View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE NEED FOR CLEAR THINKING
IN DEALING WITH INFLATION

Address by
Lawrence K. Roos
President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
Traffic Club of St. Louis
Stouffer's Riverfront Inn
April 15, 1980

It is a real pleasure to be with you this evening and to discuss some of the issues
currently facing the economy.

As we meet in the good fellowship of another Traffic Club annual dinner, it would
be difficult to characterize the present state of the economy in glowing terms. Inflation
is raging at double-digit levels. Interest rates are at an all-time high with the prime rate at
20%.

Financial markets are in a turmoil with triple-A rated bonds trading at deep dis-

counts and the Dow Jones averages significantly below levels of recent months. While
economic activity continues to show strength in some sectors, vital industries such as
residential construction and automobiles are in severe slumps.

Most Americans agree that inflation is our most pressing domestic problem, and
there is an almost universal determination to "do something" about it.

In choosing

policy options for remedial action, it is essential that we separate fact from fiction and
truth from fantasy as self-delusion complicates, rather than facilitates, our ability to act
effectively.

With this in mind, I shall direct these remarks toward debunking some

prevalent economic misconceptions which stand in the way of effective action against
inflation. Among the topics I will discuss are:

(1) Misconceptions about the real causes of the inflation we are experiencing,

(2) A mistaken belief that the Federal Reserve is responsible for our present
high interest rates,

(3) The suggestion that the imposition of economic controls offers an effective
way to curb inflation, and

(4) The wishful thought that somehow we can cure inflation in a painless
manner without our suffering temporary economic distress in the process.

I would like to consider each of these misconceptions separately.

First,


as to the causes of inflation.

It is obvious that, just as a doctor cannot effectively treat an illness without identifying its probable causes, neither can policymakers effectively deal with a problem as complex as inflation without understanding what brings it about. A serious obstacle to our
ability to come to grips with inflation is the confusion which exists over what really
causes it.

One day we are told that inflation is the result of the decisions of greedy

businessmen arbitrarily to increase the price of goods and services they create. In the
next breath, we are told that the real culprit is exorbitant wage demands by powerhungry labor.

I recently heard a congressional critic of the Federal Reserve System

charge that inflation is caused by high interest rates which add to the costs of production.
High wages, high prices and high interest rates are the results of inflation, not its causes.

There are those who, in an attempt to explain away the inflationary effects of past
monetary and fiscal policy errors, would like us to believe that our present inflation is
largely the result of OPEC-inspired increases in the price of energy. This simply is not
true. Energy price increases do contribute in a small and passing way to inflation. But
in no way are they responsible for the bulk of the problem. Assuming that inflation, as
measured by the GNP price deflator, is currently approximately 10%, the portion of that
10% that is directly attributable to energy price increases is less than 3%. A t least threequarters of our present inflation is the direct result of excessive money growth. To put
it somewhat differently, had there been no oil shocks, we would still be experiencing an
inflation rate of 7%, as measured by the GNP deflator, or 11% as measured by the consumer price index, due solely to the fact that over the past several years money growth
has averaged 7%.

The effects of higher energy prices and similar extraneous factors

account for only a small part of our present inflation.

The fundamental rate of inflation is determined by one basic factor, the rate at
which the money supply is permitted to grow. By money supply, I mean assets that can
be easily exchanged for goods and services.

Persistent increases in the money supply

cause inflation to accelerate; persistent reductions in the rate of growth of the money



supply cause the level of prices to decline.

The Federal Reserve, through purchases and sales of securities on the open market,
has direct control over the rate of growth of the money supply. Our present high rate of
inflation is a consequence of excessive monetary expansion over the past fifteen years. In
the 1940s and 1950s when money grew at a rate consistent with the growth of productivity, inflation was virtually nonexistent.

It was only after the mid-1960s, when the

Johnson Administration adopted a "guns and butter" policy and the Federal Reserve
accommodated deficit spending by expanding the money supply, that inflation became
the serious problem that it is.

Last October, the Federal Reserve officially adopted a policy of gradually reducing
the growth of the money supply and thus took a giant step forward in coping with
inflation.

If we are truly concerned with inflation and desirous of combating it in

the most effective

manner,

it is essential that we give our full support to the new

policy.

A second common misconception that surfaces too often these days is the charge
that Fed policy is responsible for having pushed interest rates to their present high levels.
It is true that, since October 1979, when the Fed announced its new measures to control
the growth of the money stock, the prime rate has risen from 13.5% to 20%, with the
bulk of the increase . . , 4.75% . . . occurring since the end of February. I submit that the
Fed had very little to do with these increases.

Interest rates are prices of credit and, like all other prices, are determined by the
demand and supply of credit.

Demand for credit is the sum of all borrowing in our

society, by individuals, businesses and governments. The supply of credit is provided by
savers in our economy and by the Fed. The Fed supplies credit through its open market
operations. When the Fed buys securities in the open market, it creates additional bank
reserves.

expand


The banking system uses these new reserves to make loans which, in turn,

credit and money. When the Fed wants to reduce reserves, it sells securities in the

open market. The Fed can cause a temporary increase in interest rates only by dramatically restricting the growth of bank reserves, and this has not been the case in recent
months. If we compare the growth of bank reserves for the six months preceding October
with the growth from October to February, we find that the Fed was supplying reserves
at a rate of 260 million dollars per week before October and 220 million dollars per week
since October. A decrease of only 15% cannot, by any stretch of the imagination, account
for the sharp increase in the prime rate.

But if we look at what has happened to credit demand, we find that it has been growing by leaps and bounds. Prior to October, short-term and intermediate credit rose at an
average rate of 1.4 billion dollars per week. Since October, it increased by 2.7 billion
dollars per week, a whopping increase of 93%. And during January and February, the
period which accounts for the steepest increase in the prime rate, credit grew at 3.7 billion
dollars per week, a 164% increase over the level of pre-October growth. Clearly, it was
not any restrictive policy of the Fed, but rather an enormous appetite for borrowing that
brought about the sharp increases in the prime rate. I should note parenthetically that
47% of the borrowing since October was by the U. S. Treasury and other government
agencies.

Another misconception is that the Fed causes interest rates to rise when it increases
the discount rate. Whenever a discount rate increase occurs, the 6 o'clock news can be
expected to announce, "The Fed raised interest rates again t o d a y / ' Let's examine what
really happens.

Member banks borrow from the Federal Reserve from time to time in

order to obtain reserves they need to support some of their loans to their customers. The
rate the Fed charges for such loans is known as the discount rate. Actually, loans of this
sort by member banks are insignificant when compared to the total lending by banks.
Total member bank borrowings through the discount window are currently only 2.5
billion dollars compared to total commercial credit of about 450 billion dollars. Thus,
increases or decreases in the discount rate affect only a small segment of total funds used

for bank


lending.

In general, the idea that the Fed can set interest rates at any level it desires, or even
raise or lower them at will, is fallacious. The only real effect the Fed can exert on rates is
by expanding or contracting the supply of credit. In times of strong credit demand such
as we have recently experienced, if the Fed expands bank reserves by creating more
money, in order to keep interest rates from rising, the inflationary implications of such
expansionary actions are readily recognized by financial markets, and interest rates will
continue to rise in expectation of further inflation. The same thing, but in the opposite
direction, results from a restriction in the supply of credit by the Fed. A restriction first
raises interest rates, but it also reduces the growth of money. When inflationary anticipations fall, so do interest rates.

A third misleading concept which arises in times of inflation is the belief that
controls of one sort or another offer an effective method of dealing with inflation.

Controls, guidelines, q u o t a s . . . call them what you will

only serve to redistribute

the burden of inflation across the economy. Controls only dam up the flow of the economy, causing it either to seek other channels . . . such as black markets or similar avenues
. . . or simply to gather momentum for a new burst of inflation once controls are lifted
and the floodgates opened. They have the effect of a pressure cooker. When the lid is
removed, the pent-up pressure explodes. To illustrate, in the period immediately prior to
1943 when wartime controls were imposed, consumer prices were rising at a 6.1% annual
rate. The year after controls were lifted, prices zoomed upward 14.4%. In 1961, before
guidelines were introduced, prices were increasing 1.1%, a figure the economy could live
with.

In 1967, after the guidelines had failed, prices more than doubled their earlier

growth rate. In this decade, the same thing happened. Prices rose 4.3% in 1970 before
the Nixon controls were imposed. They shot up 9 . 1 % after controls were lifted. Controls have never been an effective weapon against inflation. There is no reason to believe
they would serve a meaningful purpose today.

Finally, there is the erroneous belief that we can somehow break the back of inflation




in a painless manner. Currently, we are seeing an emerging pattern of resistance to the
Fed's anti-inflation measures on the part of various interest groups who find themselves
economically or socially inconvenienced by what we are attempting to do. Hardly a day
passes when someone, be it a farmer, a builder, an automobile dealer, a beneficiary of a
publicly-funded social welfare program or other affected [individual, does not petition
the Federal Reserve for exemption from the anti-inflation program.

Inevitably, each

group concedes that inflation must be dealt with, but each feels that the burden of sacrifice
should be borne by others.

I recognize that it is a natural human impulse to try to protect one's own turf, and
most people can rationalize why they particularly should be excluded from the inconvenience of the anti-inflation effort. On the other hand, there is simply no way to break
the momentum of an inflation which is the result of nearly two decades of economic selfindulgence without each of us enduring a certain part of the withdrawal pain. We simply
can't expect to withdraw from a 15-year economic binge and not suffer a hangover!

The inflation we are experiencing, if allowed to continue, poses a deadly threat, not
only to our economic well-being, but to the survival of the political and social institutions
which have made out Nation great. The surest way to destroy a democracy is to tolerate
runaway inflation.

The inflation in Germany after World War I led to Hitler.

Hyper-

inflation in South American countries has led to the establishment of numerous military
dictatorships. If we are unwilling to tolerate the temporary discomfort of higher interest
rates and perhaps some softening of economic activity as inevitable side-effects of what is
necessary to eliminate inflation, we cannot expect to avoid the fate of other countries
which have not faced up to the seriousness of the problem.

I have confidence in the wisdom of the American people and in their courage to
respond in the face of an emergency. What we are experiencing today is an economic
emergency of the worst sort. If the American people are presented with the facts and are
not misled by momentary self-interest or by the promise o f simple solutions, we can




bring inflation down to tolerable levels. If we opt for the simple and seemingly painless
solution, we will merely prolong our present plight.

These are the choices we face; I

trust that we will choose wisely and persist in what is necessary to restore stability and
growth to our economy.