View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At the First EU/U.S. Retail Banking Forum Conference, Brussels, Belgium
November 15, 2005
Perspectives on the Development of a Unified National Payments System in the United
States
Introduction
Good morning. I would like to thank the World Savings Banks Institute, as well as the
European Savings Banks Group, for the invitation to address this distinguished audience. I
appreciate the opportunity to share some thoughts on the development of a unified national
payments system in the United States. I am looking forward to Ms. Tumpel-Gugerell's
remarks on the euro system's perspective, and I anticipate a lively panel discussion will
follow.
The European Union and the United States have had very different experiences with the
origin and evolution of their payments systems. There is a great deal to learn by studying
both systems and their ongoing changes. This morning, I would like to discuss the
development of a unified national payments system, or single payments area, in the United
States. I will sketch the foundations of the contemporary U.S. payments system and remark
on the history of U.S. banking. I think you will recognize some parallels with, but also
important differences from, the European Union experience. I will then discuss some of the
challenges in the U.S. experience, as well as some thoughts on the future of the U.S.
payments system. The overarching theme of my remarks is that the United States has
evolved toward an increasingly unified national payments system, through both marketdriven development and some specific public-sector actions.
A Brief History of the U.S. Banking and Payments System
From the late 1700s through the mid-1800s, the development of the U.S. banking system was
dominated by roles played by individual states. Generally, commercial banks were not
chartered by the federal government; rather, they were chartered, regulated, and supervised
by the states and operated under different state legal and regulatory frameworks. The
explicit delegation of bank supervision to the states reflected the strong preference for
decentralized authority and resulted in the first brief efforts to establish a national bank. In
1791, the federal government chartered the First Bank of the United States with a
twenty-year charter, its first attempt to establish a central bank. After that charter lapsed in
1811, the federal government in 1816 made a second attempt to form a central bank, by
establishing the Second Bank of the United States. That twenty-year charter was also
allowed to lapse amid the economic and political controversies of that time.
In ensuing years, the banking system was highly decentralized with individual statechartered commercial banks issuing their own bank notes. Although there has been an
academic debate about the success of this period of competitive, private-bank note issuance,
the federal government ultimately acted to address significant problems posed by this
banking structure. In the payments system, for example, state bank notes were subject to
devaluation in response to credit risk and to counterfeiting, creating a significant burden on

local and interstate commerce. In 1863 and 1865, the National Bank Acts permitted the
federal government to charter national banks and allowed these banks to issue national bank
notes backed by federal bonds. The collateralization of national bank notes with U.S.
government bonds, along with a 10 percent tax on state notes, expedited the acceptance of
national bank notes and quickly eliminated state notes from circulation. In addition, the
United States Treasury also began directly issuing notes backed by gold in the 1870s. These
developments were important first steps in unifying the national payments system.
In retrospect, the overall fragmentation of the U.S. banking system helped produce a
fragmented national retail payments system, including a fragmented check-clearing system.
Checks, which were traditionally cleared through local private clearing houses or
correspondent banks, were the predominant alternative to making payments with bank notes
or gold. However, checks were not paid at par. That is, checks cleared between banks in
different states or locales were discounted based on the costs of transportation needed to
collect the checks, the risk profiles of the banks on which the checks were drawn, and the
need to earn a return on clearing activities. Neither the consumer nor the merchant knew
how much of the value of a check would ultimately be delivered to the intended beneficiary,
so it was difficult to determine the value of a check needed to pay a bill. As the level of
interstate commerce grew, the costs associated with this inefficient practice became quite
burdensome. Also, collecting a check could take a long time. Because a check could be
forwarded to numerous correspondent banks before ultimately being presented for payment,
some public officials charged that banks deliberately engaged in the “circuitous routing” of
checks to exploit the inefficiencies of the payments system.
The risks and inefficiencies in the fragmented banking system also resulted in bank panics,
which were relatively common, and made it difficult to transfer liquidity from one region of
the country to another. In 1913, the U.S. Congress established the Federal Reserve System,
not only to provide greater financial stability and to improve banking supervision, but also to
provide an elastic currency and a national check-clearing system. The Federal Reserve
began issuing currency in 1914. Moreover, checks that were cleared through the Federal
Reserve and that were drawn on Federal Reserve member banks were exchanged at par
value.
In the early days, the Federal Reserve's national check-clearing service was provided free of
charge to nationally chartered banks that were required to join the system and statechartered banks that joined voluntarily. Despite some early difficulties with achieving
widespread par clearing, the Federal Reserve's check collection services ultimately provided
the nation with a much more unified payments system.
During this period, checks or drafts were also used as a means of settling interbank payment
obligations. To improve the safety and efficiency of the interbank settlement process, in
1918 the Federal Reserve developed and implemented Fedwire, the first real-time gross
settlement system. The key feature of the Fedwire system was the ability to transfer account
balances held at the central bank through telegraphic messages using a secure
communications network. Although Fedwire was intended to improve the large-value
payment system, and quickly accomplished that goal, it was also used for some urgent
large-value commercial and retail payments, and continues to be used that way today.
The payments operations of state and federally chartered private banks, private clearing
houses, and the operations of the new central bank, provided the foundation for the privateand public-sector payments infrastructure that exists in the United States today. Yet for

many years, policies that deterred interstate banking shaped the design and operation of the
retail payments system. The U.S. banking and payments system has also been shaped by
other important state and federal laws. Starting in the late 1800s, states attempted to develop
a more-uniform set of commercial laws codifying existing laws and common business
practices. They eventually adopted the Uniform Commercial Code, or UCC, which states
generally enacted. At the federal level, a number of laws influenced the development of the
banking system.
Laws such as the McFadden Act and the Douglas Amendment to the Bank Holding
Company Act were passed to restrict either bank ownership or bank branching across state
lines. Over the years, legislation enacted by the various states, and ultimately at the federal
level, eliminated the barriers to banks operating across state lines, at least with respect to
interstate bank acquisitions. In 1994, the Riegle-Neal Act, which repealed most of the
federal prohibitions on interstate banking, set the foundation for establishing efficient,
national retail banking and payment arrangements.
If the U.S. banking structure is the foundation of the retail payments system, the cornerstone
is the competitive market model for payment system operators. The Monetary Control Act
of 1980, or MCA, codified the use of the competitive market model for the U.S. payments
system with the central bank as a provider of services. Prior to that Act, only Federal
Reserve member banks were permitted to use the Federal Reserve's (free) payment services.
Nonmembers typically cleared checks through a network of upstream correspondent banks
that were Federal Reserve members. The MCA confirmed the Federal Reserve's role as a
key provider of services and required the Federal Reserve to provide payment services to
both member and nonmember banks. Most importantly, the MCA required the Federal
Reserve to price its payment services and to fully recover the costs of providing those
services, including imputed taxes and profits. The purpose of this requirement was to avoid
having the central bank underprice payment services in a way that would undercut the
existence and growth of private-sector alternatives. The ultimate goal was to stimulate
efficiency and innovation by encouraging competition between service providers and
payment system operators, including the central bank.
The legal framework governing payment systems has continued to evolve. In its role as
catalyst for payments system improvements, the Federal Reserve has worked with the
private sector to identify and address barriers to improvements in payments system
efficiency. It then developed legislative recommendations that eventually became the Check
Clearing for the 21st Century Act, known as Check 21. Check 21, which became effective
in 2004, eliminated legal impediments to the use of electronic technologies to collect checks.
Under Check 21, banks no longer need to physically move original paper checks from the
bank where the checks are deposited to the bank that pays them. The law created a new
negotiable instrument called a substitute check, which permitted banks to truncate original
checks, to send digital check images across the country, and to deliver paper substitute
checks to banks that wanted to continue receiving paper checks. As a result, checks will
ultimately be collected faster and at lower cost through an electronic national clearing
structure.
Consumer Behavior and Market Response in the Future U.S. Payments System
The development and adoption of new payments instruments is largely being influenced by
consumers, merchants, and their banks and service providers interacting in a market setting.
Until very recently, checks have been the dominant form of noncash payment in the U.S.
payments system as measured by the annual number of payments. However, the 1990s saw

a marked shift in consumers' behavior. Federal Reserve research has revealed a steady
decline in check usage since the mid-1990s. By 2003, electronic noncash retail payments
exceeded check payments for the first time.
Debit cards, used primarily by consumers for everyday purchases, have represented the
fastest growing segment of the retail payments system. They have been a natural bridge from
cash and checks to electronics. Historically, automated teller machine and debit card
networks, much like the early check-clearing network in the U.S., were generally regionally
based. Banks issued debit cards that could be used only on certain networks, which had
limited reach across state lines. This meant that, although early debit cards were a
convenient new way to make noncash payments, the scope of their use was limited. Some
networks developed interchange agreements to expand the acceptance of their debit cards.
In addition, as debit cards evolved, the major credit card companies and their banks began to
issue a new type of debit card that operated through the existing national credit card
networks. The use of these so-called signature-based debit cards has been growing rapidly
for several years.
Another payment mechanism that was developed jointly by the private sector and the
Federal Reserve was the automated clearinghouse, or ACH, system. The ACH system is a
batch electronic payment system that has traditionally been used to process recurring credit
and debit transactions, such as payroll payments, mortgage and utility payments, and
government benefits. In its infancy, the ACH system was a segmented regional system that
has since evolved into a nationwide payments system. More recently, banks have used the
ACH system in innovative ways to make nonrecurring payments, such as payments over the
telephone or Internet, which were typically made by credit or debit card. In addition,
businesses that receive large numbers of checks from customers are obtaining their
customers' permission to convert the checks into ACH payments. As a result, the ACH has
exhibited significant growth in recent years and is contributing to the decline in the number
of payments being processed as checks.
It remains to be seen how significant an effect recently emerging instruments such as payroll
cards, stored-value cards, or electronic benefits transfer instruments will have on the
payments landscape. Whether or not these instruments are broadly accepted will depend
largely on consumer and business preferences, and on how much of an improvement these
instruments are over competing payment instruments. It is difficult to foresee how quickly
and in what forms alternative payments will evolve in the U.S. economy. It is likely,
however, that the evolution will continue to be market-driven.
In conclusion, I want to emphasize that the national payments system of the United States
has evolved through both private- and public-sector contributions. Both sectors have been
involved in technological innovation and the development of payments infrastructure. In
addition, the public sector has responded by addressing legal and other barriers that
adversely affect the banking system. Together, private and public sectors have contributed to
a more-efficient national payments system that facilitates greater commerce and innovation.
Looking forward, market needs will ultimately shape the U.S. payments system and its
direction. If the past is a guide, geography will continue to decline as an important factor in
the national payments system just as it has in other areas of economic activity.
Thank you.
Return to top

2005 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: November 15, 2005