View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

release on delivery
1 "pnn. TTTSTT. f2 p.m. E.S.T.)
Saturday, March 30, 1985

Remarks by
Paul A. Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




before the
XIII American-German Biennial Conference
Dallas, Texas
March 30, 1985

- 1 It is not just a routine remark for me to say I'm glad to be back, at
least for a day, at this Biennial Conference. There are old friends from both
sides of the Atlantic that have labored long and effectively to enhance and
preserve German-American relations. Maybe more important, there are, as well,
younger people ready to carry the work forward.
The American Council on Germany and the Atlantik-Brucke are, in
themselves, small organizations, and the Biennial Conference one among many
meetings. But their importance lies in being catalysts for sanething much
larger. They are a part of the cannon cause — the "gemeinsame Sache" — that
has inspired the relations between our two great nations over the postwar era.
That common cause is built on a solid foundation — a mutual respect
through the years for the basic principles of market-oriented economies, of
freedom of trade and capital movements, of stability, and of democracy and of
the interdependence of our security.
But however strong, common foundations do not automatically result in
harmonious architecture or understanding relationships ainong different
households. That takes constant nurturing and effort. And that was the role




- 2 ~
the American Council and the Atlantik Brucke undertook sane 30 and more years
ago. Under the inspired leadership of John McCloy and Chris Enmnett on the
American side, and with Konrad Adenauer helping to inspire the work of sane
eminent and thoughtful Germans, a real impact could be made at a critical
time. The founders were wise enough to recognize that, for all the
antagonisms and distortions of war, the foundation was there, and that an
edifice of productive cooperation could be rebuilt — that indeed it would be
an essential to peace and prosperity more generally.
How accurate their perception was!
Of course, the specific challenge then seemed quite different.
America appeared as a kind of colossus standing astride a largely shattered
world economy — and also a strong beacon of hope to younger Germans looking
toward finally building a stable democracy from the ruins of the past. For
our part, farsighted men saw that our own prosperity and security could not be
pursued in isolation, but only as a part of an Atlantic world in which a
rebuilt Germany would naturally have to play a large role. In that context,
there was a natural impetus among sane key leaders of good will on both sides




- 3 to reach out and work together — to put aside all the anger and divisive
forces.
I suppose the celebration of John McCloy's 90th birthday symbolizes
the passage of that era.
Germany has long since fully recovered economically. The plant of
democracy is strongly rooted — and with it sane of the diversions and
uncertainties characteristic of democracies everywhere. Moreover, Germany
plays a key role of leadership in the European Community that, economicallyf
is as large or larger than the United States. So other preoccupations/
internal and external, political and econanic, have quite naturally sprung up
that can dilute the trans-Atlantic tie.
Among a new generation in both countries, without the fresh and
personal memory of war and destruction, the strong imperative to work together
may not be so instinctive. We both have other concerns — not necessarily
inconsistent with close trans-Atlantic relationships — but perhaps turning
more of our energies to other priorities.




- 4 Nonetheless, the foundation of canton economic and political
philosophies remains, and with it the conmon cause. As I see it, the American
Council and the Atlantik Brucke have a special responsibility to help maintain
the flame — keeping the lines of communication and cooperation open among
leaders, supporting contact and educational exchanges among new generations,
and helping to identify and deal with points of friction as they emerge. In
sane ways, the job may be more difficult today than in the aftermath of war
precisely because, on the surface, it may no longer seem so urgent — it's too
easy to take a basic cooperation for granted. But the fact is the
relationship needs constant attention lest we inadvertently drift apart.
In the area of economic policy, a high degree of understanding
between the United States and the Federal Republic has been — and I think
remains — natural because the basic market orientation of both countries has
been so strong, and because of our mutual concerns about economic and price
stability. Certainly, I can testify that relationships between our central
banks and finance ministries are easy, personal, and more or less continuous
— the old diplonatic phrase of "frank and full discussions" carries no
ambiguous connotation in describing those contacts.



- 5 Naturally, economic performance has not always met our aspirations.
Our fall from grace in the United States on the stability front during the
1970?s was more marked than in Germany, and the weakness of the dollar at the
time complicated the job of econonic management in Germany. In these past few
yearsf as we have struggled with sane success to restore price stabilityt I
sense German officials have been consistently supportive of the priority
necessary for that effort. They have been so, even as the recovery and then
soaring strength of the dollar again complicated German monetary management.
I suppose that welcone support for our efforts is instinctive for a country
whose central bank, at its creation, received a special charge as "guardian of
the currency" in recognition of the fundamental priority for stability in a
well-functioning economy*
Today, we can observe in the industrialized world as a whole a
pattern of converging price performance at a relatively low level of
inflation. I know a lot remains to be done. But for the first time since the
1960's there has been clear progress toward the holy grail of stability — the
internal stability that, we have told each other constantly, is the




- 6 prerequisite for more stable exchange rates and for sustained and balanced
growth.
I don't have to recite to you all the evidence that those fruits have
been elusive. So far as exchange rates are concerned, the morning paper —
or, if you are a modern-day executive, your computer screen — reports more
volatility, not less*
On the American side, after a deep recession, we have indeed had
vigorous economic expansion — among the strongest in our postwar history. In
two years, employment has increased by seme lh million, and the unemployment
rate has dropped by 2h percent; more of our population is at work than ever
before. Business investment has surged higher, and productivity trends have
shown seme signs of improvement from the poor record of the 1970's.
On the other side of the Atlantic, in contrast, Germany has found it
difficult to generate new jobs despite seme evident recovery in economic
activity. And that pattern has been typical of Europe generally, with
imemployment hovering around a postwar high of 20 million, even though most
countries have benefitted from strong markets in the United States. In Japan,




- 7 growth has been faster, and unemployment remains lew. But even more than in
Europe, much of the expansionary impetus has cone from abroad.
That contrast in recent performance has, as you know, fed and
reinforced a striking change in psychology and attitudes toward the outlook in
Europe and the United States — Euro-pessimism on the one hand, and renewed
confidence and optimism in the United States on the other. And that contrast
in attitudes amplified the extraordinarily strong rise in the dollar over most
of the past two years, even in the face of shaiply rising trade and current
account deficits*
The contrast in attitudes is, of course, more than an economic
phenomenon. But an economist observing the history of the postwar period can,
I think, raise seme questions as to whether the swing in sentiment has not
been overdone.
My own education and experience in international finance began in the
1950's, during the days of the so-called "dollar shortage." And I well recall
that, no sooner had we digested and half begun to believe all those learned
treatises explaining why the demand for dollars would remain virtually




- 8 -

inexhaustible, the facts and the perception changed. At the beginning of the
1960fs, the Deutsche mark was revalued slightly upwards, and that was just the

harbinger of a strong trend toward appreciation.

Instead of dollar shortages,

we soon began analyzing the "dollar overhang," and elaborate plans were

spawned for funding or consolidating "excess" dollar holdings abroad. And in

the 1970's, Germans could too glibly talk of the decay —

der Verfall — of

the dollar.

Well, only a few years later, the dollar was born again —

and we

have heard much more talk of "super dollar" than of decay. Dollar assets have

been described as the most attractive of all investments, seemingly oblivious

of prevailing rates of exchange or the fact that we have been swinging fast

from being the world's largest creditor to being its largest debtor nation.

Any central banker is inclined to like a strong currency —

particularly one that reflects internal strength.

I am no exception in that

respect. There have indeed been solid reasons for the recovery of the dollar
from the morass of the 1970fs. But I am also more than a little skeptical of

the notion that Germany, and Europe as a whole, are somehow trapped in




- 9 structural rigidities that doom it to slow growth and leave little or no room
for policy maneuver — or that the United States can safely relax in the glow
of a strong cyclical expansion.
lt?s hard for me to forget, for instance, that through the 1970fs the
German economy was characterized by considerably faster growth in productivity
than the United States, that "guest workers" were needed, that German industry
was and remains highly carpetitive in international markets. Certainly,
Germany has for a long time maintained a better record on price stability than
its trading partners. And it's equally hard to be oblivious to the fact that
the rising trade deficit in the United States is new undercutting our
expansion and incentives to invest domestically over a wide range of
manufacturing industries.
The current volatility of exchange rates mirrors an unsettled nature
of expectations — the sense that something is out of kilter, despite all the
progress made toward containing inflation here and elsewhere and toward
restoring growth. And certain facts seem to me to underline that uneasiness.




- 10 There is the still widening gap in our trade accounts, which has
increased by sane $100 billion since 1982, hardly a sustainable trend. Our
interest rates are still extraordinarily high, by world standards or those of
our own experience* Abroad, unemployment has been stuck at high rates, and
much of the expansionary impulse has been derived from the United States,
rather than "hone grown/1
But I also believe that we all have made a lot of progress toward our
mutual goals of growth and stability, and we can build on it. What needs
still to be done, here and abroad, seems to me both reasonably clear and well
within our economic and political capacity to jjnplement, so long as we work
together.
None of you will be surprised to hear me say that decisive action to
narrow the Federal budget deficit in the United States ranks first on the list
of needed actions -- and that we should achieve as much of that as possible by
reining in expenditure growth. The simple fact is that we have an enormous
gap between what we save internally and the deinands we place on those savings.
So long as we face the need to finance huge deficits, now approximating $200




- 11 billion, on top of business investment and housing needs, that disequilibrium
will remain. And, one way or another, the economy will be distorted.
So far, we have been able to bridge the savings-investment gap with
surprising ease by drawing on savings from abroad in unprecedented quantities,
amounting to fully a quarter of our net domestic needs for investment and
deficit financing. But that capital inflow, in turn, implies an equally large
and rising current account deficit. Sectors of the American economy exposed
to international competition — that is, much of industry, mining, and
agriculture — are paying a heavy price. Surely, a process of sharply rising
international indebtedness and a weakening competitive position is not
sustainable indefinitely.
Right now, we have no satisfactory alternative to prolonging the
capital inflow because neither the budget deficit nor the trade deficit will
disappear overnight. That will require us to maintain a strong sense of
confidence in our ability to maintain growth in a framework of stability. In
that respect, there is a particularly heavy burden on monetary policy.
Certainly it is not an environment in which we can neglect the effort to




- 12 nurture greater price stability, upon which confidence depends* In such
circumstances, to yield to any temptation to try to substitute money creation
for a shortfall in real savings would be to aggravate the problem.
Instead, we have to close the budget gap. If that takes time, as it
must, to fully jinplement, it is within our ability to take decisive action to
set us on a clear path toward that goal. The critical time, for the economy
and for the political calendar, is now.
Out of sheer frustration, as things now stand, pressures are building
in the United States for protectionistic measures, even among industries and
segments of the labor movement that traditionally have supported liberal
trading policies. Such a response would deal with symptoms, not causes. In
the end, like inflationary policies, protectionism would only complicate the
problem. It does not deal with the underlying imbalance between our capacity
to generate internal savings and the demands we place upon those savings.
So long as that basic imbalance remains, we perhaps could, in theory,
shift the pressure points from one sector of the economy to another. Suppose,
for instance, we somehow succeeded in reducing the trade deficit by the brute




- 13 force of controls, or by depreciating the currency. Then, by definition, the
net inflow of capital would also decline. Other sectors of the economy
dependent, directly or indirectly, on that flew of capital would be sharply
impacted — with housing potentially the most vulnerable. And it's also
evident that any purely economic analysis of that kind of "trade-off" can not
capture the crushing effects of the largest and strongest economy in the world
leading us all into the trading equivalent of mutually assured destruction.
Those protectionist pressures are rightly being resisted by the
Administration and, more or less successfully so far, in the Congress. But I
suspect that political resistance can be well sustained only to the extent our
trading partners — especially in the industrialized world, but in developing
nations as well — resist protectionist pressures within their own countries,
and those in exceptionally strong trading positions — such as Japan — must
find the will and the means to move toward liberalization.
Germany has, of course, been in the forefront of that effort through
the years. There, it may not be so much a question of more liberalization,
but of taking continuing leadership in the mutual effort to encourage others




- 14 to emulate its example. The torch of further liberalization through
international negotiations needs to be held high; Germany has strongly
supported that initiative.
Such negotiations may well be a labor of years. But, in this
instance, as in so many others, a good offense — a clear sense of
constructive goals and steady effort toward those goals — may be our best
defense.
In other respects, there are strong positive aspects of our recent
performance, and these may have implications for others.
Certainly, Germany, like other countries, does have important
structural rigidities that impede new business formation and innovation,
impair labor markets, and inhibit growth. Those rigidities need to be dealt
with. It takes time. An outsider can offer little in the way of detailed
prescriptions for another econany with its own social and political
traditions. But we can and do welcome the clear recognition and emphasis on
those structural problems in a country whose example and efforts are so
important for the whole of Europe.




- 15 One wonders whether that necessary process can be integrated with,
and indeed supported by f some changes in emphasis in more general economic
policy. Gennany through recent decades has achieved a remarkable record of
price stability. Notably, that record has been well maintained even in the
face of the sharp depreciation of the DM against the dollar, which has been
reflected in rising costs for oil and sane other imports. Moreover,
substantial progress has been made in containing a relatively large budget
deficit that arose in earlier years.
No central banker — certainly not this one — has anything but
support and admiration for those efforts.
At the same time — looking ahead — there are sane nagging
questions•
For more than two years, growth in the United States has, directly
and indirectly, provided the principal impetus for the world economy. The
United States accounts for sane 40 percent of the GNP of all OECD countries.
But in 1983 and 1984, the growth of demand in the United States accounted
directly for sane 70 percent of OECD growth, and indirectly presumably for




- 16 more. While our output, measured by the GNP, rose by more than 12 percent
over those two years, sane $140 billion of demand generated in the United
States flowed abroad• That demand created exports, jobs, and GNP elsewhere
than in this country. Indeed, for sane countries, growth in exports to the
United States has been the most important single factor providing stimulus to
their economies.
For awhile, that pattern has brought benefits to both sides — growth
abroad, and useful products and resistance to inflation in the United States.
But huge and widening trade imbalances are not a secure foundation for
sustaining growth or containing inflation either here or abroad. And the
prospect now is that, after two years of extraordinary growth, the pattern of
expansion in the United States may be less ebullient. Indeed, as I indicated
earlier, import penetration has itself reached the point of discouraging sane
domestic production and investment.
Fortunately, in Germany and elsewhere in the industrialized world, a
growth trend now seems to be reasonably well established. Yet, that growth,
in the eyes of most observers, official and non-official, does not seem to be




- 17 strong enough in Europe to reduce appreciably the historically high levels of
unemployment. Moreover, unlike in 1983 and 1984, the impetus from the United
States is likely to be diminishing.
Meanwhile, in Germany, as in the United Kingdon — and in stark
contrast to the United States — the structural budget position appears to
have reached balance or surplus. In other words, the recorded budget deficits
now are a reflection of a period of slew growth and higher-than-normal
unemployment, rather than a basically divergent trend of revenues and
expenditures. Viewed from this distance, one wonders whether, in all the
circumstances, the past efforts have not now won for the authorities a degree
of fiscal flexibility that could be usefully employed, for instance, in
improving incentives and otherwise promoting economic efficiency and
structural adjustment. I know that sane planning for tax reduction has been
on the German agenda.
Should the DM stabilize — or its appreciation relative to the dollar
of recent days persist — one source of upward cost-price pressures in Germany
would end. A natural consequence could be that the monetary authorities, too,




- 18 might find themselves with more maneuvering room, to be usefully employed if
needed to encourage growth, without jeopardizing prospects for stability*
I realize all of that would be much easier in an environment in which
the United States is not itself drawing so heavily on world savings, an
environment in which we could enhance the possibilities of sustaining lover
interest rates consistent with further progress toward price stability. That
is, of course, why action on our budget deficit is so crucial to the whole
effort.
I need hardly belabor the fact that success in the United States, in
Europe, and in Japan in providing growing and open markets will also be
critical to the efforts of much of the developing world to struggle out from
under its heavy burden of debt. After more than two years of successfully
coping with the iirmediate debt crisis, seme lessons seem clear in that
respect.
The major borrowing countries do have the potential for balancing
their external accounts — or at the very least sharply reducing the need for
new bank lending — and at the same time restoring growth. Mexico, Brazil,




- 19 and Venezuela have gone a long way in that direction already, shaving the way
to others* Success over time will, in my judgment, require not only self
discipline but also steps to liberalize their cwn economies. They must be
made more flexible, efficient, and corpetitive and more attractive for private
investment, whether by their cwn citizens or from abroad.
It's not easy for any of us to break out of past patterns.
Constructive new measures in developing countries will be introduced and
sustained only as their leaders can offer people realistic hopes that the
efforts will pay off. And that "pay off," in the end, will be dependent on
our efforts in the industrialized world as well as theirs — our success in
sustaining our own growth, in maintaining open markets, and achieving
reasonable interest rates. No IMF programs, and no series of bank financings
or refinancings, important and imaginative as they can be, can substitute for
those fundamentals.
Nor can we really expect the volatility in exchange markets — with
all its connotations of uncertainty and unsettlement — to subside in any
lasting way without addressing the elements in our policies that give rise to




- 20 economic imbalances . As I emphasized at the start, the cornerstone of that
effort lies in the progress toward price stability among the leading
countries. In that respect, the onens are better than for many years. But
taken alone, that progress may not be enough to assure a stable international
system.
Indeed, our experience with floating exchange rates over the past 15
years has not, to my mind, been totally reassuring — certainly not when
measured against the expectations of many. The floating system has, of
course, been justified on the strongest of all grounds — that, after all, in
its way, it has worked, when no other arrangement seemed practically feasible.
But the amount of volatility has been large, and so far has not decreased.
If we can achieve better balance in our growth, and sustain that
growth in a context of greater price stability, then we should also have the
basic "environmental" conditions for exchange rate stability. If spontaneous
market forces then do not develop a more stable exchange rate system, I
believe we have a further challenge for our cooperation efforts — the
challenge to think hard about ways that governments and central banks can
better encourage that result.



- 21 Inevitably, relationships among the dollar and the mark (in its role as
a national currency and as a central part of the ECU) are pivotal to any wider
stability. And certainly, the exchange rate today is too iitportant an
economic variable to ignore in our policy making. It is sirnply another aspect
of the interdependent nature of our econcmic relationship, the health of which
is of significance to far more than our two countries.
That needed econcmic cooperation can flourish only in the larger
context of sympathetic understanding reaching to all levels of society in our
two great democracies.
In both countries there are carpeting and compelling demands for
attention elsewhere, internally and abroad. To a degree, that's natural and
inevitable. The unique atmosphere of intensity and urgency that led to the
formation of the American Council and the Atlantik Brucke — and that underlay
the broader constructive effort to rebuild our political ties and a shattered
economy — is no longer present. But the need to maintain the strong ties of
communication and understanding that originated in that period remain.




- 22 The function of meetings of this kind, and the work of the American
Council and the Atlantik Brucke, is to attend to that continuing need. I wish
you every success, because nothing seems to me more certain than that the
relationship between our two countries will remain central to our peace and
prosperity.




•

* * * * • • * * • * *