View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

UNIVERSITY OF MISSOURI-ST. LOUIS
St. Louis, Missouri
January 24, 1997

.....................................................................

Money and Banking in the 21st Century
We’re here to discuss money and central banking in the 21st centur y. That’s not an easy assignment.
Anytime you look into the future, your v ision can be blurred. For example, Popular Mechanics predicted in 1949 that “Computers in the future may weigh no more than 1.5 tons”
They’re not alone in making less-than-accurate predictions. In Chicago we’re still smarting from the
prediction that Er nie Broglio would help the Cubs win the pennant and that Lou Brock was just another ball player.
Nevertheless, we’re here today to address the question: “Will the Federal Reser ve System, designed in
the early 1900s, still be effective and relevant in the 21st centur y?” To me, this isn’t a tough call. It
shouldn’t surprise anyone here, but I feel safe in predicting that the answer is “yes”
To support my answer, I’d like to discuss how the Fed’s decentralized, regional structure helps us formulate effective, long-ter m monetar y policy. To do this, I’ll start by giv ing a brief historical over v iew
of the Federal Reser ve. Then I’d like to prov ide a specific example of some regional analysis that’s taking place at the Chicago Fed.

Fed Structure
The Fed System was set up by Congress in 1913. It’s been a unique organization from the beginning
because of its mix of the public and the private, the centralized and the decentralized.
The United States tried two previous experiments in central banking—both failed. The first bank lasted
from 1791 to 1811; the second from 1816 to 1836. Each bank closed after its 20-year charter expired …

158

Michael Moskow Speeches

1997

largely because of a basic American distrust of concentrated power, especially money power. We then
faced a 77-year period with no central bank. Most other industrialized nations had central banks; we
were behind the times.
By the early 1900s, it became clear that the U.S. needed a central bank. The crucial question was how
to structure it. Some favored a centralized institution with a strong private-sector orientation. Others
preferred a regional structure dominated by the gover nment.
The organization that resulted was a compromise. The Fed was created with an intricately structured
balance between the public and the private, the central and the decentralized. It’s a balance that still
exists. The 12 regional Reser ve Banks throughout the countr y have a mix of public and private features.
The Banks are overseen by a gover ning board in Washington, D.C., which consists of seven officials
appointed by the President and approved by the Senate. It’s interesting to note that European Union
central banks are tr ying to establish a structure and a process we’ve been fine-tuning for decades.
The Fed’s regional, decentralized structure helps to insulate it from day-to-day political pressures. To
this end, Congress prov ided staggered, 14-year terms for the seven members of the Board of Gover nors.
Reser ve Bank presidents are appointed by the board of directors of each Fed Bank, with the approval of
the Board of Gover nors in Washington. We also don’t depend on the appropriations process to meet our
expenses. I should add, though, that Congress does rev iew our budget. And the vast majority of our
ear nings is tur ned over to the U.S. Treasur y. Out ability to fund our own operations is a public trust
… it’s a responsibility we take ver y seriously. The Federal Reser ve is insulated from short-ter m political pressures, but we’re ultimately accountable to Congress and the American people. This delicate
balance is sometimes referred to as being “independent within gover nment” We’re tied to gover nment,
but we’re also insulated from it.
Why do we need this insulation? It can be difficult for an elected representative to “ resist the temptation to gun the economy periodically. That’s the conclusion of many students of central banking,
including Congress. Nobody’s more aware of short-ter m political pressures than those who experience
it ever y day. This is nothing new—back in 1830 the House Ways and Means Committee expressed its
reluctance to have the gover nment directly involved in issuing money, stating, (quote) “…the temptation to supply the Federal Treasur y by the easy process of bank issues, rather than resorting to the
unpopular process of inter nal taxation, would be too fascinating to resist.”

Federal Open Market Committee
The Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC, is the most intricate example of the Fed’s checks and
balances. It’s the Fed’s most important policymaking body, which decides the course of monetar y policy. The FOMC meetings combine the seven members of the Board of Gover nors and the 12 Reser ve
Bank presidents, five of whom vote on a rotating basis. It’s admittedly a complex system—but it works.
At the FOMC meetings, decisions are usually made by consensus, and there’s rarely a close vote.
Regional input is crucial. We get grass-roots, up-to-the minute infor mation that we’re able to glean
from a variety of regional sources. This helps us understand the stor y behind the numbers.

Michael Moskow Speeches

1997

159

The board of directors at each Federal Reser ve Bank and Branch play a key role in the infor mationgathering process. The boards consist of leading private citizens representing a number of economic
sectors and interests such as banking, industr y, retail, labor, and agriculture. They prov ide us with a
first-hand view of the latest developments in the economy.
Importantly, the Reser ve Banks add a regional perspective and a broad range of ideas to the policy
process. The Bank presidents ensure a constant flow of input from beyond the Washington “beltway.”
So our regional structure not only insulates us from narrow influences, it also helps us obtain a broad
range of infor mation and ideas from people liv ing and working throughout the countr y.

Midwest Study
So far I’ve talked in general ter ms about the advantages of a regional structure. Now I’d like to give a
specific example of a project that helps to illustrate these advantages. Specifically, I’d like to talk about
a long-ter m, Chicago Fed project to study the renaissance of the Midwest economy. The study focuses
on the Seventh District states of Illinois, Indiana, Wisconsin, Michigan, and Iowa. But I think it raises
issues that are of interest to people in the Midwest more broadly defined.
As you know, it wasn’t that many years ago that the Midwest was commonly referred to as the rustbelt.
And you couldn’t find many people predicting that good times were ahead. The Midwest bottomed out
during the early 1980s. It received a wake-up call; it just wasn’t competitive.
There’s been a dramatic tur naround since then. The Midwest has been outperfor ming the rest of the
nation in recent years. One indication is that unemployment rates in Seventh District states have been
below the national average by about one percent. Back in 1982, unemployment rates for the Midwest
were three percentage points above the national average.
So the region’s done well. The big question is why? And how do we sustain the comeback? It’s important to look at public policy options that will help the region prosper in the future. As a regional institution, the Chicago Fed is uniquely positioned to study the Midwest and communicate infor mation to
policymakers. And through these efforts, infor mation flows back to us — and helps us do a better job
in contributing to national monetar y policy. We’ve obtained a better understanding of the Midwest
economy—how it’s likely to develop and how the region may be affected by specific factors such as
NAFTA or new welfare legislation.
During the past year, we’ve held six workshops focusing on a wide range of topics, We’ve looked at global
linkages to the Midwest economy; the labor force and education policy; the rural economy; tax and
regulator y policies; the perfor mance of metropolitan areas; and changes in the manufacturing sector.
We’re also working with an adv isor y group, which includes the gover nors of the five Seventh District
states as honorar y members. Each of the gover nors has a representative on the group. The group also
includes six university presidents as well as representatives from business, labor, and not-for-profit
organizations.
We’ll be issuing a report in April. Then we’ll begin a major effort to distribute the findings of the study
to policymakers and community and business leaders.

160

Michael Moskow Speeches

1997

Study results
I’d like to take a few minutes to give you a flavor of what we’re finding. A number of interesting issues
have emerged.
One thing that’s ver y clear is the Midwest’s transfor mation from over-the-hill to the king of the hill …
from rustbelt to robust. The old image of a gutted-out region overflowing with obsolete manufacturing
plants is a thing of the past.
We did go through some tough times. For example, the Midwest lost three percentage points of its share
of national manufacturing employment from 1977 to 1983, But since 1983, we’ve gained two percentage points of national manufacturing employment. And we’ve seen major manufacturing industries,
such as steel and autos, reconcentrate in the Midwest.
The other mainstay of the Midwest economy is agriculture. Here we’ve seen increased output, primarily
due to exports. And, surprisingly, we’ve also seen an increase in manufacturing employment in rural areas.
The stronger economy has attracted people. The Midwest’s old image included a mass migration to
war mer, more successful states. But again, the facts belie the image, In fact, tight labor markets in
recent years have led to an inflow of people to the region. This trend has been most pronounced in rural
areas. Froin 1980 to 1990, the population in rural counties declined by 2.2 percent. But since 1990, the
population has increased and wiped out those losses.
We’ve seen an increase in population in metropolitan areas too. Many of these areas losses, have undergone an economic transformation. The Chicagoland area, for example, has transformed from a manufacturing center to a service center, specializing in business services, trade, travel, and financial services.
Why did all this happen? We’re all aware of some external factors that have benefitted the Midwest …
declining energy prices; the stronger dollar; and cuts in defense spending. That last trend helped the
Midwest because defense spending historically has been concentrated on the East and West coasts.
But these exter nal factors don’t completely explain the turnaround in the Midwest. The key to the
Midwest’s success, I believe, is that the region’s industries have changed how they conduct their businesses. The Midwest has not dramatically changed its lines of business. It continues to be more concentrated than the nation in its mainstay industries — durable manufacturing and agriculture.
So, the Midwest is doing the same thing — it’s just doing it better. The region has changed the way it
does business — its organization; mode of operation; and use of technology. The region has been a
leader in implementing best manufacturing practices, such as lcan manufacturing. Each industr y has
found ways to be competitive.
A study by Chicago Fed economists highlights the competitiveness of the Midwest economy. According to
common wisdom, the Midwest benefitted quite a bit from the declining dollar, which made its exports cheaper for overseas buyers. This is a logical conclusion, given the results of studies that have looked at the value
of the dollar and the nation’s major trading partners. Our economists took a different approach—a regional
approach—and looked at the value of the dollar and it’s effect on the Midwest’s major trading partners. They

Michael Moskow Speeches

1997

161

found that the dollar did not decline in those countries. In other words, the Midwest did not have a built-in
price advantage. It appears that the Midwest succeeded because of better products and prices, not just
because of external factors such as the performance of the dollar.
That’s just a brief indication of what we’re finding in the study. It’s been a very useful process for the
Chicago Fed because it’s enhanced our understanding of the regional economy…It’s encouraged us to take
a more innovative approach in our analysis and helped us obtain a better understanding, of the numbers.
I hope our study also will be a useful tool for Midwest policymakers. The Midwest has rebounded… but
that’s no guarantee for the future. The region doesn’t have an abundance of natural advantages. And we
don’t see any exter nal trends that will sustain the region. The Midwest needs to look at policies that
can keep prosperity going. Our goal is to be a catalyst for the development of effective regional policy…
policy that will contribute to a healthy,,growing economy.

Conclusion
To sum up, the Fed’s regional system offers a number of important advantages. Certainly, the Fed needs to
respond to a changing environment, and we are doing that, as indicated by colleagues’ comments.
It’s important to keep in mind, though, that our regional system facilitates the development of effective, longterm policy. It provides insulation from day-to-day political pressures. It helps us keep track of the very latest developments in the economy, before they show up in the numbers. And it encourages a flow of ideas and
in ut from “beyond the beltway.” It’s a system that’s worked well for many years, and, I predict, will continue
to do so in the 21st century.

162

Michael Moskow Speeches

1997