View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
THURSDAY

JULY 17, 1980

11:30 A.M.M.D.T.
(1:30 P.M. E.D.T.)

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

Remarks by

Lyle E . Gramley

Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




July 17, 1980

Denver, Colorado

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

One of the assignments I have taken on as a new Board
Member is to chair the Committee on Federal Reserve Bank Activities.
During the next few months I will be visiting each of the Reserve
Banks, and some of their branches, meeting as many of the officers
and directors of our regional banks as possible.

This visit to

the Tenth Federal Reserve District is the first such trip.

It seems

to me eminently proper that I should begin here, since my career at
the Fed was launched at the federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

This is one of my first public appearances since joining
the Board.

I would like, therefore, to take this opportunity to

set forth briefly what I believe the Federal Reserve can and should
do about the principal economic problem facing our country today-the problem of inflation.

Dealing with so complex a topic in a

short span requires one to be more assertive than analytical, and more
provocative than profound.
that spirit.




Hopefully, you will take my remarks in

-

2-

There are three basic points I want to make.

The first

is that the ability to use monetary policy as a short-term counter­
cyclical tool is severely limited under present circumstances.

The

principal focus of Federal Reserve policy must be on the long-term
goal of reducing inflation.

Second, pursuit of such a course of

policy does not mean mechanical adherence to predetermined growth
rates of the monetary aggregates.

Third, even under the best of

circumstances, reliance on monetary policy alone to bring inflation
down will yield extremely disappointing results.

Our long-term

inflation problem might not improve, and could worsen, unless a wide
range of governmental policies are aimed at reducing inflation as our
nation's top economic priority.

Five years ago, our country began to recover from the
1974-75 recession.

At that time, the underlying, or hard-core,

inflation rate was about 6 percent.

By the underlying inflation

rate, I mean the long-term trend rate of increase in unit costs of
production, or in the broad range of industrial and service prices-that is, prices excluding food and energy.

Over periods of several

years, these measures closely follow one another.

Sometime around the beginning of next year, our economy
will begin to recover from the recession of 1980.

That recovery

will begin with an underlying inflation rate probably in a range of
9 to 10 percent.




-

3-

We would all agree, I am sure, that another round of
acceleration in the underlying inflation rate during the next
economic expansion would be simply disastrous--not only for our
economy, but also for our social and political institutions.

But

what can be done to prevent it?

We must not be timid in setting our goals for inflation.
It would be a mistake to take as our goal merely the prevention of
any further increase in the underlying inflation rate.

If we tell

the public that inflation rates above 10 percent are unacceptable,
but that anything less is satisfactory, businesses and consumers may
well begin to borrow and spend in ways that make a higher rate of
inflation virtually inevitable.

Our goal must be much tougher .

it must be to bring the

underlying inflation rate down even as the economy moves from
recession to higher levels of economic activity.

This is a very ambitious goal.

During each and every

economic recovery during the postwar period, the underlying inflation
rate has always risen.

Moreover, with the passage of time,

inflationary expectations have worsened substantially;

mechanisms

to index wages, social security benefits and other income payments to
prices have become more widespread;




shocks to prices from the food

and energy sectors have become more common, and for other reasons,
also, the inflationary bias in the U.S. economy has increased.
Nonetheless, despite these difficulties, history during the forth­
coming economic recovery must be stood on its head.

The hard core

inflation rate must be brought down.

To have any hope of accomplishing that objective, monetary
policy must be conducted in ways that are different from the pattern
of the past quarter century.

Throughout most of that period, the

Federal Reserve's principal monetary policy objective was to be a
countercyclical balance wheel--to "lean against the wind," as Chairman
Martin used to say.

That meant using the tools of monetary policy

fairly actively to combat recessionary tendencies when they appeared
and to restrain the economy when the degree of slack in labor and
product markets diminished to a point where pressures on wage and
prices began to threaten.

In an economy in which wages and prices are relatively
flexible in both directions, as was the case earlier in the postwar
period, that kind of monetary policy can contribute a good deal to
economic stability without adding to long-run inflation.
policy is too easy for awhile

an<^

If monetary

inflation rate jumps up a

little, a corresponding period of tight money can bring it down again.




-

5-

That is not the kind of economy we live in now, however.
Since the early years of the 1960's, each recession has had less
effect of reducing inflation than the previous expansion had in
increasing it.

The result has been a steady rise in the long-term

trend of wages and prices.

The principal reason for this is the fact that wage rate
increases have become increasingly less responsive to rising unemploy­
ment.

xn the recession of 1948-49, for example, average wage rates

stopped rising altogether when slack in labor markets increased.
This year, despite rising unemployment, the rise of average wage rates
has not moderated.

On the contrary, average wage rates so far in

1980 have been rising about 1 to 1-1/2 percentage points faster than
they did in 1979.

Moreover, there is relatively little reason for

expecting any reduction in the rise of wage rates in the near future.
The degree of slack in labor markets does have some effect on the
rise of wages, but it takes a painfully long time to work.

In today's economy, any fresh impetus to inflation--whether
it comes from rising OPEC prices, a food shortage, a productivity
disaster, or a mistake in economic policy--tends to worsen the long­
term trend of inflation.
cyclical device,

Using monetary policy actively as a counter­

in the way we once did, is extremely risky because

mistakes are inevitable, and they tend to aggravate the long-term
inflation problem.




This does not mean that the dials of monetary

-

6-

policy should be set on automatic pilot.

It does mean, however,

that to have any real hope of ultimately regaining price stability,
the principal focus of monetary policy now must at all times be to
find and pursue the course of action most likely to bring down the
long-term rate of inflation.

The differences in developments affecting financial markets
and the real economy that stem from such a course of policy will
probably be less evident during periods of recession than during the
early phases of economic recovery.

Historically, monetary policy

has not moved dramatically toward stimulus when the economy headed
into recession.

Simply holding to a fairly steady course of policy

has resulted in substantial declines in interest rates because of
weakening credit demands.

But during the earlier phase of economic

recoveries, growth in supplies of money and credit has often begun to
accelerate because the Federal Reserve did not let credit markets
tighten sufficiently while unemployment and excess capacity were still
relatively high.

That is the mistake we must be particularly care­

ful to avoid when the current recession bottoms out and recovery
begins again.




-

7-

Implementing the kind of monetary policy I am espousing
will mean, as a general principle , paying more attention to achieving
stable growth rates of money and credit than historically has been
the case, and permitting interest rates to move sooner, and through
wider swings,

in response to changes in credit demands.

you will recognize,
monetarism.

That, as

is the basic postulate of the doctrine of

Mechanical application of that principle, however,

could lead to fundamental errors.

The monetarist doctrine is based on the premise that the
demand for money is stable and predictable.

When that premise holds

true, changes in the stock of money exclusively reflect developments
on the supply side, that is developments basically controlled by the
Federal Reserve.

When it does not hold true, however, changes in

the stock of money reflect influences from both demand and supply.
Money growth is then no longer a reliable guide to monetary policy.

Instead of discussing these issues in the abstract, let
me give you a concrete example.

During the second half of last

year, the narrowly-defined money stock, M-lA,rose at an annual rate
of 6-1/4 percent.

From the fourth quarter of 1979 through the

second quarter of this year, however, growth in this measure of
money fell to an annual rate of only 1/2 percent.

Some monetarists

believe that the Federal Reserve has engaged in massive restraint
because growth of M-1A has declined so sharply--restraint that poses
the threat of a prolonged and deep recession.




-

8-

However, there is evidence, and it is in my judgment
persuasive, that a sharp reduction occurred in the public's
demand for money during the second quarter of 1980--a reduction
that cannot be explained by the weakness in economic activity.
Estimates by the Federal Reserve Board staff suggest that the
reduction in money demand, given income and interest ratesf during
the second quarter was on the order of 3 to 3-1/2 percent of the
money stock.

Put into practical terms, this means that the 1/2 percent
annual rate of increase in the actual money stock from the fourth
quarter of 1979 to the second quarter of 1980 had the same effect on
interest rates--and ultimately on economic activity and prices--as
a 6-1/2 to 7 percent rate of increase in money over the same period
would have had with a stable money demand function.
cautious monetary authority cannot, I believe,

A prudent and

ignore facts of that

ki n d .

This example is by no means an isolated incident.
Beginning around the middle of 1974, the demand for money (M-1A)
at given levels of income and interest rates began to decline
sharply, according to Board staff estimates, and continued to fall
until around the middle of 1977.

During those three years, actual

money growth proceeded at an annual rate of about 5-1/2 percent.




But

-

9-

the effective growth of money, taking into account the downward
shift in money demand, amounted to around 9 percent at an annual
rate.

Problems of interpreting money growth will continue to
plague us.

Next year interpreting changes in the various measures

of money commonly in use will be greatly complicated by large-scale
entrance of thrift institutions into the checking account business.
Growth of M-1A, which excludes NOW accounts and ATS deposits, will be
depressed, while growth of M-1B, which includes these accounts, will
be accelerated.

Efforts will be made to determine the extent to

which demands for those two measures of money will be influenced by
the growth of NOW accounts;
at best be very rough.

these estimates, however, will

Furthermore, we may have to live with

considerable uncertainty regarding the meaning of changes in these
measures of money for some time.

Mechanical interpretations of

money growth in the current environment simply will not do.

Let me turn now to my final point--namely, that monetary
policy alone cannot cope effectively with the kind of inflation that
is plaguing the U.S. economy and the industrialized economies of the
Western World.

A prudent monetary policy is a necessary condition

for ending inflation.




It is not, however, a sufficient condition.

-

10 -

Let me give you a few facts from recent history.

In

1977, consumer prices in our country rose about 6-3/4
percent.

Two years later, the rise was up to almost 13 percent.

What happened to money growth during this period?

In fact, it

decelerated --M-1A rose 7-3/4 percent in 1977, 7-1/2 percent in 1978,
and 5 percent in 1979.

Growth of money and prices were not closely

correlated during that period.
as its monetary roots.

Inflation has its nonmonetary as well

In periods of several years, or even longer,

those nonmonetary forces may predominate.

Almost everyone would agree, I imagine,

that the chances

of reducing inflation by restraining the growth of money and credit
would be greatly diminished if at the same time Federal budgetary
policy were highly stimulative.

It is also true that the effects of

monetary restraint on inflation may

be disappointingly small if

OPEC is able to increase its prices for oil at will,
if productivity declines because of inadequate investment, or if a
variety of governmental policies seeking to achieve important economic
or social goals do so by raising costs and prices.

Our best hope to turning history around, and bringing the
underlying inflation rate down during the next economic expansion,
lies in putting the fight against inflation at the forefront of every
governmental economic policy decision.
needs to be done is long and difficult.




The list of things that
Let me name just a few.

-

11 -

First, a major objective of Federal budgetary policy
over the next five to ten years should be to raise sharply the
rate of business investment in new and modern plant and equipment
in order to increase supply capabilities and to raise productivity
growth.

That will require both substantial business tax incentives

and greatly increased national savings to finance the needed invest­
ment.

Greater national savings will be difficult to achieve without

more or less continuing surpluses in the Federal budget.

Both

objectives together will not be realized unless far more effective
policies are pursued to restrain growth of Federal spending.

Second,

policies to decrease our dependence on foreign sources of oil need to
be accelerated.

We have made great strides in this area in the past

several years, but more needs to be done.

Third, a substantial

overhaul of the financing of social security benefits is needed to
reduce sharply the reliance on payroll taxes, which add to business
costs and prices.

Fourth, substantial further steps must be taken

to reduce the effects on costs and prices of governmental regulatory
policies--especially policies relating to the environment and to
the safety of the workplace.

Fifth, a wide range of policies or

laws designed to provide income maintenance for particular elements
of the economy--such as import restrictions, dairy price supports,
the minimum wage, the Davis-Bacon and Service Contract Acts--badly
needed to be altered or eliminated altogether to reduce pressures
on prices.




-

12 -

If we as a nation did all of these things, and if at
the same time the Federal Reserve pursued a steady anti-inflationary
course of monetary policy, we could regain price stability during
the next decade.

Perhaps it would be unrealistic to expect a full

measure of success in defeating inflation during the 1980s.

We

must not fail, however, to take the first essential step--and that
is to make some progress in reducing inflation during the next
economic expansion.

That is the objective to which Federal Reserve

policy is strongly committed, and it is the objective on which I will
be expending a large part of my energy.




#######