View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
I PVH., P.D.T. (4 P.M. E.D.T.)
Bhursday, May 16, 1985

Address by
Paul A. Volcker
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Focus International Conference on the World Economy and Peace




Seattle, Washington
May 16, 1985

It is a great pleasure -- and challenge —

to appear

before you today to lead off your program on "The World Economy
and Peace."

But I am also conscious that you have set a

daunting challenge for me.

I was asked to address the state

of "the existing world market economy and how it might be
modified to enhance prospects for peace" -— all in thirty
minutes.
My refuge is that I only have to introduce the subject
to presumably make a few provocative or tantalizing comments,
fly home, and leave it to all the rest of you to develop the
subject adequately.
The importance of the subject is undeniable.
occupied the minds of thinkers from time immemoriale

It's
No doubt

cavemen fought each other with stone axes over what we would
now call access to resources and markets.

There are passages

in the Bible and Plato alluding to trade and peace.

In the

more modern era, Karl Marx and John Maynard Keynes both dealt
with the subject -- in quite different ways!



—

-2An economist looking at problems of trade and peace
starts with some simple propositions.
endowed with resources or skills*

Nations are not equally

Consequently, there is an

urgent need to trade with each other to enhance standards of
living*
When economists read history, they observe those circumstances have sometimes lead to political temptations for stronger
and more dominant powers.

They might seek territorial expansion

or political hegemony over other nations.

Gr, more benignlyf

special trading relationships are developed with others.
But, by definition, some are excluded from such arrangements.
Consequently, commercial jealousies and rivalries
emerge.
Looked at from a strictly economic standpoint, economists
have emphasized time and again that free and open trade with
everyone would maximize economic gains through the operation
of laws of comparative advantage.

Stepping outside their

own discipline, some economists have drawn a political conclusion




as wells free trade would also remove one important incentive
to political conflict and war among nations.

A leading

thinker on the subject, Jacob Viner, writing as World War II
ended, summarized the case this way;
08

. « o universal free trade would make every
country dependent on other, and often distant,
countries for some of the essentials of civilian
life and of warfare and therefore would make war
obviously a more hazardous enterprise than it is
today. . * Second, , . # under free trade the
proportion of the population whose everyday means
of livelihood is directly or indirectly dependent
on the uninterruped continuance of foreign trade
would be a maximum « . . Third, under universal
free trade, the attractiveness of territorial
expansion, in so far as this is based on economic
considerations, would be very much reduced.
Fourth, the frictions and controversies which
result from contact with or even mere knowledge
of the existence of foreign trade barriers, tariff
discriminations, and colonial preferences would
be eliminated*"
Well, that's an attractive case for an economic theorist
dedicated to free trade.

And so far as it goes, it seems to

me fundamentally correct.
But there is something lacking.
economist's ideal of free trade.

We don't have an

And Viner's argument implicitly

assumes that free trade is operating within the context of relatively
fully employed, growing economies with a high degree of price and




-4-

exchange rate stability*

Take those assumptions away, and

trade distortions, perceived and real, can become fertile
ground for tensions and acrimony.
Here in Seattle, you look out across the broad Pacific
from an area characterized by great natural resources.

At the

other end of the economic spectrum, it is also the home of one of
America's great companies, with a strong position in one of our
most technologically advanced industries.

You have a natural

dependence on trade, and large potential markets.
But there is an understandable feeling of grievance:
those seeming competitive advantages do not seem to be fairly
reflected in trade patterns.

With our national trade deficit

running at a rate of some $125 billion a year, and with imports
continuing to grow much faster than a slowing domestic economy
over the past year, those complaints are echoed through much
of the industrial and agricultural sectors of our economy.
In the circumstances, protectionist sentiment is coming
to a boil.




And, in greater or lesser degree that's true in some

other countries as well.

It's happening out of sheer frustration,

even though I suspect most thoughtful observers, in government
and out, recognize precisely the dangers that Viner warned
against —

of one restriction breeding another, of trade

antagonisms spilling over into political relationships, and
of damage to the economic prospects and political cohesion
of the Western world.
The day is long since past when we could safely think about
dealing with trade frictions by retreating within ourselves, even
for a country so large and diversified as the United States*
tried that once in 1929, with miserable results.

We

We have too

many mutual dependencies today, and the results could be no better.
Boeing, after all, does sell a lot of planes abroad, and the
Northwest still ships a lot of logs and lumber —

even if those

shipments at times seem subject to less than fair competitive practices.
And that story could be repeated for any region*
Protectionist threats are sometimes rationalized by
the argument that they are a legitimate negotiating tactic,




-6essential to deal with the perceived inequities.
understand and empathize with that approach.

We can all

We need to bring

the message to others that trade is a two-way street.

But let's

be sensitive to the danger that today's negotiating tactic may
become tomorrow's reality.

There have to be more constructive

approaches if the protectionist stew is not to boil over and
burn us all.
The basic function of a conference like this, it seems
to me, should be to explore and encourage those more constructive
approaches.

We should be working toward creating those conditions

in which trade will flourish to the mutual advantage —
seen to be in the mutual advantage —

and be

as Viner assumed.

We don't, in my opinion, have far to look to see the
areas where action is necessary.
understood.

In broad terms, they are widely

But there is a big gap between understanding and

effective action —

and so long as there is, prospects for

economic and political harmony will be jeopardized.




One essential approach, if a liberal trading order is to
be sustained, politically as well as economically, is to make
sure the rules for trade ar^ fairly and uniformly applied.
Virtually every country, with some justice, feels it has
grievances -- certainly including the United States*

And

because we all "sin," to a greater or lesser extent, each of
those complaints has a degree of legitimacy.

And experience shows

that those grievances are often hard to deal with, one-by-one.
That is especially true when trading rules and codes
of behavior are obscure, ineffective, or unenforced*

And as

the nature of trade shifts into new products or services, with more
governmental intervention and with more countries becoming heavily
involved, the more the complications and the dangers increase.
That is the basic reason there has been a lot of
discussion —

most prominently at the recent Economic Summit

about the idea of launching a new round of multilateral trade
negotiations.




The idea has borne fruit in the past with the

—

-8-

successive Dillon, Kennedy, and Tokyo rounds of negotiations
in the GATT negotiations that successfully propelled the
industrialized world toward more open trade and helped to support
the unprecedented pattern of world growth over the post-war decades.
That growth has itself naturally raised new issues*

For

instance, developing countries and many services are not clearly
covered by existing GATT codes.

Nor is the treatment of a number

of important commodities and such matters as subsidies really
adequate for existing circumstances.

Thus, there is plenty

of reason to move forward once again for technical and objective
reasons.

And, it seems to me there is an even more compelling

political reason.
The Summit called for "tangible progress in relaxing and
dismantling trade restrictions."

Certainly, the Administration

in Washington is deeply committed to that approach.

But, of

course, nations collectively have been doing the opposite.

They

have not done so by any single dramatic act, but by conceding




-9to the domestic pressures here and elsewhere, "small" protectionist
measures in one area or another.
Given the strength of the pressures, we can with some
justice, claim some success in holding them at bay —

the

essentials of a liberal trading order have been defended*
But I doubt the protectionist pressures can successfully be turned
back toward freer trade by a succession of small bargains.

More

general multilateral negotiations, to which there can be
political commitments by all participating countries and a wider
area for mutual concessions, stand a better chance of galvanizing
the necessary support and energies.

Or to put the point more

simply, a good offense may be the best defense.
I do not want to suggest multilateral agreements to
reduce trade restrictions, important as they are, end our trading
problems.

Freer trade will not in itself end the massive deficits

in our own trade accounts, or the surpluses of Japan, nor will it
assure the growth and prosperity in national economies necessary




-10to support a liberal trading order.

Indeed, such trade

agreementsf if they are to be possible at all, will need
to be accompanied by other actions to reduce present trading
imbalances and support growth.
The fact is that the recent trends in the external
economic position of the United States are not sustainable
indefinitely.

Over the past two and half years, our trade

deficit (and the deficit on our current account, which
measures trade in all goods and services) has increased by
about $100 billion,
imports.

almost entirely because of rapidly rising

Today, non-oil imports account for some 18 per-

cent of the total output of goods in the United States, a larger
share by 3-1/2 percentage points than in 1982 and 10 percentage
points more than 20 years ago.
From the standpoint of the American consumer, those imports
have brought great benefits in terms of more choice of products at
lower prices.

It has, in the short-run, brought benefits to

our trading partners, which have had high levels of unemployment




-11or which* as in Latin America, have desperately needed to
improve their own external accounts.

But in the absence of a

roughly parallel increase in exports, it has also impacted
sharply on the growth of our own manufacturing and mining
industries, and has required massive borrowings from abroad
to pay the bills.

Indeed, in the space of only a few years,

the United States is shifting from, the world's largest creditor
to its largest debtor.
We are a big and strong country, and we can carry those
debts if we have to.

But the trend is ominous.

At some point,

the pressures on our industries could undermine our own economic
growth and the confidence that underlies the ease which we can
now borrow abroad.
If all that!s true, one might conclude that the solution
is both urgent and simple -- a direct across-the-board assault
on the trade deficit by tariffs or other restrictions.
not that simple.

The trade imbalance reflects in significant

part a massive imbalance in our own policy posture.



But it's

Unless we

-12deal with that underlying imbalance, a basic force driving the
poor trade performance will be left unchecked.

Protectionism

would reap a grim harvest in terms of higher prices, retaliation,
and shrinking trade, while leaving the source of the difficulty
unresolved.
The imbalance to which I refer is, of course, the deficit
in our Federal budget.

In the end, we have to finance that

deficit out of savings, ours or those of some other nations.
In a good year, like 1984, we generate in this country
net savings -- by businesses, by individuals, and by state and
local governments —

of about 8-1/2 to 9 percent of the GNP.

That's within a range that has persisted for 30 years.
have learned from experience, it's hard to change.

As we

At the

same time, we invested last year in housing, inventories, and
plant and equipment about 6-1/2 percent of the GNP (net).

With

the Federal deficit added, demands on savings ran to nearly
12 percent of the GNP.




The difference between our capacity to

-13save and the need for finance was made up by borrowing from
abroad*

That borrowing is necessarily matched by a current

account deficit, and the rapidly rising imports have generated
that deficit.
So we are in a dilemma.

On the one hand, we count on

savings from abroad to help, directly or indirectly, to finance
our Federal deficit.

On the other hand, we understandably

are concerned about the large and growing trade deficit that
threatens to sap the vitality of our industry.

But the capital

inflow and the trade deficit are two sides of the same coin.
Do away with the trade deficit, and we also would do away with
the net capital inflow.

Without the capital inflows, pres-

sures on our domestic financial markets would increase, undercutting prospects for housing and investment.
The lesson is plain.

We should be less dependent on

capital inflows to maintain balance in our domestic capital and
credit markets.

But we don't want to cut back on investment.

The only reasonable alternative is action on our budgetary problem,




-14Let me put the point directly.

Action to reduce the

budget deficit must be a fundamental part of any constructive
effort to deal with the trade imbalance.

It is thus a basic

element in the effort to support and maintain a liberal trading
order.
That, as you well know, implies tough political choices.
I have no competence to suggest where those budgetary savings
should be made.

But I do know that progress needs to be made,

and made p.d.q.
The Senate, as you know, recently made an encouraging
start in that direction.

Now it is the turn of the House.

There

is no more urgent business than achieving a reconciliation of
difficult approaches toward achieving the needed savings.
Your representatives in the Congress will need your strong
support to complete that effort.
So far, we have been able to enjoy a strong expansion
despite the growing trade deficit, although signs of strain are
showing.




As I suggested a few moments agof the United States,

for more than two years, has also been able to act as a kind
of motor for the economy of the industrialized world as a whole.
We've provided strong markets for the hardpressed developing
countries that must expand their exports*

Foreign capital

has come to our shores freely, easing the pressures on our
domestic financial markets.
But now we have to begin working back toward a more
sustainable balance —

the sooner the better.

There are clear responsibilities for other countries
in that effort.

Japan, for instance, is broadly in the opposite

position from the United States.

It generates a high level of

net savings, roughly twice our own level relative to GNP.
Those savings are not fully utilized at home.

It exports huge

amounts of capital, and with it a huge amount of manufactured
goods, far more than it imports.
No doubt it can and must do more to open its markets,
to the ultimate benefit of its own consumers.

But that will not

alone be enough to make really rapid progress toward closing its




-16$40 billion current account surplus? it will also need to generate
more "home grown" expansion, instead of relying so much on exports
to generate growth.
Meanwhile, Europe has been mired in historically high
levels of unemployment, despite a generally improved trade
performance*
prescriptions.

I am in no position to offer detailed policy
Moreover, there are some encouraging signs that

we can look forward to a little faster domestic expansion in
both Japan and Europe.

But clearly, much remains to be done,

in the words of the Summit communique, "unremittingly to
pursue .

. policies conducive to sustained growth and

higher employment."
There is another area that needs attention as part of a
growing world economy.

The imbalances in growth and trade

among the industrialized countries have been accompanied by
large changes in exchange rates.

Indeed, those changes

—

marked by an extremely strong dollar and relative weakness of
the yen and especially European currencies —




have been the

-17mechanism inducing, in large part, the shifts in trade.
There has been a great and understandable reluctance by most
countries to intervene strongly in the exchange markets.

And

I think there is a wide area of agreement that such intervention,
standing alone, could hardly be successful in achieving
greater stability if more fundamental policy imbalances are
not corrected.

But the goal of greater stability is important.

The kind of extreme volatilty we have seen —
when measured over periods of months or years —
acceptable.

Patterns of trade are distorted.

particularly

is hardly
The laws of

comparative advantage that underly our theorizing about free
trade are, in a practical sense, undermined when price incentives
can change so radically without equivalent changes in underlying
economic circumstances.
That instability is a signal that some thing is askew.
But there is no point in railing about it without facing up
to the source of that instability -- that would fall into the
category of shooting the messenger.




-18We nave made a lot of progress, not just in the United
States but elsewhere in the industrial world, in bringing
inflation down*

The job isn't done.

inflation under better control.

But we collectively have

Inflation rates among industrial-

ized countries more nearly converge than at any other time since
the dollar was floated in 1973.
In concept, that should, in itself, contribute to more
stable exchange rates.

But of course other imbalances remain,

including our budgetary difficulties which help to keep
inflationary expectations alive.

There are, as I noted,

differences in economic growth rates and prospects.
As we deal with those problems, exchange rates should
reflect more reasonably underlying economic circumstances.
not, it seems to me the inference to be drawn is clear.

If

The

governments of the world will have to give more attention to
the requirements for greater stability, lest fluctuations in
exchange rates undermine the very goals of the liberal trading
order we want to support.




Finally —

in terms of the order of my remarks today

but not in the sense of the intrinsic importance of the subject

—

we will have to more fully recognize the problems and potential
of the developing countries if trade is truly to promote our
common prosperity and contribute to political stability.
As you knowf a number of developing countries —
those expanding the most rapidly —

basically

became large borrowers in

international markets during the 1970's and early 1980's.
Major commercial banks around the world were eager lenders in
a context of rapid growth, relatively low interest rates, and
accelerating inflation.

But when conditions changed —

in terms

of better control over inflation, higher interest rates, and
more sluggish growth —
selves vulnerable.

both borrowers and lenders found them-

The international financial system and

the trade it supports were in jeopardy.
The response to crisis was heartening.

A number of major

borrowing countries undertook strong measures to adjust their
external accounts* including measures to deal forcibly with




-20™

tLhei£ budget deficits and to curtail monetary growth.

They cut

back on swollen imports, and because the crisis centered in
Latin America where we have particularly close trading relationships, the effect on our own exports for awhile was disproportionate,
Banks, recognizing their self-interest in an orderly resolution
of the problem, joined cooperatively in providing limited amounts
of new money when needed as part of the adjustment effort and in
restructuring old loans so they could be serviced.
At the center of the entire process stood the International
Monetary Fund.

It has worked with the indebted countries to develop

needed adjustment programs.

It has helped coordinate the banks

in developing their lending programs.

It has provided an

essential margin of the needed new funds.
The Fund could play that role for one reason —

as an

international organization with membership of nearly all
countries, it could be accepted as a neutral arbiter.
had professional competence.

And it had funds at its disposal

to help carry out its purposes*




it also

— 21 —

The challenge remains.

The debt problem is still with

u s , and it will have to be resolved ultimately in the context

of growth.

Success will require continuing self-discipline by the

borrowing countries*

More than that, they will have to make

their economies more competitive, efficient, and flexible.

In

many cases, that will require steps to liberalize, in the old

fashioned sense of the word, their own economies, making them

more attractive for investment by their own citizens as well

as by firms from abroad.

And, the borrowing countries, as they do produce at

competitive prices, will need open and growing markets abroad.

That need be no threat to the industrialized world.

The

indebted countries have, and will continue to have, large import

needs.

Those needs that can be satisfied only by countries like

the United States.

Of course, we can expect competition.

But their growth,

and our growth, will ultimately be spurred by fair competition.




~22~
Rising trade need not mean one-sided trade —

and all sides can

benefit.,
I can3t go deeply today into the problems of the developing
world and their solutions*

But I would submit to you that we have

had in the past few years a vivid demonstration of the central
importance of strong international institutions in managing the
world economy.

The IMF was there, fortunately for all of us, to

help deal with crisis*

The World Bank, the interAmerican Develop-

ment Bank, and the Asian Development Bank •— institutions whose
business is long-term development —
constructively.

have also contributed

Their role will be even more important as the

borrowing countries begin to deal with the need for more
fundamental restructuring of their economies.
No doubt, as with any human institution, the international
financial organizations will need to adapt and change in response
to shifting circumstances.

But my point is a simple one.

hard to visualize an effective trading system —
which all can participate and grow —




It f s

a system in

without organizations like

-23these to help protect the financial structure and support
development.
enforcing —

They provide a forum for developing —
the rules of the game.

and

They provide needed financial

lubricants, even if the driving engine of the world economy must
be found in the performance of individual countries.

They are

a force for cohesion and consensus.
And they will not be able to operate effectively without the
support and encouragement of their leading stockholder, the
United States.
The burden of my remarks can be summarized in a few
sentences.
If we are interested in the prosperity of the United
States -- as we must be —

we are going to have to find that

prosperity in a larger world order.

In this day of instantaneous

communication, relatively cheap transportation, and constant
travel, we are not going to be satisfied to live in isolation.
We need world markets in which to sell —




and in which to buy.

-24That means we have to opt for open trade*

That trade

will have to be supported by generally accepted rules of the
road, perceived to be fair and reasonable by all participating
countries.
All countries that participate in the system will need
to deal with imbalances in their own national policies.

We

can't expect to pass our internal problems off on others.
In the process, the success of one country will help its trading
partners.

And the responsibilities of the United States today,

as the largest and strongest country, are especially great.
If we are to be less dependent on foreign capital, this
country will have to face up to the need to deal with its budget
deficit.

That measure -- thought of as a purely domestic

economic and political matter —

has great implications for our

trade, for financial markets, and for other countries as well.
All countries have a strong interest in nurturing and
supporting the international institutions —
and the development banks*




the GATT, the IMF,

Those institutions, created by

-25imaginative men in the aftermath of the most destructive war
in history, reflect and incorporate our common interest and our
common vision of a liberal world trading order in which all can
prosper -— and stay at peace.
I don't think it stretches the facts to claim that all of
this is part of a kind of intellectual consensus among thoughtful
people, here and elsewhere.

It is certainly part of our common

rhetoric.
But f of course, we need more than rhetoric.
practical measures to implement that consensus.
it will be shattered —

We need

Otherwisef

shattered by the exigencies of the

economic and political pressures.
Our trade J^s way out of balance.
complaints.

Exchange rates are too volatile.

around the world Jjs

to

° high*

Unemployment

The international institutions

have no strong domestic constituency.




There are legitimate

-26You are meeting at a timely hour.
ambitious —

as it should be.

Your agenda is

None of us can do it full justice,

in all its detail and implications.
But the fact you have taken this initiative at all is
what strikes me as important.

For out of this kind of debate

and discussion we can help build the intellectual foundation
for policies that can support both peace and prosperity.

And

we can begin to move from intellectual consensus to constructive
action.




* * * * * * * * * *