View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 A.M. G.D.T. (11:00 A.M. E.D.T.)
June 14, 1984




Our Internal and External Deficits And
____ The Relationship Between Them_____

Remarks by

Lyle E. Gramley
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at a meeting of

The Twin Cities Business Community

Minneapolis, Minnesota
June 14, 1984

Our Internal and External Deficits And
The Relationship Between Them_____

During the first quarter of 1984,

the balance

between our receipts and expenditures on merchandise trade '
with other countries registered a deficit of over $100
billion at an annual rate.

In April,

that external deficit

increased substantially further.

During the first five months of 1984, the Treasury
borrowed $74 billion, on its way to financing a gap between
Federal receipts and expenditures--bot.h on and off budget-that will probably total about $195 billion during this
calendar year.

I would like to talk with you briefly today about
our internal deficit--that is, the deficit in the Federal
budget--and our external deficits--the deficits on merchandise
trade and current account--and the relationship between them.
Five years ago, I would not have dreamed of making such a talk
here today, and you would probably not have wasted your time
listening.

But the issues at stake are vital to the health

of individual industries,

to the stability of financial markets

to the ability of developing countries struggling to make
progress in managing debt problems of enormous magnitude, and
to the economic welfare of people throughout our nation and
around the western world.



-

2

-

Deficits in the Federal budget, and in our
merchandise trade and current accounts, are not, per s e ,
unmitigated evils.

For example,

the fiscal stimulus of

rising Federal deficits has made an important contribution
to the strong economic recovery that we have enjoyed since
late 1982.

Similarly,

the rapid rise in U.S. imports has

helped fuel recovery abroad and has enhanced the export
earnings capacity of developing countries.

The availability

of imports from other countries at relatively low prices,
moreover, has been one of the factors holding down inflation
in the U.S.

And the counterpart of large current account

deficits has been a sizable inflow of foreign capital that has
facilitated the financing of large Federal budget deficits
at lower interest rates than would otherwise have prevailed.

But our internal and external deficits are a bit
like doses of medication.

One sleeping pill may be the key

to a good night's sleep when you need it.

But ten sleeping

pills will not produce a night's sleep that is ten times
better.

Our internal and external deficits have risen, in

my judgment,

to levels much larger than what any sensible

economic doctor would prescribe.







-

3

-

In discussing these issues with you today,

let

me caution you that I will be giving you my own personal
opinions, not those of the Federal Reserve Board.

Let me begin with the external side.

Over the past several years,

deficits in our

merchandise trade and current accounts have risen to
proportions

that are astonishing by historical standards.

During the thirty years ended in 1980, the U.S. current
account, on average,

showed a small surplus--amounting to

about one quarter of one percent of G N P .

Current account

deficits, when they occurred, never exceeded one percent of
GNP in any year during those three decades.

Our external balances began to deteriorate early
in 1981.

By the first quarter of this year, the deficit

on current account was up to about $85 billion, or 2-1/4
percent of GNP, and will very likely increase significantly
further in the period immediately ahead.




A large part of this deterioration stemmed from
the tremendous increase in imports during the current
economic recovery.

Since the fourth quarter of 1982,

merchandise imports in real terms have risen more than five
times as fast as real GNP.

Weakness in the demand for U.S.

exports has also been a factor.

The volume of exports did

begin rising last year, after a prolonged decline, but the
level in the first quarter of 1984 was still about 15 percent
below the peak volume of 1980.

What accounts for these extraordinary developments?
The reasons are many and varied, and I will mention only the
main ones.

First,

there is the contribution of troubled

industries--particular industries that, over time and for a
variety of reasons, became less competitive in international
markets.

Steel is one example.

Second, our domestic economy has grown more strongly
than the economies of foreign countries, especially since late
1982.

Part of the increase in our external deficit is thus

a normal cyclical development that will be reversed as activity
picks up abroad and the pace of expansion slows at home.

-

Third,

5-

the internal adjustment programs put in

place by countries such as Mexico and Brazil to deal with
their external debt problems have had a significant effect
on our trade and current account positions.

For example,

our exports to Mexico last year were $9 billion, or 50
percent, below their 1981 level, although very recently our
exports to Mexico.have turned up again.

Fourth, and most important, our competitive position
in world markets has worsened dramatically because of the rise
in the international value of the dollar during the past four
years.

Adjusted for rates of inflation at home and abroad,

the dollar has risen in value in relation to other major
currencies by roughly 50 percent
19S0.

since the fourth quarter of

More than half of the deterioration in our current

account balance since that time is probably due to the resulting
loss of price competitiveness.

Restoration of our competitive position is, obviously,
essential to obtaining a reasonable balance in our external
accounts.

Barring a marked acceleration of inflation abroad

relative to the U.S., a substantial improvement in inter­
national competitiveness will require a rather pronounced
decline in the value of the dollar in exchange markets.
dollar is, in this sense, overvalued.




The

-

6

-

Why has the dollar's value gone up so much?
Again,

there is no simple answer, but a dominant factor

has probably been the rise in U.S.
to those abroad.

interest rates relative

During the past five years,

interest

rates in the U . S .--adjusted for inflation--have risen about
six percentage points relative to those of other major
industrialized countries.

The U.S.

is, of course, a country

with a long history of political stability, and its money and
capital markets are free and open.

Moreover, the dollar

serves as both the medium of exchange for international trade
and payments, and the key reserve currency around the world.
These institutional factors mean that the demand for dollar
assets is quite sensitive to U.S.

interest rates, so that a

rise in our rates relative to those abroad pushes the exchange
value of the dollar strongly upward.

An extremely strong dollar creates problems for
industries that compete in international markets,
ones.

For industries beset with serious problems arising

from other sources,

the loss of price competitiveness in

international markets is even more serious.




even healthy

-

7-

Problems are created abroad as well as at
home.

Countries whose exchange rates have declined

sharply with respect to the dollar have had to cope with
the resulting increase in inflationary pressures.

And

when the U.S. is importing capital from abroad on so large
a scale, developing countries in need of significant amounts
of international capital to achieve their economic and social
objectives become deeply concerned.

Perhaps those that are disadvantaged by an over­
valued dollar and large external deficits should take comfort
in the fact that the present situation cannot last indefinitely.
Dollar assets are accumulating in the portfolios of non­
residents on an unprecedented scale.
has not happened already,

Some time soon, if it

the U.S. will switch from its long­

standing position as an international creditor to that of a
debtor country.

(Available data do not permit a precise

pinpointing of when that will happen.)

Within a couple of

years thereafter--unless external deficits decline--the U.S.
will become the world's largest debtor country.




-

8

-

It is hardly surprising,

then, that a significant

decline in the value of the dollar in exchange markets is
widely forecast.

Such a decline is clearly essential to

restoration of international competitiveness to U.S.
industry, and in that sense it would be welcome.
it occurs,

But when

it will have two effects that will be most

unwelcome--namely, it will add to our inflation rate, and
it will put upward pressure on our interest rates.

Interest rates are already extremely high in the
U.S. by historical standards.

They have been rising

strongly since late last year as a consequence of burgeoning
overall demands for credit.

Earlier in the recovery,

the

financing of an enormous Federal deficit was accomplished
with relative ease--partly because of large capital inflows
from abroad, but also because private domestic credit demands
were still weak.

With the passage of time, however,

borrowing by the private non-financial sectors became
progressively larger.

By the first quarter of this year, the

flow of such credit, combined with Federal borrowing, amounted
to 18-1/4 percent of GNP, the highest ratio ever
recorded.




-

9-

Do Federal deficits really matter?

Both

traditional economic theory and common sense suggest that
they do--that increases in government spending, or reductions
in taxes,

tend to stimulate the economy,

raise total credit

demands relative to supplies, and push up interest rates.

But if any doubt remained, developments in financial
markets this year should have laid the argument to rest.

The

damaging effects of greatly excessive fiscal stimulus on our
external balances, on interest rates, and on the stability of
domestic and international financial markets have become
abundantly obvious in recent weeks and months.

Our fiscal

chickens have begun coming home to roost.

I am not going to speculate on whether or not interest
rates have reached their cyclical peak for the current period
of expansion.

Certainly, all of us hope that they have.

But

we may have to face the unhappy fact that real interest rates
in the U.S.--on average,

in good times and bad--could remain

high in relation to historical levels, and high in relation to
those of other countries, unless we take dramatic steps to
reduce the competition between public and private demands for
credit.




-

10

-

The reason for this is that the United States
has money and capital markets in which there are fewer
barriers to the flows of money and credit than any other
country in the world.

Over the past three decades, and

especially over the past five to ten years, innovation and
deregulation of U.S. financial markets have increased the
mobility of funds from one region of the country to another
and from one market to another.

Nearly all of the legis­

lative and regulatory impediments to payment of marketrelated rates of interest to savers have been removed.
most importantly,

And,

the usury ceilings and other artificial

barriers to credit flows that used to play so prominent a role
in the rationing of available supplies of credit among potential
borrowers have largely disappeared.
we live in now,

therefore,

In the financial world

the rationing of credit is done

almost entirely by real interest rates.

As a consequence,

real interest rates in a period of economic expansion are
forced to much higher levels than we were accustomed to seeing
in the 1960s and the 1970s.

There is a way for economic policies in our country
to compensate for this tendency of our financial markets to
generate high real interest rates.

It is to adopt Federal

budgetary policies that minimize the conflict between Federal







-

11

-

and private credit demands.

We need to aim, on average

over the business cycle, at a balanced Federal budget,
or even moderate surpluses.

Instead, what we have done

is to adopt fiscal policies in recent years that have
produced large and growing structural deficits.

Since fiscal 1981,

the structural deficit in the

Federal budget--that is, the deficit adjusted for cyclical
changes in Federal receipts and expenditures--has increased
by approximately $100 billion.

The effects of this magnitude

of fiscal stimulus on the economy and on interest rates are
hard

to estimate precisely.

Some econometric models suggest

that, assuming a given stock of money, an increase of fiscal
stimulus of this magnitude would raise short-term
interest rates by two percentage points or more.

And,

unfortunately, rising fiscal stimulus will continue under
current law.

Indeed, estimates by the Congressional Budget

Office indicate an increase in the structural deficit of
almost $200 billion more between now and fiscal 1989, unless
specific steps are taken to lower Federal expenditures or
raise taxes.




We need prompt and forceful action to deal with
this problem.

We need it for farmers in Minnesota and

Iowa, for banks from New York to California,

for home

builders and thrift institutions across the nation, and
for our friends in Latin America and elsewhere.

I am quite hopeful that a "downpayment" on
deficit reduction will be accomplished yet this year.
A serious process of political negotiation does seem to
be underway.

I am concerned, however,

that the amounts

of deficit reduction currently being discussed for the
near term are so small relative to the size of the problem.
Under current law, the structural deficit will increase by
about $25 billion in fiscal 1985.

The two bills before the

Congress provide for deficit-reducing measures of between
$25 to $30 billion in the upcoming year--that is, about
enough to keep the problem from getting worse.

Thus, unless

the Senate-House conferees adopt stronger measures of deficit
reduction for fiscal 1985, the near-term effects of the fiscal
"downpayment" on the economy and on financial markets are
likely to be quite small.

-

13

-

These large internal and external deficits
that I have been discussing with you today pose a
serious threat to the sustainability of the current
economic recovery.

The main concern is not that high

interest rates will,

in and of themselves,

slow the

growth of demands in interest-sensitive sectors and
thereby plunge the economy into recession.
could happen,

it is unlikely.

While that

The principal danger is

that particular industries will be so severely damaged,
that financial markets will become so shaky, that
confidence will be so seriously eroded as to precipitate
events that economic policies cannot effectively control.

There is also a danger that, in such an environ­
ment, we will succumb to the temptation to adopt policies
that, in the long run, we will come to regret.

Proposals

for industrial policies will be treated more sympathetically;
so also will calls for more protectionism.
for individual industries will proliferate.

Bail-out plans
Most worrisome

of all is the likelihood that pressures will increase for
the Federal Reserve to "do something" to bring down interest
rates.




-

14

-

Attempts to lower interest rates by speeding
up the growth of money and credit would, under present
circumstances, be a serious mistake.

The economy is

growing strongly;

total credit demands are extremely

large;

although not yet accelerating,

inflation,

is still

proceeding at an annual rate of four to five percent.

If

people here and abroad gained the impression that the Federal
Reserve had thrown in the towel in the fight against inflation,
we would be faced,

in my judgment, with potentially chaotic

conditions in financial markets.

We in the Federal Reserve have no intention of
succumbing to any pressures of that kind.

The best

contribution we can make to prolonging the recovery is to
continue to follow a disciplined money policy--providing
sufficient growth in money and credit to finance a sustainable
economic expansion, but avoiding the excesses that \7 0 uld
lead to a resurgence of greater inflationary pressures.

To increase the chances of prolonging the recovery,
however,

discipline must be brought to bear on Federal

budgetary policies.

Reduced fiscal stimulus is the single

most important step that could be taken to reduce interest
rates,




to encourage a gradual decline in the value of the

-

15

-

dollar and thus to improve the competitiveness of American
industry in international markets,

to calm domestic and

international financial markets, and in all of those ways
to increase the durability of the economic recovery.

Our economic problems are not insurmountable.
But we must find the political will to come to grips with
them while there is still time to do so.




############