View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

~

sbl

Speech delivered before
Washington Rotary Club
Mayflower Hotel, Washington, D. C.
August 20, 1947

RUHR COAL, GERMANY, AND EUROPE

VJhen I came back from Germany, about 3-1/2 months ago, I felt that
the American public needed to be more fully informed of the crucial role
to be played by the German economy in the reconstruction of Europe. In
the meantime, the German question has become the center of attention.
At present, Anglo-American discussions are taking place on the subject
of German coal mining, and another conference, with the participation of
French delegates, is going to tackle the over-all problem of the level oi
German industry. Thus the need for emphasizing the urgency of these subjects has lessened, but it still may be helpful to point out the essential questions involved in those discussions.
The main bottleneck of European rehabilitation is the scarcity of
coal, caused mainly by the decline in British and in German coal production. In the Ruhr, where the most important German coal mines are located, daily output averaged some 4-30^00 metric tons before the war. I:.
1946, it stayed at less than 200,000 tons until late in the fall when an
increase in food rations for miners raised it gradually to 238,000 tons
in March 1947. Unfortunately, at that time growing unrest appeared in
the Ruhr. The food situation deteriorated because of the unprecedented
severity of the winter of 1946-47 that hampered transportation and production in all of Europe, and the uncertainties of international political developments made the outlook even more gloomy. Output dropped to
on average of 212,000 tons. Only in recent weeks did production again
approach the March figures, after the food situation had improved because of increased imports from the U. S. and after added incentives in
the form of other consumer goods had been promised to the miners.
What did the drop in coal output mean to Germany? The four occupying powers, in the level-of-industry plan adopted in the spring of 1946,
agreed that German steel production, which is the basis of Germany's
heavy industry, was to be limited to 5.8 million metric tons annually, a
figure corresponding to the depression level of 1932. Actually because
of the lack of coal the Ruhr district, to which the great bulk of total
German steel production was allocated, did not even produce half of the
permitted amount. As the result of the lack of steel, heavy industrial
production in the combined US-JK zones of Germany also has remained, well
below the limits of the l e v e l - o f - i n d u s t r y plan. Moreover, the production
of building materials (cement), urgently needed for rebuilding the shattered German cities, and of textiles (artificial fibers) also was decisively affected by the lack of coal. Total industrial production in
the combined US-UK zones stood at 39 per cent of 1936 in May and June
1947, the best months of the period of occupation, as against a planned
level of 55-60 per cent. In the field of agriculture, domestic production has declined to about 60 per cent of prewar. This decline is due
largely to the lack of artificial fertilizer, and this in turn, to the
lack of coal.
The scarcity of consumer goods leads to a vicious circle; the minerr

62

won't produce more coal if they don't receive more food, better housing
facilities, more clothing, and other consumer goods. In order to improve
food production, housing conditions and the supply of other consumer goods*
however, more coal must be mined.
We might say that this dilemma is the consequence of German aggression, and that it is historic justice that the German people suffer.
But what are the consequences for the victims of German aggression? German coal always has been essential for the industries of most Central
and Western European nations. The Ruhr alone used to export more than
30 million tons of coal per year. In 1946, for reasons of justice and
diplomacy v/e forced the export of coal at the expense of German consumption. Even so, we were unable to export more than 11 million tons—less
than one-third of prewar. And this smaller quantity had to be sufficient
for countries which suffered from a decline in their own coal production
and in British coal exports. Thus the lack of coal also prevented the
French, Belgian, Netherlands, Italian, and Austrian industries from utilizing their full productive capacities. In the winter of 1946-4.7, the
catastrophic situation of the German economy compelled us to curtail coal
exports far below the level reached in previous months so that in February 3947, exports dropped below half of the 1946 average, and in the
first five months of 1947 had reached an annual rate of only 8 million
tons, less than one-fourth of the prewar level. This decline in Ruhr
coal exports was one of the most important reasons for the deterioration
in the European economic situation in the spring of 1947.
The drop in coal exports is not the only adverse effect of the lag
in German coal production. Equally disastrous for Europe is the lack of
exports of German industrial products. Before the war, the German industry was the source of supply for the great bulk of European machinery
and precision instruments. For instance, half of the Netherlands industry is equipped with German machine tools. Some European countries had
hoped that the limitations imposed upon German industry would enable
them to capture German markets. But in many of these countries, the domestic industry cannot make use of that opportunity because it cannot
work efficiently without German equipment and especially without German
spare parts. Thus some countries, like the Low Countries, the Scandinavian countries, and Austria that would have most reason to see German
heavy industry condemned to perpetual stagnation, today are among those
that ask most loudly for the revival of German heavy industry which has
to furnish them with urgently needed parts.
Finally, the lack of German coal production has made it necessary
for the US and UK governments to come to the help of the German people in
order to avoid wholesale starvation, disease, and unrest. Since Germany,
largely because of the lack of coal, cannot produce the food and other
subsistence goods which the German people need for survival, these commodities must be imported from the UK although other European countries,
many of them our allies during the last war, also are in great need of
these goods, and although such exports are a tremendous burden upon the
UK and in a lesser degree a burden upon our own economy. To a certain extent, the present exchange difficulties of the British people are due to
the exports to Germany. Moreover, these exports must be financed temporarily at least out of budgetary receipts, which means out of the taxes
paid by the British and American public. We don't consider them to be

gifts to the German people, and we hope to be repaid in future years.
For the time being, however, the economic effect of these expenditures is
not much different from that of unilateral contributions.
Thus the problem of increasing the coal production of the Ruhr is of
the greatest interest not only to the Germans, but also to all European
countries end to the British and American taxpayer. In fact, it is one
of the few points on which all nations of the world are in complete agreement. The question is only, how increased production should be attained.
The experiences in the fall of 1946 and the summer of 1947 have shown
that an increase in goods made available to the miners, especially food,
housing and other consumer goods, will bring about an increase in output.
But such supplies have either to be taken away from the rest of the German people, whose meager rations do not leave room for such measures, or
a
ga.in, have to be financed by the occupation powers. The British obviously are unable to take over additional burdens, and so the expense of
such an incentive program would have to be borne by the U. S. The cost
certainly would be worthwhile, even in terms of dollars, since eveiy increase in coal production lessens the strain on our own economy by the
demands of other European nations for relief grants or credits with which
to purchase our own scarce coal. However, it is hardly possible for us
to pay for such a program without having a controlling influence upon
its execution. The Ruhr is in the British zone, and British ideas of
management and ownership are sometimes somewhat different from our own.
It is incorrect to say that the British are bent on socializing the Ruhr
mines, or to say that we are absolutely opposed to socialization, but it
is true that there are some differences of opinion. The first question
is whether or not we can expect the mines to be better managed by the occupation authorities or by the Germans themselves. Everybody acquainted
with military government procedures will agree that German management
would be more efficient. Then the question arises, who should do the
managing. The old masters of the Ruhr coal cartel were among the major
German war criminals, and we cannot think of restoring the crucial European industry to their control. Such a step would not only produce the
danger of outright sabotage of our efforts toward European cooperation,
but also arouse our most faithful friends in Western Europe against us.
But where to find German managers nob tainted by too close collaboration
with the old Nazi gang? The British argue that only socialization can
solve that dilemma, while we point out, first, that the Germans themselve?
a
*'e not too happy about that idea—the German bizonal economic council,
elected by the legislatures of the German states, just has appointed a
strictly anti-socialist directorate—and, secondly, that the inexperienced German democratic burocracy would be even less efficient than the
experienced British administration. The present discussions certainly
will lead to some compromise, but only the future can tell whether it
will be practicable.
Another problem is, what to do with the increased coal output once
it is mined. We cannot expect production to increase so much that the
domestic as well as the export demand will be fully satisfied. A few
days ago, the German bizonal economic council submitted an economic plan
for 19/f7-/v8, based upon the production of 70 million tons of hard coal as
against
million in 1946-47. At the present rate of output, this figure appears reasonable. The council, however, wishes to cut exports substantially below the 1946 level, and to devote not only a larger part of

61;

the present output but also the entire increase to German consumption.
This is understandable because the needs of the German economy are closer
to the heart of the German people and its representatives than the need of
the rest of Europe; moreover, it can be argued that German miners will be
spurred by the knowledge that all increases will accrue to the German
economy. But such a solution obviously would not be acceptable to Germany's neighbors that need German coal as urgently as Germany itself. In
contrast, the coal distribution plan agreed between the US-UK zonal authorities and the French .in the spring of 1947 would allocate to exports
the present quota plus about one-fifth of the increase in output. Obviously, the French will not agree to the execution of the coal program to^
be turned over to German authorities, unless they are satisfied that their
import requirements will receive due consideration.
Once the question of allocating coal is solved, the problem remains
what to do with the coal reserved to the Gorman economy. The German council proposes to allocate only 10 per cent of the German quota to household
consumption despite the hardship which such a small allocation is bound to
cause. The resumption of German .industrial production is indeed more important than the comfort of the German population—although too much discomfort may force the population to spend a disproportionate amount of
time on the search for other fuel (woodcutting) and induce pilferage and
black market operations. Still, the problem remains whether to use the
remaining 90 per cent of the German quota mainly for the production of export goods, or for the production of goods destined to German consumption.
The diversion of too much coal to production for the German market will
leave the needs of the victims of Germany unsatisfied—and indirectly
force us to grant further aid to those victims—while a diversion of too
much coal to the production of export goods will hurt German labor morale
and efficiency, and in addition make necessaiy further relief imports into
Germany, thus again in the last resort burdening the U. S. economy.
So you see how closely related the coal problem is with that of the
level of the German industry, and with our own contributions to the recovery of Europe. We can only hope that the participants in the conferences will contribute to the solution of the over-all European problem
by keeping in mind the broad implications of their decisions. Their main
goal should be not just an increase of so much per cent in the production
index of such or such country, but the reintegration of the entire Europe^
economy. That alone will bring about not only economic progress but also,
more importantly, the prospects of permanent peace.

j