View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For RELEASE ON DELIVERY
MONDAY, SEPTEMBER 8, 1980
9:00 A.M. E.D.T.

PRICING AND ACCESS TO FEDERAL RESERVE SERVICES

Remarks by
Lyle E. Gramley

MEMBER, BOARD QF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Before the

1980 Southern Regional Operations and Automation Workshop




New Orleans, Louisiana
September 8, 1980

Pricing and Access to Federal Reserve Services

The Monetary Control Act of 1980 requires two fundamental
changes in the way the Federal Reserve provides its payments services.
First, our doors must be open not just to member banks, but to all
financial institutions offering transactions accounts.
of such institutions will soon increase sharply,

The number

Second, prices must

be charged by the Federal Reserve for services rendered.

These changes,

along with the numerous technological innovations that are occurring in
the financial world, may well have a profound and dramatic impact on our
nation's payments mechanism.

None of us can foresee with any clarity what the payments
mechanism will look like 10 years from now, or what the Federal Reserve's
role in it will be.
that trend

I certainly will not try to make any forecasts of

this morning.

What I would like to do is to discuss with

you briefly what the Federal Reserve's responsibilities are under the
Act, as we see them; why the Board made some of its decisions embodied
in the pricing schedule released recently; and some of the potential
problems that we will all have to be alert to as the effects of the
changes stimulated by the Act begin to -unfold.

The changes in payments services mandated by the Act were
motivated by Congressional and Federal Reserve concerns over the System's
membership and related problems.




Historically, only member banks have had

- 2 -

direct access to Federal Reserve services,

While there has been no

explicit charge for these services, iR.’mber banks certainly believe that
they pay for them by maintaining non-interest bearing reserves,
Federal Reserve invests these reserves in Treasury securities

The
and trans­

fers the interest earned, net. of operating expenses, back to the Treasury.
The Congress did not believe, hcwever, that this revenue transfer should
be considered compensation for services received by member banks at no
explicit cost.

The Federal Reserve was also concerned about the lack of
explicit charges for services rendered,

Implicit charges, unrelated to

the quantity of services used, can lead to inequities and, more importantly,
to serious economic inefficiencies.

It was difficult to do anything about

that situation, however, when only member banks were required to hold
reserves at the Fed, particularly in light of the erosion of membership
that had been occurring.

The Monetary Control Act of 1980, by requiring explicit pricing,
open access, and universal required reserves at lower reserve ratios,
responds to the concerns of both the Congress and the Federal Reserve.
Explicit pricing should ensure that payments services are used more
efficiently.

We all recognize that goods and services that are free**«

or more generally, priced below cost— tend to be utilized in. ways that
are wasteful.

Artificially cheap gasoline promotes too much driving;

similarly, cheap payments services encourage wasteful use of resources.




- 3 The law opens up new opportunities for the private sector
to compete with the Fed, which will also help to increase efficiency.
We anticipate, and indeed welcome, competition— net only from commercial
banks, but from a variety of private sector suppliers of payments
services.

This competition will provide additional encouragement for

innovation and will help to ensure that payments services are produced
at the lowest possible cost.

As you know, we will begin pricing in January 1981, starting
with our wire transfer and net settlement services.

In April 1981

charges will be levied for check clearing and collection, and for automated
clearinghouse services.

Purchase and sale of securities, safekeeping and

transfer of securities, and non-cash collection will be priced in October
1981.

Pricing is being phased in, rather than introduced all at once, to

facilitate as orderly a transition as possible to the requirements of
the Act,

Float will be handled through a three phase program that I will

discuss shortly.

The only services exempted from pricing are those that fall
into the category of public goods.

These are services that benefit the

public collectively, so that explicit prices would not serve a useful
economic function,
good,

National defense is an often cited example of a public

In the payment area, the storage, issue and retirement of currency

and coin are examples.




- 4 -

Ti.e announcement of proposed prices released i-jcently includes
a discussion of the principles governing the implementation of our fees,
I would like to review these principles with you to provide some insight
into how we designed our fee schedule and how we intend to improve the
efficiency of the payments mechanism through pricing.

The Act and its legislative history give us considerable
direction as to how to implement pricing.

For example, the Act not

only requires that we recover the full cost of providing services, but
also that we include in our costs an allowance for taxes and a profit
markup.

This adjustment factor is designed to put our costs in line

with what they would be if we were a privately owned corporation,

We had

previously estimated an adjustment factor of this kind in November 1978,
when we issued for comment a proposed schedule of prices for Federal
Reserve check and ACH services.

We received very detailed and thought­

ful continents on that schedule from the ASA..

In light of those coments,

we revised our method of calculating this private sector adjustment.

The private sector adjustment now incorporated in our proposed
prices adjusts all our costs upward by 12 percent.

This figure was

obtained by conceiving of our operations as if they were performed by
a large conmercial bank.

The value of the assets to be financed was set

at the historical cost of the assets actually employed by the Federal
Reserve in the production of priced services.

However, it was assumed

that the maturity of our assets and the maturity of liabilities issued




- 5 to finance then are approximately equal— that is, long-tern
assets were assured to be financed with long-term liabilities and short­
term assets with short-term liabilities.

Estimates of the costs of the

liabilities— debt and equity— and the taxes we would incur if we were
a private firm were derived from the actual costs of a sample of large
conraercial banks.

The decision to use a large bank model as the basis for the
private sector adjustment followed a lively debate in the Federal Reserve.
There were some who favored using a public utility model, on the grounds
that the Federal Reserve's operations closely approximate those of a
public utility.

That view did not prevail, but we have not ruled out

altogether the use of a public utility model at some time in the future,
at least for some of our services.

In any case, we expect changes to

be made in die size of the adjustment over time, since it will vary with
changes in taxes and the cost of financing,

Hie Act leaves us free to decide whether prices should be
established on the basis of costs measured at the District or national
level,

We have been guided by efficiency considerations in making that

decision.

For example, it makes sense to use local or District prices

for services where costs differ significantly across Federal Reserve
Districts (or across offices within the District), and where the market
is local in scope.

A nationwide price for such services might make us

the low cost provider in high cost areas and uncompetitive in low cost




- 6 -

areas.

That would contribute to inefficient resource use.

Therefore,

District fees are proposed for coin wrapping, securities and noncash
collection services; for currency and coin shipping services, prices are
set at individual Federal Reserve offices,

Fees for check collection services

may be set at the District or office level, whichever weald better reflect
regional cost differences.

Services that are nationwide in scope will be

priced uniformly across the Federal Reserve System.

Although this general method of differentiating our fees seems
appropriate, we knew that problems will occur that we have not foreseen,
By retaining the flexibility to adjust fee schedules and respond to
information gained from careful monitoring of the markets for these
services, we will attempt to ensure that our fee schedule is working
as intended.

Situations nay arise where institutions desiring direct access
to Federal Reserve services do not maintain a reserve balance with vis,
or one that is too small to permit direct payment for services.

We felt

it appropriate to acccmnodate the needs of such institutions by giving
them two payment options,

They can arrange to have their credits, debits

and charges posted to the account of another institution that is main­
taining an adequate balance and is agreeable to the arrangement;
tively , they can maintain a clearing balance,

alterna­

These clearing balances

would be in addition to any required reserves r and would earn an interest
credit that could be used solely to offset charges for services received^




- 7 The Act requires that we price Federal Reserve float.

Elimina­

tion of float— through operational improvements,changes in availability
schedules, or other ways— is, we believe, consistent with the requirements
of the Act.

We intend to do this in ways that will discourage remote

disbursement and other practices that are economically wasteful from the
standpoint of the nation as a whole.

Moreover, in dealing with float,

we hope to promote increasing use of electronic technology.

To accomplish

these objectives we have announced a three phase program for float as
part of our pricing schedule.

The first phase calls for improvements in Federal Reserve
operations that can be cost justified.

We have no intention of spending

sums on operational improvements that exceed the value of the float
reduction that they would promote.

Rough estimates suggest that a

50 percent reduction in float can be achieved by a less than 10 percent
increase in the costs of check collection.

Our Interdistrict Transporta­

tion System is undergoing improvement already and further steps are
scheduled,

Far more cost-effective improvement can be achieved, we

believe, through the use of teleccmnunications.

We are exploring carefully

the legal and operational problems of electronic check presentment, partic­
ularly for large dollar value checks.

Implementation of electronic check

presentment may prove to be a feasible transition to electronic initiation
of both debit and credit items.

The second phase will begin in September 1981, when availability
schedules will be increased by fractions of days to reflect actual collection




- 8 -

times more accurately.

We expect these changes to amount to no more

than 27o-4% for local items and 6%-107o for inter-District items.

In

order that the link between availability and collection times be strength­
ened, we are exploring the possibility of using wire advice of credit
along with fractional availability,

After phases 1 and 2 have become fully operational, we expect
float to be reduced to negligible levels.

Beginning in the first half

of 1982, an explicit charge will be levied for any remaining float.

The

value of float will be assessed at the prevailing Federal funds rate,
and

the fee probably will be incorporated into the charge for the function

creating the float.

Our program for handling float aims at minimizing real resources
expended, whether by us or the private sector,

As I indicated, in con­

sidering operational improvements we are weighing carefully the potential
reduction in float against the cost of achieving it.

If, however, our

actions pronpted a major unanticipated investment in real resources in
the private sector, we would have to reexamine them to determine whether
a more economical method of float reduction might not be available,

It

is the total benefits and costs of float reduction that matter most, not
just the benefits and costs to the Federal Reserve.

To promote greater efficiency in resources, we also expect to
resort to some forms of incenti^?^rfciii^^For example, after further
.. . ■

-yr.T.>

■

i

**

study we may adopt peak load pricing to ehgfcfurage a more even work load




- 9 over the day— rather than the peak periods we now observe, followed
by slack times when our facilities go underutilized.

Peak load pricing

has been used for some time in other areas in the economy, and could be
beneficial in the payments mechanism.

Also, there are electronic substitutes for paper checks that
have been promoted by the Federal Reserve, with sane success, that might
be encouraged by incentive pricing.

For example, we have made substantial

commitments to the ACH program because it has the potential to reduce
operating costs for the Federal Reserve, the financial industry and
the public.

It also offers the consumer a more reliable and efficient

method of making and receiving payments.

For these reasons, automated

clearinghouse services will be priced from the beginning as if we had
already attained a mature volume.

A complement to ACH is the greater use of electronic delivery,
Currently, most ACH payments depend on messenger and courier services
for delivery from the ACH to financial institutions.

Using messenger

and courier services to deliver electronic payments detracts from many
of the operational and cost advantages that ACH. offers.

As a consequence,

ACH funds availability schedules are generally no better than for paper
checks.

Courier delivery of ACH payments is also more costly than

electronic delivery and more susceptible to transportation delays.

A

preferable delivery method depends on electronic terminals being used
to transmit ACH payments items.

Incentive pricing is now under con­

sideration as a potentially useful way of encouraging the development of
t ' P T T r n ' n ' 1 ^ <■




- 10 -

Let me turn new to some concerns that some of us in the Federal
Reserve have about how the payments system might evolve under the new
arrangements.

Explicit pricing for services will, I have argued, promote

a more efficient use of resource in the payments mechanism.

It is also

true, however, that competitive markets probably lead to a larger use of
real resources in collecting checks than is socially desirable.

That is

true because payors and their banks can realize profits by using real
resources to slow down the collection process, while payees and their
banks benefit by vising real resources to speed it up.

A substantial part

of the resources so utilized may be contributing nothing of value for
the nation as a whole,

Social waste of this kind could become worse in a system in
which the Federal Reserve and the private sector compete actively
to obtain, or maintain, an operational presence in the payments mechanism,
For example, what if competition led to a duplication of the Federal
Reserve's transportation network by the private sector?

One could hardly

argue that society would benefit from this type of competition.

We firmly believe that if private financial institutions can
produce and sell payments services competitively more cheaply than the
Federal Reserve, the nation may well be better served if they do so.
But suppose that competition resulted in less profitable markets being
subjected to vastly higher charges for payments services than more
profitable areas.




Such an outcome might occur: if private competitors

-11 were able to chip away the lower cost, higher profit, areas, leaving
the Federal Reserve to service remote locations with high transportation
costs.

The prices we would have to charge to cover oar higher average

cost per item might rise to levels that are socially and politically
unacceptable,

Such a situation would almost certainly attract Congressional

attention and give rise

to calls for corrective action.

I do not raise these concerns because I am pessimistic about
the results of pricing for our services--quite the contrary,

I merely

want to underscore that we are breaking new and unfamiliar ground, and
we cannot be entirely sure what lies beneath.

Historically, the Federal

Reserve has played a large role in the operation of the payments mechanism.
That role may expand or contract.

We are entirely prepared to see it

contract as long as the nation is provided with an adequate level of
services

at reasonable cost

and at competitive prices,

Any other out­

come, however, would not be acceptable to us, to the Congress, or to the
public at large,

I am confident that the new arrangements mandated by the Monetary
Control Act of 1980 will be of substantial long-run benefit to the payments
mechanism and to our nation's economy,

ifeny of you in the private sector,

I am sure, are anxious for the opportunity to cocpete
welcome your rivalry.

We intend to give you a tough, but fair, battle!

May the best and most efficient win.




with the Fed,

We