View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
June 3, 1984
10:00 A.M. (E.D.T.)

Statement by

Lyle E. Gramley

Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy
of the
Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs




U.S. House of Representatives

June 8, 1984

I am glad to appear before this Subcommi t.tee
to present the views of the Federal Reserve Board on the
behavior of interest rates this year.

My remarks will

focus on the principal causes of the recent rise in interest
rates and its implications for the overall expansion of the
economy.

My colleague, Karen Horn, President of the Federal

Reserve Bank of Cleveland, will discuss the effects of the
increase in interest rates on economic conditions in the Fourth
Federal Reserve District.

Interest rates have moved substantially higher this
year.

Short-term rates have risen about 1 to 1-1/2 percentage

points since December.

In long-term markets, rate increases

on Treasury and corporate bonds have been as large as those on
short-term securities.

Increases in rates on mortgages

have been somewhat more moderate.

A rise in interest rates in an expanding economy
is not unusual.

As Chart 1 illustrates,

interest rates

typically increase during periods of economic expansion,
when growing demands for money and credit press against
limited supplies.

Interest rate patterns during the first

1-1/2 years of expansion do differ.




Nevertheless, the chart

-2 -

suggests that the rise in short-term rates during the
current expansion has not been exceptional.

The

increase in long-term rates during the first year and
a half of this recovery is, however, quite large relative
to the experience of the past 30 years.

What role, if any, has monetary policy played
in the rise of interest rates since late last year?

The

answer is, I believe, a minor one.

During the late spring of 1983, the Federal Reserve
did take steps to slow the growth of Ml and M2 from the very
high rates that had prevailed in the latter half of 1982 and
early 1983.

It did so in the context of growing evidence

that the economic recovery was robust and that the velocity
of money, particularly that of Ml, was returning to more
normal patterns.

In that context, those policy actions

were effective in slowing the annual growth rate of Ml to
7-1/4 percent, and the growth rate of M2 to about 8 percent,
from the second to the fourth quarter average of last
year.




-3-

In February,

the Federal Reserve announced growth

ranges for 1984 of four to eight pcrcent for Ml, six to nine
percent for M2 and M3, and eight to eleven percent for the
debt of domestic nonfinancial borrowers.

When these ranges

were announced, most observers considered them appropriate
to support the nation's economic objective of sustained
economic expansion without jeopardizing progress against
inflation.

That judgment is still, I believe, correct.

From the fourth quarter of last year through the
first four weeks of May, Ml increased at around a 7 percent
annual rate, about equal to its rate of increase in the
second half of last year and in the upper half of the target
range for 1984 (Chart 2).

From the fourth quarter through

April--the latest month for which data are available--M2 had
increased at a 6-3/4 percent annual rate, in the lower half
of its range and a little slower than in the second half of
last year.

M3 growth on the other hand, accelerated to a

9-1/2 percent annual rate, above the upper end of its range
and above the rate of expansion in the second half of 1983.
These patterns of change in the monetary aggregates do not
support the contention that monetary restraint has played
any substantial role in the rise of interest rates this
year.




-4 -

A more likely source of the upward pressure
on interest rates is the explosion that has occurred
in demands for credit, generated in the main by the
strength of economic expansion.

In nominal terms,

GNP rose at more than a 10 percent annual rate in the
latter half of 1983, and the pace of expansion increased
further to almost a 13 percent annual rate in the first
quarter of 1984.

By late last year, the growth of total

credit extended to domestic nonfinancial borrowers was
near the upper end of the Federal Reserve's monitoring
range, as indicated in Chart 3.

The growth rate of such

debt has risen still further, to above the upper end of the
monitoring range, in the early months of 1984.

Private credit demands typically strengthen as
recovery proceeds, and this recovery has been no exception.
In the private domestic nonfinancial sectors, the growth of debt
has

moved progressively upward, from a six percent annual

rate in the first quarter of 1983 to nearly 12 percent in
the first quarter of 1984.

Consumer instalment debt rose

at a 17 percent annual rate in the first quarter; mortgage
borrowing remained strong, and business credit demand
strengthened substantially further.

While some business

borrowing this year has been to finance takeovers and other




-5-

forms of reorganization, underlying business credit demands
have also increased--as growing outlays for investment in
inventories and plant and equipment have outpaced the internal
generation of funds.

While an increase in credit usage by private
borrowers is normal during an economic expansion, sustained
heavy credit demands by the Federal government are not.
Historically,

the Federal deficit and borrowing have dropped

off rapidly in an expansion,

as growth in private income

leads to higher tax receipts, and Federal spending slows for
a variety of income support programs.
remains as huge

When Treasury borrowing

as it is currently, competition between public

and private borrowers is bound to intensify.

Both traditional economic theory and common sense
suggest that increases in government spending, or reductions
in taxes, tend to stimulate the economy, raise total credit
demands relative to supplies, and push up interest rates.
There is a large body of empirical evidence supporting that
view.

Econometric models by the dozens have been constructed

that find significant effects of fiscal stimulus on the real
economy and on interest rates.
monetarist persuasion,

They include models of a

such as the well-known model of the

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.




-

6

-

The state of knowledge is not sufficiently
advanced to permit precise estimates of the effects of
increasing deficits on interest rates.

But the magnitudes

are apparently not small when fiscal stimulus occurs on the
scale we have seen in recent years.

Since fiscal 1981, the

structural deficit in the Federal budget--that is, the deficit
that emerges when Federal receipts and expenditures are adjusted
for the cyclical position of the economy--has risen by about
$100 billion.

Such an increase, according to some econometric

models, may have raised interest rates by two percentage points
or more, other things equal.

Longer range developments in financial markets have
also played a role in the behavior of interest rates during
the current recovery.

Over the past three decades, and

especially over the past five to ten years, innovation and
deregulation of U.S. financial markets have increased the
mobility of funds from one region of the country to another
and from one market to another.

They have removed nearly

all of the legislative and regulatory impediments to payment
of market-related rates of interest to savers.

Most importantly,

they have led to a breaking down of usury ceilings and other
artificial barriers to credit flows that used to play so
prominent a role in the rationing of available supplies of credit




-7-

among potential borrowers.

In the financial world we live

in now, the rationing of credit is done primarily by interest
rates.

As a consequence,

interest rates in a period of

economic expansion are forced to much higher levels--even
after adjustment for inflation--than we were accustomed to
seeing in the 1960's and the 1970's.

In this context, the prospect that structural
Federal budget deficits might increase substantially further-as they will under current law--has serious implications for
long-term interest rates.

Potential investors in long-term

securities cannot be sure from past experience how high interest
rates will have to go to balance supplies and demands for credit
at a level appropriate to maintaining a sustainable pace of
economic expansion and avoiding a resurgence of inflation.
Failure of the Federal government to take prompt and decisive
action to reduce structural deficits adds powerfully to their
concerns.

Participants in financial markets now widely expect
that a downpayment on deficit reduction will be accomplished
this year.

They are understandably concerned, however,

because the amounts of deficit reduction currently being
discussed for the near term are so small relative to the size




-8 -

of the problem.

Under current law, the structural deficit

will increase by about $25 billion in fiscal 1985.

The two

bills before the Congress provide for deficit-reducing
measures of between $25 and $30 billion in the upcoming fiscal
year--that is, about enough to keep the problem from getting
worse.

Thus, unless the Senate-House conferees adopt

stronger measures of deficit reduction for fiscal 1985, the
near-term effects of the fiscal downpayment on the economy
and on financial markets are likely to be quite small.

Let me

turn now to your question regarding the

effects of the rise in interest rates on the economy.

It

seems evident some slowing in the pace of expansion is likely
to result from the higher costs of credit, and the sectors
most likely to be affected are those--such as housing--in
which dependence on credit is heavy and demands are therefore
sensitive to rising interest rates.

How much the economy will

slow is hard to judge at this juncture, given our limited
knowledge of the relationship between interest rates and
economic activity in today's environment.

A considerable

moderation from the very rapid pace of real economic growth
in the first quarter--nearly nine percent at an annual rate-is necessary if we are to sustain this expansion over time.
It seems likely, however, that economic growth will not slow




-9-

so much as to prevent further progress in reducing unemploy­
ment, because the basic forces of economic expansion are
still quite strong.

Quite apart from their effect on overall economic
growth, the effects of rising interest rates are very
worrisome.

High interest rates relative to those abroad

have pushed up the value of the dollar in exchange markets,
contributing to extraordinarily large deficits in our
merchandise trade and current accounts.

Higher interest

rates add to the already serious problems faced by farmers.
Small businesses more generally have only begun to recover
from the difficulties they encountered in 1980, 1981, and
1982.

Our thrift institutions are still in a weakened

condition.

Equally worrisome is the effect of rising interest

rates on the prospects for managing the external debt-servicing
problems of developing countries.

Many of these countries,

with the advice and assistance of international lending
organizations, are attempting to put in place domestic economic
policies that will generate both cash and confidence to help
them attract capital and meet their obligations.

It is of utmost

importance to us, as well as to them, that they succeed in this
endeavor.
difficult.




A rise in interest rates makes this task more

-10 -

You ask, Mr. Chairman, what policies could be
followed to foster lower interest rates and sustain
economic growth.
you.

I doubt that my answer will surprise

What needs to be done is to act promptly, and

decisively, to reduce structural deficits in the Federal
budget.

Let me note, in this respect,

that the fiscal

"downpayment" presently under discussion in the Congress
is a necessary first step in developing a fiscal policy suited
to our needs.

But it is only a first step in a larger effort

that needs to begin very soon.

Attempts to lower interest rates by speeding up the
growth of money and credit would, under present circumstances,
be a serious mistake.

The economy is growing strongly;

total credit demands are extremely large;

the Federal budget

is badly out of balance; our merchandise trade ^nd current
account deficits are enormous;
accelerating,

inflation, although not yet

is still proceeding at an annual rate of four

to five percent.

If people here and abroad gained the

impression that the Federal Reserve had thrown in the towel
in its efforts to keep money and credit growing at a reasonable
pace, we would be faced, in my judgment, with potentially
chaotic conditions in financial markets.




-11-

Let me assure you that we in the Federal Reserve
have no intention of proceeding on such a course of action.
We are supplying enough money and credit to finance a
sustainable rate of economic expansion, and we intend to
continue doing so.

But we do not intend to waste the

substantial gains in the battle against inflation that have
been won at such enormous cost during the past few years.




########*#########

Chart 1

3-MONTH TREASURY BILL RATE
Percent

20-YEAR TREASURY BOND RATE
Percent

Note Shaded areas represent business cycle recessions.




Chart 2

M1

M2


Note. M1 for May is based on data through May 28.


Billions of dollars




Billions of dollars

Annual rate of growth
1 98 3-04 to April: 9.6 percent

j _____

i_____ i

j____ i

—

2900

—

2800

—

2700

Chart 3

DOMESTIC NONFINANCIAL DEBT
Billions of dollars

Note Domestic nonfinancial debt for April 1984 is estimated




GROWTH IN DOMESTIC NONFINANCIAL DEBT
(Seasonally adjusted annual rates, percent)

Total

Federal
Government

Private

1983-Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

9.0
12.2
10.1
11.4

19.5
25.9
15.2
10.1

6.2
8.4
8.6
11.8

1984-Q1

12.3

14.2

11.8