View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on D elivery

April 14, 1981
10: 30 A. M. E.S.T.

Remarks by

Lyle E. Gramiey

Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




at the

1981 NACHA SurePay Conference

New York, New York
April 14, 1981

I am delighted to have this opportunity to address
the annual conference of the National Automated Clearing House
Association.

The bulk of my remarks today will relate

to the

present and future role of automated clearing houses in our
nation's payments mechanism.

We in the Federal Reserve share

with you a lively interest in this topic.
the issues involved, however,

I want to consider

in the larger context of the effect

of the Monetary Control Act of 1980 on the provision and pricing
of financial services.

It is only infrequently that the Congress,

the Federal

agencies that regulate financial institutions, and the financial
community are able to reach a consensus on major banking and
financial issues of a controversial character.

The enactment

of the Monetary Control Act of 1980 was one such case.
Act deals with several problems.
the payments system are:

The

Those that most directly affect

(1) the extension nationwide of interest-

bearing checking accounts for individuals and some other depositors,
(2) the placing of thrift institutions and commercial banks on an
equal footing in competing for individuals' checking accounts,
and (3) the requirement that the Federal Reserve price all of
its financial services.

This last requirement may have larger

implications for the use of ACH than is generally realized.




-

2

-

The ACH innovation was a product of joint efforts
in the public and private sectors.

We in the Federal Reserve

take some pride in our role in the innovational process.

I

want especially to acknowledge the important part played by one
of my predecessors on the Board of Governors, George Mitchell.
Without his tireless efforts, ACH might never have become a
reality.

The ACH was originally intended to handle a narrow
range of payments transfers, generally low-value recurring
payments.

The Treasury Department was first to demonstrate

the versatility of the ACH by using it to make large-value
deposit transfers to State and local governments participating
in the Federal Revenue Sharing Program.

The banking community

has begun to use the ACH to exchange consumer-initiated payments
such as ATM items and telephone bill payments.

A recent

demonstration of the versatility of the ACH is the program that
began two weeks ago with the banking industry's selection of the
ACH as the mechanism for clearing truncated checks in the ABA's
check safekeeping test.




-

3

-

Over the past decade, the ACH has developed
operational procedures that provide a number of significant
advantages to banks and their customers for both credit and
debit transfers.

However,

the diversion of check and cash

payments to electronic transfers through ACH thus far has
been relatively small.

ACH volume in 1980 was less than 250

million transfers, only about 1-1/2 percent of the 15.6 billion
checks cleared by the Federal Reserve.

The Federal Government is still the major user of the
ACH, accounting for over 80 percent of total volume.

In the

fourth quarter of 1980, the ACH credits generated by the Federal
Government were equal to 30 percent of its check volume.

The

number of Federal checks has been declining for some time--in
1980,

there were 20 percent fewer than in 1975.

Commercial ACH volume has grown much more slowly.
True, volume growth very recently has been impressive in
relative terms--nearly a 90 percent increase last year.
in New York was even larger--more than 150 percent.

Growth

In many

areas of the country, however, volume growth has been modest.
During the past five years, increased commercial use of ACH has
not been sufficient to stem the tide of a growing volume of
commercial checks.

At the Federal Reserve, commercial checks

rose 38 percent from 1975 to 1980.




-

4

-

Some countries have been more successful than the
United States in promoting the use of ACH.

In the United

Kingdom, for example, where payments practices rather closely
resemble ours, the Bankers Automated Clearing House (BACS)
began operations in the early 1970's, at about the same time
as the earliest ACH associations in the U.S.
handled 384 million transfers,

In 1979, BACS

equivalent to more than 15

percent of the 2.2 billion checks written in the U.K.

Why is it that ACH volume in our country has grown
so slov’ly, considering the security, convenience and potential
efficiency that ACH transfers provide?

A number of reasons

have been advanced--such as inertia in the management of
depository institutions,

the difficulty of altering the public's

payments habits, and the lack of electronic capability to
initiate or receive transfers at smaller depository institutions.
There is some truth to each of those allegations.

Nevertheless,

the more fundamental reason for slow growth is the lack of
appropriate economic incentives.

In markets for financial

services, prices have not been playing the role they can play
in promoting economic efficiency.




-

5

-

The major reason for this is the fact that, prior
to passage of the Monetary Control Act of 1980, the Federal
Reserve generally did not charge explicit prices for the
financial services it provided to its member banks.

Up until

now, the Federal Reserve has always given first priority to
providing the maximum certainty, reliability and promptness
to its clearing and settlement functions.

Tight schedules

for cut-off hours and delivery times have impaired efforts to
utilize equipment and staff more efficiently for processing
operations.

The lack of explicit prices for payments services

has encouraged excessive fine-sorting at Federal Reserve offices
and wasteful courier deliveries of small daily volumes. Delivery
is a costly service;

in 1980, courier, mail and express charges

incurred by the Fed for payments services amounted to $40 million.
Availability schedules have been provided for checks that make
no allowance for transportation or equipment breakdowns or
weather delays.

Funds have been, and still are, made avail­

able to depositing banks on the basis of those schedules
regardless of the actual collection time.

The user of paper

checks, moreover, has benefitted greatly from float.
has given rise to payments practices,
controlled disbursement,

such as remote and

that waste resources from the stand­

point of society as a whole.




This

-

6

-

Another reason is that banks typically have not
passed on to banking customers the costs of using payments
services in the form of explicit prices.

This is especially

true as regards transfers of funds by individuals.

To some

degree, the lack of explicit prices for payments services to
ultimate users may reflect the absence of pricing by the Federal
Reserve.

There is, however, no logically necessary connection

between the two.

Considering the environment that has prevailed in
the last decade, it is not surprising that ACH volume has
grown slowly.

ACH transfers have been competing in a payments

system in which originators of payments transfers have strong
reasons to continue use of paper checks because they incur few,
if any, costs in the process.

More importantly perhaps, by

doing so they delay the ultimate transfer of funds and thus
benefit from float.

The Monetary Control Act of 1980 addresses this issue
by requiring the Federal Reserve to price its financial services
and to open access to those services to all depository
institutions.

The Act stipulates that the Federal Reserve must

charge prices for all of its services, including Federal Reserve
float,

that cover the full costs of producing them.

The Act

makes clear that the Federal Reserve must permit--indeed, I
would say encourage--competition from the private sector in the
provision of financial services.



-

7

-

We believe that the requirements of the MCA offer
a unique opportunity for the Federal Reserve to take steps
that will have profound implications for the efficiency with
which payments services are provided in this country.

The

Act puts other requirements on us also--namely, that we ensure
an adequate level of payments services nationwide.

There is,

as I am sure you know, concern within the Federal Reserve about
whether the System can discharge these responsibilities
effectively if it does not maintain an operational presence
in some, if not most, areas of payments services.

However,

we cannot, and will not, compete in ways that are designed to
"protect our turf."

Our principal concern must be an

efficient and effective operation of the payments mechanism.

In this connection, let me comment briefly on the
Board's decision to provide temporarily a subsidized price for
ACH services.

For all services other than ACH,

the prices

published by the Board are based on fully allocated costs plus
a 16 percent private sector adjustment factor.

ACH prices,

on the other hand, are based on a projection of costs based
on volumes that are large enough to realize economies of scale.
We elected to price on this basis because we believe that, over
the long run, the ACH will prove to be a much more efficient




-

means of transferring funds.

8

-

Financial institutions can

offer their customers secure,prompt and relatively economic
electronic payment services that are more adaptable to their
internal data processing operations than are paper-based
transfers.

Your industry has understood our purposes and
supported the temporary subsidization of ACH.

The Federal

Reserve does not, however, intend to subsidize ACH items
indefinitely.

It is not our purpose to drive the paper check

out of existence.
event.

I doubt that we could, or should, in any

The paper check

will almost certainly have an

important role to play in the payments system for the indefinite
future.

The Board will review ACH prices annually to determine

if the subsidy presently granted should be continued or modified.
If our assumptions about ACH volume growth or economies of
large-scale operations prove to be incorrect, we will not hesitate
to modify them and to change our ACH unit prices accordingly.

Among the pricing decisions that the Federal Reserve
makes, one of the most important for the future of the ACH may
well be the way in which Federal Reserve float is handled.

That

decision is, at the same time, of fundamental importance to the
evolution of more efficient payments practices.




-

9

-

Pricing float in ways that increase efficiency in
the payments mechanism is a complex matter.

One of the knottiest

problems stems from the fact that resources used to collect
checks may be wasted from the standpoint of the economy as a
whole.

Both originators and collectors of checks presently

expend substantial amount of resources to increase the avail­
ability of funds to themselves.

Since the result is merely a

transfer of money from one economic unit to another,

there

may be no useful social product created.

Timely collection of checks is important to prevent
fraud and abuse in the nation's payments mechanism.
probability, however,

In all

the time value of money--especially in

an economy with a 10 percent inflation rate--would lead to a
greater use of resources to collect checks than could be
justified by such considerations.
moreover,

This would tend to be true,

even in an economy in which check collection services

were provided entirely by firms in the private sector, operating
under competitive conditions, and charging prices that reflect
costs.




-

10

-

It seems to us extremely important,

therefore,

that

we take this problem very carefully into account in handling
float.

Also, we believe it is important to avoid loading all

of the cost of float onto the depositing institution.

Efficiency

in resource use is unlikely to be enhanced by charging for float
unless the paying bank bears the burden and passes the cost on
to the user of paper checks.

Unfortunately,

it is not easy

to design effective procedures for shifting more of the burden
of reducing float to the paying bank.

The first phase of our program for dealing with
float has emphasized operational improvements within the Fed
with a high benefit-cost ratio.

Since these improvements

speed up the check-collection process while adding modestly
to Federal Reserve expenditures,

they put most of the burden

of the resulting float reduction on the paying bank.

These efforts have met with considerable success.
In 1979, the daily average level of total Federal Reserve float
was $6.7 billion.

As a result of operational improvements,

float decreased 37 percent in 1980 to a level of $4.2 billion.
More recently, total Federal Reserve float has declined to
below $4 billion.




-

11

-

The costs of the operational improvements under­
taken to achieve these results were added into the prices
for check collection that will go into effect August 1, 1981.
By increasing the costs and prices of collecting paper checks,
these operational improvements will help modestly to stimulate
increased use of ACH.

Another program under consideration to reduce Federal
Reserve float is the use of the Fed Wire to speed up the
collection of large dollar-value checks.

The program involves

capturing the MICR data from the check and converting it into
an electronic item for same-day collection, with subsequent
delivery of the paper item for verification.

Electronic collection of checks has important advantages
over other methods of eliminating float.

In effect, it provides

immediate availability to the collecting bank and removes the
benefit of Federal Reserve float that previously accrued to the
paying bank.

Because of that, it would significantly reduce

payments practices

(such as remote and controlled disbursement)

that are very costly for the standpoint of society as a whole.




-

1 ? .-

If electronic collection of large dollar value
checks proves viable,

it will increase the incentives for a

gradual evolution of the payments mechanism toward greater
use of electronic payments transfers in all forms.

ACH

usage will, we believe, be encouraged.

For certain types of payments, ACH cannot realistically
be expected to displace checks, use of cash, or other electronic
forms of money transfers.

But it has extraordinary capabilities

for making income payments of all kinds to individuals and for
bill paying, particularly when the amounts are repetitive.

What other steps could be taken to promote greater
use of ACH technology?

There are at least two that deserve

mention.

Last year the Federal Reserve's ACH deposit deadlines
were moved up five hours by adding a night-time processing cycle.
This allows corporations to receive cash payments from any ACH
member in the nation on an overnight basis.

Despite this improve-

ent, the schedule is not as expeditious as it could be since it
is still geared to the time required to serve the remote
depository institutions by mail or courier.

Deposit deadlines

could be improved substantially if remote banks had the equip­
ment needed for electronic delivery.



-

13

-

Electronic capability to receive and originate
payment advices has many advantages even for low transaction
volumes.

Electronic terminals are better and cheaper than

they were when Governor Coldwell stressed the importance of
electronic delivery at this Conference two years ago.
also have many uses outside the payments mechanism.

They
Wide ­

spread use of low-cost electronic terminals should be
encouraged by the banking industry and the Federal Reserve.

Another operational problem that needs resolution
is the processing of return items.

Almost 90 percent of the

flow of payments between the ACHs and depository institutions
is by telecommunications or magnetic tape, but all return
items are initiated and handled as paper items.

This causes

delays, errors, and unnecessary costs to users of ACH services.
The returns should be automated or, better yet, depository
institutions should address and reduce the problem of NSF returns
through pricing, minimal balances, or guarantees of payment
below certain amounts.

Returns for stop payment or fraud, of

course, would not be affected.




-

14

-

Let me conclude by noting that we are at a
watershed in th<-> history of our country's payments system.
In the next several years, we are likely to see substantial
movement towards a system of money transfers that is
increasingly efficient.

We in the Federal Reserve are confident

that ACH will play a larger role in payments transfers in the
future than it does today.

We look forward to working with you

in NACHA toward the development of a more secure and efficient
payments mechanism.




###############