View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Speech
Governor Mark W. Olson

At the Annual Washington Conference of the Institute of International Bankers, Washington,
D.C.
March 13, 2006

Are Banks Still Special?
Thank you for inviting me to speak to you today. Over the past twenty years, I have attended many
of these Institute of International Bankers (IIB) spring conferences in Washington, D.C., either as a
speaker or a participant. These meetings continue to address interesting and pertinent issues. The
consistently larger number of attendees at a meeting here in Washington, as opposed to a meeting in
one of the more dynamic international financial centers like New York or Los Angeles, reflects this
group's clear recognition that public policy has a direct impact on the viability of your respective
institutions. Appropriately, most of the topics presented over these two days cover legislative and
regulatory issues intermixed with critical strategic issues. For my presentation, I will revisit a topic
initially raised twenty-four years ago by a former president of the New York Federal Reserve Bank,
E. Gerald Corrigan. In 1982, Jerry Corrigan, then the president of the Minneapolis Federal Reserve
Bank, wrote an essay entitled "Are Banks Special?" for the Bank's annual report. Today I would like
to revisit the issue and ponder the question "Are Banks Still Special?"
I realize that some of you may be wondering why a focus on the specialness of the domestic U.S.
banking industry would be an appropriate topic at a meeting of foreign bank representatives. There
are several reasons why the subject is relevant to this group. First, U.S. laws and regulations for
foreign banks adhere to the fundamental principle of national treatment. That is, our regulations
allow foreign banks to have the same range of product authority as domestic banks. Therefore, any
change in policy that affects domestic banks will also potentially affect the range of products foreign
banks may offer. Another reason why the issue is likely to be of interest to this audience is that, in
any discussion of product authority or regulatory structure, the experiences of other nations are often
used as examples. These examples are often presented as policies or practices to be avoided or
emulated. But the accuracy of the facts presented to support or oppose other countries' experiences
is not always clear. At times, these "facts" may be undocumented generalities or even wild
speculation.
Let me return to Corrigan's essay. In 1982, the banking industry was facing an identity crisis unlike
any it had faced since the Depression era fifty years earlier. Within a period of a few months in the
mid-1930s, Congress (1) required the separation of banking from many securities functions by
passing the Glass-Steagall Act, (2) provided protection for bank depositors by passing the Federal
Deposit Insurance Act, and (3) authorized the creation of a dedicated home mortgage lender by
passing the Home Owners' Loan Act. Through these laws, Congress established the legal framework
that clearly delineated the competitive relationship for the securities, banking, and thrift industries
for close to fifty years. This delineation extended to the marketplace for the banking and securities
industries. During this period, there were few issues of controversy between banks and securities
firms, the most notable exception being the narrowly focused but heated disagreement as to whether
banks should be allowed to underwrite revenue bonds. The Glass-Steagall Act specifically
authorized banks to underwrite general obligation bonds, but the act was silent on the issue of
revenue bonds. The banking industry viewed that as an oversight; the securities industry viewed it
as a purposeful exclusion. This debate went unresolved until 1999, when the Gramm-Leach-Bliley
Act specifically authorized revenue bond underwriting by banks. In contrast to the relative peace
between banks and securities firms, the competition for deposits between banks and thrifts was quite

strong and intensified with the imposition of Regulation Q. Not only did Regulation Q establish
ceilings on interest rates for both passbook savings accounts and certificates of deposit (CDs), the
regulation gave thrifts an interest rate advantage of initially 50, then 25, basis points for each of their
interest-bearing products. The intense marketplace competition between banks and thrifts was
matched by the level of competition in the halls of Congress. Bankers aggressively worked to
eliminate that quarter-point rate differential, while thrifts worked equally hard to preserve it.
Such widespread competition was nonexistent between the securities and banking industries. From
the 1930s to the late 1970s, there seemed to be a clear distinction between investment and savings or
at least between investment dollars and savings dollars. Savings dollars were held in passbook
accounts or CDs, and were insured up to certain limits by Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) or Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC) insurance. Investment dollars
were in equities or bonds. Banks and thrifts waged a turf war against each other, but neither industry
aimed its marketing guns or lobbying efforts at the securities industry. Then along came money
market mutual funds, or money funds.
High interest rates during the late 1970s and early 1980s had a stunning effect on the flow of
deposits into banks and thrifts. Money fund shares issued by investment firms offered market
interest rates and a high level of liquidity, through either immediate withdrawal or the ability to
effect transactions by using payable-through drafts. By contrast, Regulation Q mandated low
interest rates on passbook accounts, specific term restrictions on CDs, and significant penalties for
early withdrawal. Money funds offered rates that were at times double the rates on passbook
accounts. The banking industry had no products to counter the market appeal. Even though money
funds shares are not federally insured, billions of dollars flowed into the accounts. In 1981 alone,
$109 billion flowed into money funds. After a tepid and wholly unsuccessful effort by bankers to
restrict the growth of money funds, the banking industry began considering a different response.
Now that the securities industry had successfully breached the separation between banking and
savings by allowing consumers to invest in money funds, the banking industry was forced to
examine its fundamental marketplace role. During that period, I was the vice chairman, then the
chairman, of the Governmental Relations Committee of the American Bankers Association. At
meetings held between 1980 and 1982, as many as 400 bankers representing institutions of all sizes
and markets gathered to consider an industry response. Congress's response to the growth of money
funds was to pass the Monetary Control Act of 1980 and the Garn-St Germain Act of 1982. Taken
together, these laws, along with other provisions, eliminated many of the rate and term restrictions
on banks' and thrifts' deposit taking and allowed both types of institutions to offer products that
could match the rate and liquidity provisions of money funds. But it was clear to many bankers that
a lasting response to marketplace changes would require more than just the removal of Regulation
Q. Bankers were seeking answers to such basic questions as "What is a bank?" and "What is the
public purpose of banking?" Jerry Corrigan's essay proved to be a beacon of rationality in that
discussion.
Are Banks Special?
Corrigan identified three characteristics that made banks special:
-Banks and only banks offered transaction accounts. That is, "they incurred liabilities payable
on demand at par and are readily transferable by the owner to third parties." That transaction
account authority helped "to insure that financial disruptions do not spread." Backed also by
deposit insurance and access to the discount window, banks "reinforced public confidence that
is essential to a healthy economy."
-Corrigan's second criterion identified banks as critical backup sources of liquidity. In fact his
essay stated that "banks are the primary source of liquidity for all other classes and sizes of
institutions, both financial and nonfinancial."
-The third characteristic Corrigan identified is that banks "are the transmission belt for
monetary policy. That role combined with operating the payments mechanism permit the
highly efficient financial markets to function and effect the orderly end of day settlement."

Corrigan went on to address the question "what is a bank," a question that had been complicated by
different definitions in different laws. The Federal Deposit Insurance Act defined "bank" differently
than the Bank Holding Company Act did, a distinction that allowed commercial entities to own
FDIC-insured banks by narrowing their product offerings to meet the BHC Act test. (The
Competitive Equality Banking Act reconciled these definitions in 1987.) If banks are special,
Corrigan stated, limitations on what services and lines of business banks could offer were justified.
Further, the services of businesses that are allowed to be owners of banks should reflect in a nearly
symmetric way, the services banks are allowed to offer. Corrigan had made a remarkably prescient
observation, as the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act that would be passed seventeen years later essentially
adopted that last criterion in determining what types of corporations could own banks, and what
activities could be conducted in those corporations. Between the publication of Corrigan's essay and
passage of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, market forces, supported by either regulatory
interpretation or court challenges, continued to blur the lines between the banking, securities, and
insurance industries. As capital markets expanded, mutual funds put pressure on bank deposits. In
Europe, foreign bank successes in securities activities suggested that banks conduct these activities
in a safe and sound manner. But until 1999, there was no legislative response to these basic
marketplace changes or to the broader question of the separation of banking and commerce.
Separation of Banking and Commerce
The appropriate separation of banking and commerce is a delicate proposition that has both
historical and philosophical underpinnings. The term "separation of banking and commerce" can
mean different things, depending on the perspective of the person using the term. At the time of
Corrigan's essay--the early 1980s--the statutory authority for that separation was largely contained
in two laws: the Glass-Steagall Act, which separated commercial banking from certain investment
and securities activities, and the Bank Holding Company Act (with amendments), which narrowly
limited the activities of corporations that were allowed to own banks. When it passed in 1956, the
Bank Holding Company Act was thought to have been in response to one company's aggressive
expansion into banking activities. That company, Transamerica Insurance, had expanded into
several western states and concerns were raised about the resulting concentration of financial
resources. Therefore, the ensuing body of law on the commerce and banking issue concentrated
significantly on separating, or was inspired by desire to separate, banking from securities or banking
from insurance. From the time of Corrigan's essay until passage of Gramm-Leach-Bliley, the
banking industry had expanded substantially into both the securities and insurance agency fields,
though significant restrictions still remained.
Much of the industry's expanded securities authority was gained through the Federal Reserve's
approval of securities underwriting for banks, under Section 20 of the Glass-Steagall Act. Under the
Federal Reserve's rule, a bank subsidiary was "not engaged principally" in securities underwriting if
at first 5 percent, then 10 percent, and ultimately 25 percent of its revenue came from underwriting.
This expanded authority allowed many banking organizations, though almost exclusively large
banks, to significantly expand their domestic securities activities. These same powers were extended
to foreign banks operating in the United States.
In insurance, gains for the banking industry were largely the result of court determinations that
annuities could be underwritten and sold by banks. Court determinations also expanded national
banks' ability to market insurance products. Consequently, banks of all sizes have expanded their
involvement in insurance and annuity activities.
By 1999, banks and bank holding companies had gained significant additional product authority in
securities and insurance, areas that had been perceived to be on the other side of the banking and
commerce wall at the time Corrigan wrote his essay. A number of factors persuaded Congress that
federal action was appropriate, and the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act was passed. Congress had learned
from the securities and insurance experiences of foreign banks, both the high points and the low
points. On the one hand, institutions in some European countries had successfully broadened their
securities and insurance activities. On the other hand, there were lingering questions about whether
some Pacific rim banks were too closely linked to certain commercial enterprises in the region, thus
facilitating the Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s. However, the U.S. banking industry had also

developed improved ways to manage risk, and banking supervision had become more effective. In
addition, the improved analytical capacity offered by new technology, better coordination among
domestic and international bank supervisors, a healthy track record for U.S. banks, and the growth
of consolidated home-country supervision across the world helped U.S. banks and their affiliates to
further expand their commercial activities.
The response of Congress was essentially threefold. First, it moved the separation wall between
banking and commerce to reflect what had already occurred in the marketplace: Gramm-LeachBliley also addressed the broader question of what types of businesses could own or affiliate with
banks by allowing companies to own banking, securities, and insurance entities within a structure
known as a financial holding company. Second, Congress provided a way for banks to gain newproduct authority when the new products were determined to be financial in nature, incidental to
banking, or complimentary to existing banking authority. Third, by clearly separating the federally
insured entity--either banks or thrifts--from the newer and potentially higher-risk new-product
authorities, Gramm-Leach-Bliley reaffirmed as a matter of public policy that banks continue to be
regarded as special. But the act offers a clear acknowledgment that the separation of banking and
commerce is not a bright line but is instead a negotiated compromise--one that will continue to
move as markets change and products are refined. The guiding consideration in this compromise
will be the protection of the federal deposit insurance fund.
Are Banks Still Special?
Much has changed in the banking landscape since Corrigan wrote his essay twenty-four years ago.
Significant increases in international capital flows among bank and nonbank entities, in addition to a
broad range of specialized financial instruments mean banks can no longer be considered the only
source of transaction accounts. Except for their access to the Federal Reserve discount window,
banks are no longer the dominant provider of liquidity for other financial industries. But banks
remain the key access point to the dominant wholesale payments network, and they still provide
federally insured checking and savings deposits. With the rise of new financial services, products,
and techniques, moreover, banks have expanded their role in providing liquidity in more indirect
ways, for example, through securitization of loans and backup commitments to securitization
vehicles and other capital-markets instruments. Even when banks may not be "special" or unique
providers in a particular market, banks have proven themselves to be formidable competitors and
innovators--which only reinforces banks' importance in the proper functioning of our financial
system. In short, the public's trust and confidence in banking continue to be vital to our financial
well-being.
Banks provided considerable credit in the aftermath of the September 11 attacks, when financial
flows were slowed by operational problems. To be sure, banks were able to provide this credit in
part because of the huge injection of liquidity provided by the Federal Reserve. But that is a key role
for banks in a crisis: to obtain funds--through the discount window or from open market operations,
if necessary--and to channel them to those needing funds, based on an assessment of their
creditworthiness. Banks' access to the discount window and the payments system, as well as their
ongoing relationships with customers and their credit-evaluation skills, allow them to play this role.
During a crisis, those banks that play critical roles in the payments system are especially important.
As a result, these banks are expected to be very resilient. Though banks now have a smaller role in
transmitting monetary policy, they still help to transmit policy actions by arbitraging between the
federal funds market and other money markets.
Conclusion
A strong case can be made that banks continue to be special. And because they are special, we, as
regulators, will continue to apply high standards to companies seeking a bank charter. We must also
continue to examine and supervise banks for safety and soundness. Likewise, it appears that
Congress will take a cautious approach when determining what types of companies may own and
affiliate with banks.
But banks must also compete in the marketplace. Consequently, we can expect over time to see
adjustments in both the direct activities of banks and in the line separating banking and commerce.

History is, in some sense, about the drawing, re-evaluation, and re-drawing of lines. As a matter of
public policy, changes will trail rather than lead the marketplace, and any changes must be informed
by a careful study of both the role we want banks to play in our economy and the needs of the
marketplace.
Return to top