressures of demands
for credit, nor can money creation substitute for real savings.
We can, of course, affect that balance of demand and
supply in credit markets by fiscal and other policies, and that
is why I welcome the effort of the Congress to achieve greater
fiscal restraint.

I recognize —

and more importantly the markets

recognize -•- sizable obstacles remain in converting the intentions
expressed in the First Budget Resolution into concrete legislative
action; harmonizing the values and aims of the authorizing and
revenue committees —

indeed the values and aims of our citizens

—

within the constraints of budgetary discipline is always difficult,
and no more so than in today's circumstances.
Moreover, the effort this year must be put in a larger
perspective.

Even if the objectives of the Budget Resolution

are fully achieved for next year and the underlying economic
assumptions are realized, the deficit in FY 1983 would be about
as large as this year's.

Moreover, the risks seem, in my judgment,

all on the side of a still greater deficit, despite your important
efforts.

If the deficit turns out to be larger than expected

entirely because of a shortfall in economic growth or inflation
and I would point out that the members of the FOMC anticipate
somewhat less real growth and inflation (and thus inflationgenerated revenues) than the Congress ~
not be a source of much concern.

that "ac^d on" should

What is of concern is that you

—

-6-

are working from so large a "structural" deficit —

a deficit

that would exist even in a relatively prosperous economy

—

and that concern would mount to the extent the targeted savings
are not achieved.
As we appraise the fiscal situation today, projected
deficits continue to carry the implicit threat of "crowding out"
business investment and housing as the economy expands -- a
process that would imply significantly higher interest rates
than would otherwise result•

Your continuing leadership in

prodding your colleagues in the Congress to deal with the
budget dilemma thus remains crucially important to the outlook
for interest rates and the credit markets.
Put more positively, significant progress in paring
the deficits will contribute importantly to lower interest
rates and reduced strains in financial markets within any
monetary framework*

That budgetary policy, as we see it, is

not fundamentally a substitute for disciplined monetary policy
but rather an essential complement.
When monetary policy alone must carry the burden of
dealing with inflation, and when fiscal deficits absorb so
large a fraction of the capacity of the economy to generate
savings, pressures tend to concentrate on financial markets and
on vulnerable credit-dependent sectors of the economy*

Con-

versely, budget restraint relieves those pressures and risks
directly, and would reinforce the growing sense of conviction
that the inflationary tide has turned.







While the Open Market^eOTttnittee, in responding to the
Budg&t Resolution, did not feel thait larger growth in the money
supply over time would be desirable, let me also say that I
believe a credibly firmer budgetary posture would permit us a
degree of greater flexibility in the short-run conduct of policy.
Specifically, by damping concern about a resurgence of inflation
or credit itiarket pressures, fiscal restraint also lessens fears
that short-run increases in the money supply might presage a
continuing inflationary monetization of the debt.

But any gains

in that respect will of course depend on firmness in implementing
the intentions set forth in your First Resolution, and encouraging
confidence among investors and borrowers that the effort will be
sustained and reinforced in coming years.
I need not dwell on the fact that we are in most difficult
economic circumstances, with unemployment far too high, with
strong pressures on financial markets, and with a sense of widespread uncertainty.

We cannot build a sound program against infla

on a base of continuing recession.

But let us recognize, too,

that we have come a long way toward turning back the inflationary
tide that had come to grip our economy over the decade of the
1970s, and that there is promising evidence of improvements in
productivity and efficiency underway.

More recently, there are

at least some signs that the "grid-lock" in the financial markets
may be beginning to break up; interest rates, while still very
high in historical perspective, have declined to the lowest levels
for some time.
The challenge is to sustain that progress during a period
of recovery, for it is that progress that is needed to extend and
support economic expansion over the long years ahead.

Monetary

-8-

and fiscal policies alike need to be directed, and work in
concert, toward that objective.

In that context, I and my

colleagues believe a continuing dialogue with members of this
Committee is highly constructive, and I welcome your comments
and questions.