View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 4, 1979

A Rational Future: More Markets, Less Government
by Mark H. Willcs
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

The ancient Greeks used to foretell the future by examining the entrails o f
sheep. This technique o f forecasting, needless to say, proved wildly inaccurate, and from
our current perspective it is easy to smile at the Greeks' superstitiousness and naivete.
Nevertheless, our age, with its vast knowledge and prodigious computers, has
barely improved upon the Greeks* methods of forecasting. Predicting the future is still a
task the wise approach humbly and the prudent not at all.

As a curious man, however, I

find it tempting to imagine our society in the coining years, and as a practical man, I find
it essential to plan ahead.
I don't foresee any radical changes in the economic system of the United
States.

Instead, 1 expect the present free-market economy to evolve gradually, finding

better ways to use its strengths and remedy its weaknesses. The system of free markets
is viable enough to survive and, I believe, desirable enough to deserve to survive, because
it makes efficien t use of resources, both human and material.

Under this system,

consequently, people can have more o f what they want than they could have in a
politically controlled economy or in almost any feasible alternative economy.

If people

can control their destinies, and if they try to make the economic arrangements that can
best provide the things they value, they will most likely choose some version of a freemarket economy.
Even your best trend won't tell you. One way to envision the future—not the
most satisfactory—is to examine current trends.

Some observers believe, for instance,

that this country will see a resurgence of the free market in some form. This is the trend,
they insist.

For support, they point to the deregulation of commercial airlines, an

undisputed success, and to the increased freedom and competition in financial markets,
which have provided investors and borrowers with many new accounts and services.




- 2-

Outside o f the United States, they point to Britain's new conservative government, which
promises to stop socializing the country's industry and to allow the market to function.
Although these events are real enough, they may not reveal much about the
future, for the trend toward free markets is opposed by a trend toward more government
regulation and control.

Some observers feel that this trend is really the vanguard of the

future. They point to new rent control laws in California, passed despite all the problems
rent controls have caused

in New

York City.

They point to President Carter’s

multifarious energy program, a program in which the prices, the goods produced, the
customers served, the development o f new technology, the amount of profits, and many
other decisions traditionally handled by the market mechanism— even the hours and days
gas stations are open— could be placed under the jurisdiction o f the government.
With contradictory trends existing side by side, the future can't be foreseen
simply by identifying a trend, no matter how noteworthy a particular one may be.

The

reason for this is not just that several trends can exist simultaneously, though this is
indeed a source o f confusion.

The reason, at root, is that without a good theory for

guidance, no one can be certain how long or how far a trend w ill continue.
based on a fleeting trend can be embarrassingly wrong.

A forecast

A demographer who forecast

population growth based on the birth rates o f the late 1950s would have imagined an
American landscape as crowded as Hong Kong's.

Although this sounds like an easily

avoidable error, a good many prognosticators do virtually the same thing— they simply
isolate a trend and assume that it will continue.

Such a methodology may not be much

better than that of the ancient Greeks.
Since trends can be misleading, economists, who are often called upon to
predict the future, have developed techniques that can provide more accurate forecasts.
They build models o f the economy to tell them what will happen if specific policies are
adopted or specific events occu;. A model is a set of assumptions that expresses a theory
of economic relationships and human behavior.




One can construct a simple model by

- 3-

assuming that today's trends will be tomorrow’s. But to make the best forecasts one needs
a more sophisticated model that does not merely extrapolate current trends.
Building a model from assumptions. As an economist, 1 prefer to use a model
that is sophisticated and explicit for making forecasts.

The basic technique of model

building— making some assumptions and deriving conclusions from them— can be applied
to the problem o f predicting the future o f the market economy.

This technique has long

given good forecasts in microeconomics, it is beginning to give good ones in macro­
economics, and there is no reason why it can't help forecast how social institutions, like
the role o f government in the marketplace, will evolve. No economist would pretend that
models provide perfect foresight— few would even claim they provide perfect hindsight.
But this approach is the best I know o f for predicting the future.
One must obviously be careful not to change assumptions in the middle o f the
analysis. If this sounds unarguably logical, good. Unfortunately, logical consistency is not
a common practice either for predicting the future or for assessing economic policy.
Many, many people who predict the future never reveal what their assumptions are,
forcing one to read between the lines to determine if their predictions are consistent.
And most economists, as I will explain later, use one set of assumptions for analyzing the
behavior o f firms and markets, and quite another for analyzing the effects o f government
policy. Strangely, in a discipline as technical and intellectual as economics, it is heretical
to insist that the same assumptions should apply to ail parts o f the economy.
To build a model that can foretell the future o f the market economy, one
needs to start with some assumptions about how people behave. One theory o f behavior
that economists generally agree on is that people act in their own self-interest.

This

means, quite simply, that people strive to better their condition and to obtain the things
they want. I find this a persuasive assumption. The alternatives—that people try to hurt
themselves or just don't care—may contain a jot of satirical truth, but do not describe the
way most people act.




-

-

From the basic principle o f self-interest can be derived a host of inferences:
People buy at the lowest price they can find, all other things being equal.

People try to

persuade government to enact legislation favoring their age group, region, or occupation.
People learn from experience, if they can benefit from it in any way. People prefer more
to less.

That is, if they can have more of something they want— say, more leisure—

without having to settle for less o f anything else they want, then they will choose to have
more.

People decide how much to save, consume, and work based on their own

preferences, their information about current opportunities, and their expectations about
the future.
Self-interest is not always a matter of dollars and cents.

Most o f us, to one

degree or another, value such intangibles as freedom, security, and personal reputation.
To say that people pursue their own interests is not to say that we have forsaken all law
and all conscience, that we are living in a modern jungle. If we fe e l better contributing to
worthy causes, feeding the hungry, or helping a sick neighbor, then we are acting out of
self-interest when we do these things. This is not to belittle such kindnesses. The point is
that self-interest is not the same as selfishness.

It includes all the things that people

might want--and most people want love, friendship, and justice as much as they want
material rewards.
Self-interest
countries.

is not peculiar to

the United

States and other capitalist

It exists as well in feudal, socialist, and communist countries.

The Soviet

bureaucrat, the East German athlete, the African farmer, the Israeli teacher, the Chinese
soldier—all try to get more o f the things they value, even though their different political
regimes channel their self-interest in different directions. The rules o f the game differ,
but the object remains remarkably constant.
Self-interest in a democracy.

Since political structure can influence how

people pursue their self-interest, one cannot build a forecasting model without making
another assumption:




that the United States will remain a democracy. This means, first,

- 5-

that people can exchange ideas freely in what amounts to an intellectual marketplace. If
someone develops a cheaper way to produce steel, a fairer way to pay for governmental
projects, or a better way to train executives, others can find out about them. This allows
them to learn how to further their self-interest.

This kind of freedom has long been a

part o f our country's traditions, and I don't believe we will give it up very easily.
There are, admittedly, some impediments to the free flow of information in
this country, even today.

Some are governmental.

One can understand why the

government wanted to censor instructions on how to build a hydrogen bomb, but one
wonders why it won't let banks advertise that savers can pool their funds to buy highyielding certificates o f deposit.
The impediments to the free flow of information are not always governmental,
however.

For instance, when a representative o f a television station called our Bank to

ask that an economist appear on a broadcast, she said she didn't want a "knee-jerk freemarket economist who doesn't care about people.”
remark.

I submit that this was a prejudicial

Although to her credit, she did allow our Director o f Research to appear on the

station, personal biases can prevent--and no doubt have prevented— useful ideas from
being heard.

Despite a few unfortunate impediments, though, new or unpopular ideas in

this country are more available than not, and I will assume that this intellectual freedom
will continue.
If the United States remains a democracy, people will not only be able to
exchange ideas freely, but be essentially free to act. Again, this is part o f our country's
tradition and seems likely to continue.

Most o f the time, people are free to act in their

own self-interest without the approval or interference o f the government, as long as they
don't defraud or coerce other people.
True, the government often takes on more ambitious projects than preventing
fraud or coercion.

It requires seat belts, licenses doctors, tests air, flouridates water,

builds schools, sets speed limits, fights fires, sponsors research, and does thousands of




- 6-

other things that somebody feels are in the public interest. Such things do impair people's
freedom to act.

Nonetheless, 1 think it fair to make the assumption that people are

essentially free to act.

The people freely elected the government that imposed these

restrictions on them, and they are free to reject it if they so choose.
A il o f these assumptions, of course, inevitably simplify the real world, and
when the world differs from my assumptions, my predictions o f the future will be less
accurate.

But all predictions o f the future depend on some assumptions, whether stated

or not and whether recognized or not, and the assumptions I have made seem sound.
The benefits o f the market economy. If free individuals act in their own best
interests, what economic arrangements will they choosc?

Clearly, those that provide

them with the most benefits, and in virtually every case, a market economy provides the
most. Those who heard this at grandfather's knee may think it went out o f style with the
bujgy whip— and, ail right, it may be out of style.

But today's brightest economists are

finding that it is nevertheless true, and their theoretical breakthroughs remedy many o f
the complaints about free markets that bothered the liberal economists of a generation
ago.

Although saying that a market economy is in the best interests o f America sounds

old-fashioned, it can be supported by some o f the most radical economic research in
decades.
To understand what a market economy is, it is first necessary to know what an
economy does.

A ll economies must solve some fundamental problems to decide three

main things: what is produced, how it is produced, and for whom it is produced. In some
societies, these decisions are made by tradition, as they were in India when it had a caste
system.

In other societies, such as the Soviet Union, these decisions are usurped by a

dictator or delegated to representatives so that someone is responsible for comprehensive
planning.




- 7-

In societies with market economies, the decisions about what to produce, how,
and for whom are made by individuals trying to better themselves.

Individuals decide

what jobs to take and what things to buy by using whatever information they have
available.

This sounds haphazard, but in fact, the checks and balances built into this

system make it viable and efficien t.
Prices:

bringing order to the marketplace. The price system brings order to

what might otherwise have been chaos, because prices are useful information. Given any
set of prices, individuals make decisions in an e ffo rt to maximize their own welfare.
Consumers, for example, make many decisions based on prices.

To drive a car or eat a

steak they must give up something else, and that something else, in the most immediate
‘ ense, is a sum o f money equal to the price. The money, in turn, represents the skill, the
time, or the capital needed to earn it.

The trade-offs facing consumers, in other words,

are conveniently indicated by prices.
Resource owners as well as consumers make decisions based on prices. In a
capitalist society, the owners of resources, including workers who own their own labor,
provide resources to the users who o ffe r the highest pricc, all other things being equal. A
higher price induces more people to provide resources. Expectations o f a higher price in
the future will induce them to withhold resources now and make them available later.
People make decisions by considering their wants— their self-interest— and the prices o f
what they want.
Prices coordinate all these private decisions so that they reflect what society
values.

The U.S., for instance, produces more electric dishwashers than scullery maids

partly because the machines cost so much less than a maid's salary. It is more efficien t to
employ, say, a thousand people to make and sell dishwashers than to have perhaps a
hundred thousand maids washing dishes in individual kitchens.

The prices reflect this,

encouraging people to choose the more efficien t alternative.

Prices guide laborers in

choosing where to work, too.




They try to work at the best paying jobs, those where

- 8-

customers most want their skills or their product.

Prices, in short, do what central

planners try to do— but often more quickly.
Because the price system translates a great number of individual priorities
into a single valuation for each item, it is a useful and responsive information system.
Because of this, it is also an efficien t economic system, as efficien t as any that could be
designed. Efficient, in the parlance o f economists, means that given the total amount o f
resources— the

workers, the

managers, the raw materials, the technology, and so

forth--there is no way to generate more output or more wealth. One economic system is
more e fficien t than smother if it can produce the same output with few er resources.
No one, not even government experts, can come up with a more efficien t
system than the free market. The government can do many things~and should—but there
is very little it can do to improve the performance o f a free-market economy. The very
best it can do is to figure out exactly what people want and need, what risks they want to
assume, what pay they need to do certain jobs, and so forth, and then establish a
government-run imitation o f the market economy. The government, at best, can do what
the market economy does all the time. And on a bad day it can do much worse.
When markets fa il.

O f course, in certain unusual cases, a system o f free

markets must be augmented with collective e ffo rt.

Some commodities and services, for

example, are public goods— goods that benefit everyone collectively but cannot in any
practical way be divided up and sold to individuals.
generally seen as public goods.

National defense and highways are

A strict market economy cannot provide these public

goods because the benefits do not go proportionately to the people who pay for them. If
Mrs. Jones hires a private army to patrol the border, Mr. Smith shares the benefits
without paying a thing. If they both hire a few soldiers without some coordination, they
could have two waring factions, benefiting neither o f them. The clear solution is for the
two of them to agree with the other residents to hire an army and split the costs in some
manner. C ollective effo rt, instead o f individual e ffo rt in various markets, is necessary to
provide these goods.



- 9-

Another special case that calls for collective e ffo rt is the existence o f exter­
nalities.

Externalities are the benefits and problems that an owner passes on to other

people without any payment.

Painting one’s house, for instance, gives one's neighbors a

better view and perhaps raises their property values, but the homeowner pays for it and
cannot charge the neighbors for it. Air pollution is another externality. A factory, within
certain limits, can release undesirable effluents into the air, but does not have to pay
people for their inconvenience.

The market system by itself can't easily deal with such

externalities, because they a ffe c t things no individual owns, like the view or the air.
When the externalities are significant enough, the government does have a legitim ate
reason to respond, although it must choose its methods carefully.
A third special circumstance that calls for collective e ffo rt is the existence o f
monopolies. The competition o f the free market usually keeps monopolies from forming,
but when one does exist its products can be higher priced than they would have been if the
firm had faced competition.

This is why governments either break up monopolies, as

happened with the old Aluminum Company of America, or regulate their prices, as
happens with the telephone company.
A ll

three

cases

of

market

failure— public

goods,

externalities,

and

monopolies— are rarer than many people think, and yet the government persistently
intervenes in the market.

Frequently, a market failure is not the motivation for its

intervention. Rising or falling prices for a commodity, for instance, have often prompted
government action.

This is a pity. A falling price for steel or a rising price for gasoline

might well indicate that the market is working, not failing.
Although government involvement may be necessary in the cases of public
goods, externalities, monopolies, and maldistribution o f wealth, one type o f involvement is
not as good as any other. A ll too frequently our representatives have taken the existence
of market failures to be license for ignoring the market mechanism entirely.

For

example, outright bans on various types of pollution are established independent o f the




- 10-

benefits and costs.

This is clearly wasteful.

Suppose the state of Minnesota wanted to

cut air pollution in half. It could decree that by a certain date all polluters must cut their
emissions by half, but this would ignore the costs o f preventing pollution. It might cost as
much to reduce pollution by one unit in factory A as it does to reduce it by one thousand
units in factory B. Obviously, reducing pollution at factory B is preferable, a better deal.
The problem, perhaps, is that there is no well-known mechanism for legislating
this.

It is not feasible to have a different pollution standard for every factory.

This is

where the price system comes in. Minnesota could o ffe r for sale permits for air pollution,
something like fishing licenses.

Each permit would allow the owner to emit a certain

amount o f pollution for a given period, and the state would sell only a limited number o f
permits, so that pollution would be reduced. The price o f the permits could be determined
by auctioning them o ff to the highest bidders.

In this way, those companies that would

have to spend the most to cut emissions would buy the permits, since this would be their
cheapest alternative.

The other companies would install antipollution devices— their

cheapest alternative.

Putting a price on pollution would thus result in more cost-

e ffe c tiv e means of reducing it.
Most o f the tim e the government has no hope o f improving upon the market; in
the rare cases where it can improve upon it, it must take care not to ignore the market
mechanism altogether, or else it will produce unnecessarily costly programs.

Although

government programs have produced some indisputable benefits, the same results could
often have been obtained at a lower cost if the market economy hadn't been ignored.
A fair distribution o f income. Even when the free-market system is working
properly, the distribution o f income may not meet our standards o f fairness or security.
This, however, is no reason to abandon the free-market system entirely.

Our decisions

about what to produce and how to produce it do not have to determine who receives it.
The optimal way to produce things and the optimal way to aid the poor must
be considered as related but separate problems. For instance, when the poor cannot easily




- 11 -

afford heating oil, we do not have to forsake the market and control the price of oil. If
we le ft the price mechanism unfettered and simply gave poor people a certain amount o f
money to buy heating oil, we would have more oil because producers could get more
money for it. In addition, the price system would still communicate a crucial fact:
there

is,

indeed,

a

short

supply

of

oil

and

that

we

need

to

look

that
for

alternative fuels. A high oil price would encourage rich and poor alike to look for other
fuels.
But, some people might object, if we just give the poor money, they might
spend it not on heating oil, but on televisions.

Televisions may not be the most socially

worthwhile product in town, but when people buy them they are presumably buying what
they want, given the real scarcity of all resources. In their own terms, they are better
o ff--th e y have done what they want.

Society, too, is better o ff because they have

decided to buy less oil, leaving more available for those who value it more highly.
An important point, sometimes overlooked, is that all collective decisions—
those dealing with market failures and those designed to redistribute income— force some
people to purchase things they do not think they benefit from.

Pacifists may object to

paying anything for an army. People who like to drive on country roads may not want to
pay as much as they are taxed for new highways. The poor may prefer to have dirtier air
if it means they can better afford a car. In such cases, people are denied some portion o f
their freedom.

A market economy, in contrast, leaves people free to make the choices

that suit them best, as long as they can afford them. It provides not only the most output,
but the most freedom.
Less is more.

Since the free market generally provides the most o f what

people want, reducing the role o f government in our economy would make people better
o ff, except in cases o f market failure, of course. Government involvement in markets is
in efficient— that is, it provides less than the maximum possible from the resources it
consumes— and not for any trivial reason. It is inefficient, first, because it uses resources




-

12

to do what would have been done anyway.

-

That is, if the government finds the most

efficien t way to price and distribute a product like gasoline, it is using our resources only
to do something superfluous, because the market would have found the most efficien t way
without any governmental expenditures. Government involvement in functioning markets,
in short, is inefficient because it is unnecessary.

Second, it is inefficient because the

government is rarely able to find the most efficien t ways o f doing things.

When the

government decides to get into the gasoline business, for example, it does not just
duplicate what the market is doing, which would be inefficient enough.

It creates new

regulations and new roadblocks that further reduce efficien cy. In short, its involvement is
not only unnecessary but counterproductive.
In many individual markets where free competition could be expected to work,
there is government involvement, often because special interest groups persuaded our
representatives to intercede in their behalf in the marketplace. Usury laws, for instance,
have been passed in many states to keep home mortgages affordable or to protect
innocent borrowers. These laws are price ceilings, limiting the interest banks can charge
for loans.

Studies done at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and elsewhere,

however, have shown that interest rate ceilings fail to lower the cost of a loan.
Sometimes, they dry up all the funds that had been available for lending because the
people with money to invest put it someplace where they get a better return. Sometimes
lenders find other ways to charge money for the loans, ultimately resulting in higher
costs. Rarely do usury laws accomplish what they were intended to do.
Price floors have as many drawbacks as price ceilings.

Minimum wage laws,

for instance, contribute to the unemployment o f unskilled laborers and are especially hard
on minorities and teenagers.

While floors and ceilings do benefit some groups, they are

inefficient ways o f doing so.

If, as a society, we wish to alter the distribution o f goods

and services in favor o f particular groups, such as indebted homeowners or skilled
laborers, we can do it at a smaller cost by giving them cash gifts financed from tax




- 13-

revenues.

We don't have to impede the free movement o f prices, causing so many side

effects.
This is not a controversial point in the economics profession. Economists are
almost unanimous in their opposition to price ceilings, price floors, and other restrictions
on competition.

The reason they oppose price ceilings is that lowering a good's price by

legal mandate exacerbates the scarcity that led originally to the high price. If gasoline is
selling for a higher than normal price, this indicates that people want more gasoline or
that suppliers have less to sell than usual.

If the price can rise, fewer people will be

demanding gasoline and more suppliers will be willing to find and sell it. A shortage thus
can be avoided very easily with no government involvement. If the price is not allowed to
rise, however, users.have no additional incentive to conserve and suppliers have no
additional incentive to provide*
In fact, price controls encourage relatively frivolous uses o f gasoline. Suppose
that two families both want ten gallons o f gas at its current price. One family wants the
gas to bring its corn harvest to town, the other to go waterskiing. A t the current price,
neither will change its demand for gas. As the price goes up, the family o f water-skiers
will find less expensive pleasures, and the fam ily o f farmers, valuing the gas more highly,
will still be able to get enough to go to town.

In no event would price controls on gas

discourage waterskiing.
But what about the inequity, someone might say. What if the fam ily o f waterskiers is so rich that they would buy the gas at almost any price, letting the farmers be
stuck at home. This may be unfair, but price controls would not solve the problem. If the
price o f gas is kept artificially low, the rich people will still buy a lot o f gas and the
farmers may still be stuck at home. If rationing were established, the rich could probably
buy ration tickets or hire people to wait in line for them.

And if rationing were strict

enough to give everyone the same amount, the amount would have to be an average.
Then, the rich who live in town might still have enough gas to go waterskiing while poor




- 14 farmers still have too little to get to market.

The only solution is to let the price rise.

This will hurt the poor farmers, too, but it will hurt them and society less than any other
approach, and after ail,

there

is nothing the government can do about the real

problem— that gas isn't as plentiful as it used to be.

Price controls and rationing can't

turn one gallon into two. When there is no market failure, government intervention tends
to make things worse.
Those aggravating aggregates.
of the economy as a whole:

What is true of individual markets is also true

government manipulation rarely helps.

The government's

efforts to manipulate aggregate economic variables like total employment, total income,
and the average price level have failed repeatedly and are doomed to fail again.
Many economists would disagree with this statement. While they would agree
that government intervention in individual markets is harmful unless it is addressing
market

failures,

they

would

recommend

that

government

manipulate

these

large

aggregates. They hold this somewhat schizophrenic attitude because for many years the
economics profession was unable to explain business cycles and unemployment with
classical models of the free-m arket system, models that had people acting in their own
best interests.

Economists consequently took a shortcut.

They tried to explain business

cycles without developing a coherent theory; they treated the aggregates as if they had a
life of their own and were not the result of individual behavior. In essence, their models
were a set o f relationships among aggregate variables. If inflation went up a few points,
for instance, unemployment was supposed to come down a certain amount.

These

relationships were assumed to stay the same even in different periods and even when
government policy changed.
O f course, since these models did not address the problem o f people's
individual welfare, they could not determine how to increase it.

So, to establish a

direction for policy, the economists had to impose value judgements from outside these
models. Once they decided that low unemployment, a stable growth o f GNP, and a stable




- 15-

price level looked worthwhile, they evaluated government policies by how well they could
further these goals. It turned out that the policies that best fulfilled these goals in these
questionable models required an active government.

When these policies were taken

seriously in the 1960s and 1970s, economic intervention became the rule rather than the
exception.
The new economics.

Two developments have led a growing number of

economists to reject these government attempts to manipulate the economy.

First, the

relationships which were supposed to be stable have proved to be anything but that in
recent years. The presumed trade-off between inflation and unemployment, for instance,
was supposed to be an unalterable law.

It is the whole reason for policies that

intentionally create inflation to reduce unemployment, yet it has consistently produced
wrong forecasts.

It has missed the mark by embarrassing margins.

Inflation sometimes

jumped up four percentage points when it was supposed to drop two. The models adopted
because

earlier

models

didn't

conform

to

the

facts

were

themselves

in glaring

disagreement with the facts.
The second development that spelled doom for the models that ignored selfinterest was a theoretical breakthrough.

While some economists had simply cast aside

classical models because they didn't explain business cycles and unemployment, others
uncomfortable with the schism between microeconomic and macroeconomic theory tried
to modify these models to fit the facts better.
Many o f the early successes o f this research came from Robert Lucas, now o f
the University o f Chicago, and from Tom Sargent and Neil Wallace, both at the University
o f Minnesota and the Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank.
thought is usually called Rational Expectations.

Their school o f economic

The name follows from the fact that

people in their models are assumed to use all available information efficien tly and to act
in their own self-interest. They arc thus rational. These economists, along with others in
the field, have demonstrated that a market economy, inhabited by rational individuals,




-

16

-

could indeed produce a trade-ofl between inflation and unemployment. But--and this is a
crucial provision— the trade-off changes whenever government policy changes.

Thus,

government cannot exploit this tra d e -o ff--if it tries to cause inflation to reduce
unemployment, it will get more of both inflation and unemployment.
Furthermore, the Rationalists have found that when individuals act in their
best interests and process information efficien tly, active governmental intervention
makes individuals worse o ff. In fact, it makes them worse o ff even when its attempts at
manipulating the economy are successful.

Government can sometimes manipulate the

economy so that GNP grows faster than it otherwise would, for example, but this does not
make people better o ff.

The manipulations trick people into working more than they

otherwise would have, and tricking people into giving up their leisure does not give them
what they really want. This goes back to the value judgements that the economists who
built these models had to make— they assumed that rapid GNP growth was good, but they
did not consider what sacrifices people would have to make to achieve this rapid growth.
As it turns out, very rapid economic growth is so expensive in terms o f foregone leisure
that, given a choice, people on the whole would rather have their leisure.
An implication common to all Rational Expectations models is that neutral,
stable policies are better than the on-again, off-again policies the government has
followed to fight inflation or smooth out the business cycle. Rational Expectations theory
implies that the best policies might include such steps as balancing the federal budget on
average over the business cycle; avoiding drastic changes in federal expenditures and tax
rates; controlling total government debt more closely; and making economic institutions
like tax laws, w elfare programs, and the regulation o f banks more efficien t.
To market, to market.

Since people do act in their own best interests, they

are motivated to learn how to improve their condition.

As more people learn that free

markets benefit them, they will instruct their representatives to reduce the government's
involvement in working markets. In the future, then, there will probably be more rational




- 17-

environmental regulations, fewer price supports, fewer interest rate ceilings, a less
distorting tax structure, few er minimum wage laws, and, in general, less government
involvement in functioning markets.

There will probably be fewer governmental efforts

to manipulate unemployment and GNP, and more reliance on fixed, stable policies.
Simultaneously, there will probably be greater efficiency, greater productivity, more
irecdom, more available goods and services, and, in general, a healthier economy. I'm not
claiming that the streets will be paved with gold, only that the citizens of this country
will try to improve their situation and will make some progress.
To be more specific, the future may see such changes in financial markets as;
lifting Regulation Q, which limits the interest banks can pay on savings and
checking accounts;
allowing checking accounts at savings and loans, credit unions, and similar
financial institutions;
allowing more interstate banking and branch offices;
eliminating most usury laws; and
charging a com petitive price for the services the Federal Reserve performs,
like processing checks and shipping money to commercial banks.
I feel strongly that these changes are for the better.

Banks and financial institutions

would benefit from the new markets they could enter; consumers would benefit from the
greater variety of services; borrowers would be able to find the funds they want; savers
would be able to earn a fairer rate o f interest.

People, in sum, would get more o f what

they want.
A little bit o f learning. To bring about this future most quickly, two kinds o f
institutional changes are needed. First, education, in the broadest sense o f the term, is
needed.

Better economic education could start with better schooling.

A t the moment,

high school students learn how politics and law can influence their society, but most don't
learn even the rudiments o f how these things a ffe c t economic well-being— and politics




- 18and law, more than ever, are determining how productive our economic system is. This is
more than an advertisement for my favorite subject. This is a plea to recognize that our
political or social goals can be met in various ways, some less expensive than others.
There is no reason whatsoever to choose the more costly ways— they are not more moral,
and they are certainly not more rational.
Another educational change needed to make people more aware o f the price of
government involvement in the market is to compute opportunity costs fully. Opportunity
costs are not just the dollar costs, but the sum of all the things given up in order to
realize a project. The opportunity cost of having a nationalized post o ffic e includes not
only the subsidies that it receives, but the more limited service everyone must accept
because there are no innovative competitors.
If opportunity costs were reckoned fully, government projects would almost
certainly be less ambitious.

Take the regulation o f banks.

Today, the Federal Reserve

lells banks that the most interest they can pay on a daily account is 5 1/4 percent. This
costs relatively little in enforcement or administration, but it is not a cheap program. A t
5 1/4 percent, savers are losing real income because inflation is much higher than this
percentage— this is one cost. In addition, many o f them, rather than take this loss, look
for better places to put their money— bonds, certificates of deposit, money market
accounts, stamps, or rare coins, for instance. The time they spend doing this instead o f
something more productive is another cost.

If just the main opportunity costs of

government programs were calculated and published, people might begin to appreciate
how efficien tly the market works— and be a bit more suspicious o f government inter­
vention in legitim ate markets.
A third necessary educational change is for proponents o f markets to take
different approaches than they have. I do not know what they need to do, but they have
certainly failed until now.

The politician who calls for price controls on haircuts to stop

the dandruff crisis is seen as a selfless, kindhearted intellectual who sees big solutions to




- 19 -

big problems, while the barber who objects is only a would-be robber baron. Few people
would stop to ask whether there is a functioning market for haircuts, whether there is a
connection between haircuts and dandruff, and whether a few more lint-free shoulders are
worth the cost o f a government war on dandruff.
Overcoming the resistance of favored groups.

In addition to educational

changes, there need to be other institutional changes if this future is to come quickly.
One reason that some groups who pursue their own best interests resist a market economy
is that our laws and regulations now favor them. Farmers, for instance, benefit from the
price supports that the government maintains on various crops.

If these price supports

were removed, some farmers would be worse o ff until they could make the transition to
other crops, more efficien t techniques, or other types of work. Understandably, people in
this situation are afraid of what would happen if the government stopped protecting them.
Shoemakers don't want quotas on imported shoes lifted, steel manufacturers don't want
tariffs on imported steel reduced, union members don't want nonmembers to be able to
take over their jobs when they go on strike, although everyone else would save money if
these things happened.
For such special interest groups to relinquish the favors o f government, they
need some guarantee that they will not suffer unduly while the transition to a more
market-oriented economy takes place.

This does not mean that no one will experience

any loss o f income. If no one did, no one would have the incentive to change jobs or look
for more productive methods, and the economy would not improve.

Any attempt to

guarantee that no one will fa il and that all incomes will rise proportionately is sure to
eliminate the incentives crucial to an efficien t market economy. But everyone can have
the guarantee that the economy will be producing more goods and services and that
everybody will have an opportunity to share this additional wealth.
One suggestion for making sure that no one starves or freezes during the
transition to a less political economic system is the negative income tax.




A negative

-

20 -

income tax is a program for transferring wealth to the poor or to special interests based
on income tax statements.

Under this program, these people would receive a certain

amount o f money, probably on some graduated scale. There would be lots o f hazards with
such a plan. If the negative tax was set too high, it could discourage people from working
and put a strain on the tax system and the whole economy. And if it was adopted without
corresponding changes in other welfare programs, from price supports to food stamps, it
could turn out to be an expensive step in the wrong direction. But somehow we need to
make institutional changes to overcome the inertia of the present system; we need to
remove the incentives that induce certain groups to fight against an efficien t economy;
we need to find a way to support the poor or subsidize favored groups without destroying
the efficien cy o f the free market. If the negative income tax is not the best way to do
this, we should be able to devise another way.
Ultim ately, I am confident that we will find a way to overcome the obstacles
and create a more vigorous market economy for the simple reason that doing so is in our
best interests.

If one were to take issue with my basic premise, that people act in their

own self-interest, one might be able to come up with an alternative forecast.

But one

would have to make vastly different assumptions, assumptions that economists have
rejected because they do not yield usable or accurate descriptions of economic behavior
when consistently applied.
One might assume, for instance, that people won't see that government is
imposing unnecessary costs on society. This is equivalent to saying that people can't learn
from experience or research— and if economists really believed this, they would probably
go into other lines o f work.

One might also assume that special interest groups will

oppose ending the governmental practices that benefit them.

No doubt some w ill, but

they can succeed only if the U.S. is not a democracy, only if a minority can bully the
majority into accepting something bad for the country as a whole.

Again, this doesn't

seem to be very plausible as a general rule, although it does happen on occasion.




If it

- 21 -

happened regularly, there would be no free market to defend or discuss--there would be in
its place a political system designed to transfer wealth from the majority to the favored
groups.
Assumptions other than the ones I have made seem to underestimate people or
misread the political signs.

They seem to imply that people are indifferent to pain,

discomfort, and inconvenience, that they actively seek unplcasurable experiences, or that
they are powerless to help themselves. These assumptions seem so implausible that I am
persuaded again o f the reasonableness o f my assumptions and my forecast: People act in
their own best interests; governmental involvement in markets and manipulation o f the
aggregates is not in their best interests; therefore, they will eventually reject unnecessary
government intervention and develop a more market-oriented economy. This process may
take a long tim e, but I await its arrival eagerly.