View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONETARY POLICY...A BETTER WAY

Address by
Lawrence K. Roos
President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before
The New York Society of Security Analysts
New York, N.Y.
February 5, 1979

I am very pleased to have this opportunity to address your distinguished group. The
New York Society of Security Analysts has a well-deserved reputation as a national forum
for timely economic discussion, and it is a distinct privilege to appear before you.

1 realize that'the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis is eyed with suspicion in certain
quarters because it has long been considered a breeding ground for that controversial school
of professional economic thought known as "monetarism."
tinguished

I am also aware that a dis-

newspaper, in a recent article, referred to me as a gadfly and a maverick

within the hallowed halls of monetary policymaking.

Well, I think a few disclaimers and clarifications are in order. First, I am not a professional economist, and when I came to work for the Fed three years ago I hardly knew
the difference between a monetarist and Keynesian.

And I am neither a professional

dissenter nor one who relishes swimming against the current simply for the sake of the
added exercise.

More accurately, I am a concerned citizen who believes that accelerating and continuing inflation poses a serious threat to the economic, social and political well-being of
our Nation. And, as a participant in our Nation's monetary policymaking activities, I am
convinced that responsible monetary policy can play a crucial role in reducing inflation
and restoring stability to our economy.

In a world beset by shortages of one kind or another, there is no shortage of theories
about the causes and cures of inflation. Seldom a day passes without anguished expressions
of concern about inflation and endless prescriptions for remedial action. We are rapidly
reaching the point, however, where conversation and theories are no longer going to be
enough. While past U. S. economic history is replete with periods of inflation that lasted
one or two years and then subsided, we have never experienced a persistent, accelerating
inflation with the scope and perseverance of that which we are currently encountering.




The wise men of economics and the Washington pundits blame our present inflation

-1 -

on all kinds of perceived villains. Some point to rising food prices, failing to note that in
recent years we have had periods of rising food prices as well as periods of falling food
prices. . . and inflation has persisted through both. Some say rising oil prices are the cause
of inflation, yet inflation had its roots in the late sixties and early seventies when oil
prices were stable. Some attribute inflation to the declining value of the dollar in foreign
exchange markets, a questionable theory in view of the fact that inflation began to accelerate at a time when the value of the dollar was static, and has steadily increased under
free-exchange market conditions when the value of the dollar has both risen and fallen.
It is time we stopped fooling ourselves by blaming inflation on spurious scapegoats which
merely divert the public's attention from the truth.

There is only one underlying cause for our current inflation, and that is the excessive
growth rate of our money supply which has out-distanced our production of goods and
services, and has thus bid up the cost of everything. Since 1960, money supply, broadly
defined, has skyrocketed 130% while real GNP has risen less than 80%.

It wasn't always so. From 1958 until the mid-60s, when we began printing millions
of extra dollars to finance both butter and guns, our money supply rose at an average
2.7% annually, while inflation registered an inconsequential 1.7%. We're not alone in that
experience. Most Western industrial nations experienced moderate money growth during
the 1960s and correspondingly moderate inflation until they accelerated their money
supply growth.

In Belgium, for example, a 3.8% late-1960s inflation rate paralleled a

3.5% increase in the nation's money supply, while the early 1970s saw both measures
growing at a 10.7% clip.

The United Kingdom, which quadrupled its money supply

growth rate from the late 1960s t o early 1970s, saw inflation jump from 4.3% to 14.9%
during the same period. In France, the 4.6% inflation rate and 5.3% monetary growth rate
of the sixties grew into 11.6% inflation and 12.1% expansion in the money supply during
the first half of this decade. Likewise, Germany, the Netherlands, Switzerland, Canada . .
the evidence is undeniable.




Why, then, despite overwhelming evidence here and abroad that money growth

-2-

causes inflation, do we continue to tolerate money growth in excess of the rate of growth
of goods and services?

Is it because of some malicious intent on the part of monetary

policymakers? Is it because political pressure groups consciously favor inflationary monetary policies?

Is it because money growth has a life of its own and cannot be controlled?

My response to all of these questions is an unequivocal " n o . "

In my opinion, the

cause lies in the process by which monetary policy has been conducted in recent years.
Our present inflation, as well as most past periods of deflation, is the direct result of
having concentrated on fine-tuning interest rates instead of controlling the growth of the
money supply. It is a procedural problem and as such is capable of being easily and expeditiously corrected.

Let's examine the process by which monetary policy is conducted.

I am sure you are aware that since the development of the Federal funds market,
the commercial banking system in general does not maintain any substantial excess reserves. It follows, then, that any substantive increases in deposits ...-. and thus in money
stock. . . can occur only if the Federal Reserve supplies additional reserves, either through
its open market operations or through a reduction in reserve requirements. Since reserve
requirement changes are infrequently used to affect reserve availability, open market
operations remain the primary tool of money management.

As you know, the Federal Open Market Committee meets monthly and gives the
trading desk at the New York Fed two primary targets to achieve. These are a Federal
funds interest rate range and a growth range for the monetary aggregates (known as M-1
and M-2).

If market forces threaten to move the Federal funds rate above the upper

limit of its range, the desk, in order to curb the rise in the Fed funds rate, buys securities,
thereby supplying additional reserves to the banking system. Conversely, if the monetary
aggregates reach the upper limits of their ranges, the desk withdraws reserves by selling
securities, thereby limiting money expansion and causing an upward pressure on the Federal funds rate. But what should be done when both the Federal funds rate and the



-3-

monetary aggregate simultaneously reach the upper limits of their prescribed ranges?
Should the Open Market Desk let the Federal funds rate exceed the limits established by
policy in order to keep money stock growth within established limits? Or should it let
money overshoot its target range in order to meet the prescribed Federal funds target?
A real dilemma occurs when the interest rate targets and monetary aggregate ranges are
incompatible. Let's see what has happened in the past when this situation has occurred.

A review of the published history of interest rate and monetary aggregate behavior
in the period since long-term monetary aggregate growth ranges were first announced is
enlightening:

In the 46 periods in which short-term policy ranges have been set, the Federal funds
interest rate fell outside of its target ranges only five times; in the same periods, M-1
growth fell outside of its ranges 22 times, or nearly 50% of the time.

M-1 tended to exceed its targets during periods of rising Federal funds rates and t o fall
short of its targets during periods of falling Federal funds rates, while usually remaining
within its targets during periods of stable Federal funds rates. For example, during the
two-year period ending in mid-1974, when loan demand grew at an annual rate of 19.1%,
the Federal funds rate increased from 4.5 to 11.9% and bank reserves were supplied at an
8% rate. But in the next year and a half, when loan demand flattened and the Federal
funds rate dropped from 12.9 to 5.2%, reserves were supplied at only a 4.7% annual rate.

Two conclusions can be drawn from these observations. First, it is evident that in
periods of incompatibility, the Federal funds rate reigns as the primary target in the conduct of monetary policy while adherence to monetary aggregate ranges is secondary.
Secondly, the principal thrust of monetary policy has been to stabilize the Federal funds
rate and to resist both upward and downward market pressures, even if by doing so the
aggregates fell outside of their ranges. Monetary policy, either by design or by default,
has been fashioned to stabilize interest rates, even if it has meant destabilizing money
growth.



-4-

While my remarks have emphasized the inflationary impact of interest rate stabilization, it is crucial that we recognize that such policy can have the opposite effect. A
decrease in credit demand normally would lead to a decrease in the Federal funds rate. If
this rate is prevented from declining with market forces, there is a resultant contraction
of bank reserves and consequently a contraction of money stock with attendant negative
impact on the economy.

Why is there such a preoccupation with the stabilization of interest rates? There are
essentially four points of view which support primary targeting on interest rates.

First, there are those who believe that interest rates represent the price of money,
rather than the price of credit. They interpret changes in interest rates to reflect changes
in people's demand to hold dollars. They rationalize that when money demand increases,
people tend to hold . . . rather than to invest or spend . . . their dollars. This is the
"cookie jar" theory . . . that people will sock away dollars in their cookie jars rather than
spend them. Thus, they reason, when interest rates rise, it is necessary to supply additional
money in order to maintain current levels of spending while at the same time satisfying
people's desires to fill the "cookie jar."

I disagree with this point of view. I believe that interest rate changes mainly reflect
variations in the desire of people to borrow in order to spend. When people are in a mood
to spend, they seek additional credit, and this credit demand translates into higher interest
rates. Under inflationary conditions, it is patently obvious that credit demand for spending dominates any desire to save for a rainy day. The "buy-it-now-because-it-wifl-onlycost-more-tomorrow" syndrome has become an accepted part of our culture, a by-product
of inflationary anticipation. As Leonard Silk noted recently in the New York Times, it is
as though people's perception has changed from mild insecurity over rising prices to a
sharp fear that money is losing its value . . . if not as precipitously as in Germany half a
century ago, then at least over the long run. Monetary policy designed to stabilize interest
rates in the face of such heavy credit demand leads inevitably to expansion of the money
supply and increased inflationary pressures.



-5-

Another argument for primary emphasis on stabilizing interest rates is that a rise in
interest rates serves to discourage borrowing, thus precipitating recessions by reducing
consumption and investment.

After all, critics note, the stock market regularly reacts

nervously when investors sense that higher interest rates are in the wind, because they interpret such signals as foretelling an eventual recession. Practitioners of this school of
thought believe that any increase in interest rates should be resisted in order to avoid recession and increased unemployment.

This argument again ignores the true causes of increases in interest rates. If interest
rates rise because the Central Bank, through its open market operations, withdraws
money and thus limits credit, yes, borrowing will decline, and economic contraction may
take place. But if interest rates go up because people want to borrow more, total borrowing and spending will continue to rise, regardless of higher interest rates.

A third argument for stabilizing interest rates centers around the contention that
targeting on monetary aggregates instead of the Fed funds rate would lead to intolerable
fluctuations in interest rates and produce "disorderly conditions" in financial markets.

It is reasonable to assume that fluctuations in the funds rate would probably increase if monetary policy were to cease its concentration on interest rate stabilization.
However, there is no historical evidence to suggest that such fluctuations would be disruptive, damaging, or excessive.

Indeed, there is every reason to believe that a free-

market approach to interest rates would encourage more careful money management.
Now, I do not doubt that there are bond traders who take some comfort in knowing that
interest rates will not exceed the boundaries of the stated target range. I'm sure, however,
that, after a short period of adjustment, these experts would conform to the new environment.

I can see no reason why financial markets are not as well equipped to an-

ticipate interest rate changes resulting from free-market forces as they are to guess the
intentions of the Federal Open Market Committee in its monthly deliberations. Adjustments to increased risk occur as a matter of course in other financial markets, without
major disruptions in these markets.



There are many markets which are not tightly
-6-

controlled and which are not suffering for this status, and there are others where former
controls have been relaxed or eliminated altogether without leading to panic or chaos.
When a flexible international exchange rate superceded a fixed rate in 1973, pandemonium
did not ensue; when farm supports were reduced in 1973, agriculture certainly did not
wither away. Why should we have so little faith in the ability of our financial markets to
adjust, especially if the new policy were clearly enunciated and announced well in advance of implementation?

The fourth argument against targeting primarily on monetary aggregates is based on
a skepticism as to whether the money stock can in reality be effectively controlled. This
concern, if based on recent experience, has no legitimacy, because the unpredictability of
aggregate behavior in recent years has resulted from the practice of targeting primarily on
Fed funds. The relationship between the monetary base, which is precisely controllable
and measurable by the Fed, and the money stock is predictable. Monetary aggregate control is feasible and practicable if annual or even semi-annual targets are set and adhered
to. Such control is not possible if intervention is attempted on a daily or weekly basis in
response to movements within the financial markets.

In order to enhance our ability to resist excessive inflation in times of strong credit
demand and to avoid the recessionary consequences of abrupt reductions in the money
supply, I propose the following changes in our conduct of monetary policy:
1.

We should abandon the stabilization of interest rates as the primary goal of

monetary policy and move gradually toward a freely-fluctuating Federal funds market.
2. We should concentrate instead on establishing and adhering to long-term money
supply growth rates that are consistent with national economic policy.
3. As the most effective available means of controlling monetary growth, monetary
policymakers should target on the monetary base, which is the source of money creation.

I realize there are those who will argue that permitting interest rates to move in response to market forces after years of controls would adversely affect our financial trading
mechanism.



Others would concede that monetary aggregates should be controlled . .

-7-

but feel that this should be done by varying the Federal funds rate.

The first concern, if it is perceived by the financial community as a valid one, can be
minimized by a gradual widening of the FOMC ranges for Fed funds rates as a means of
moving in a deliberate fashion toward a freely-fluctuating market.

I cannot agree that the most effective method of controlling the monetary aggregates
is through varying the Federal funds rate. A more effective method is to target on the
monetary base, that is, bank reserves and currency in the hands of the public. The monetary base is controllable by the central bank and is predictably related to monetary aggregates. Targeting on the base would eliminate the temptation to indulge in "fine-tuning"
which, in turn, destabilizes monetary control.

A t this point in time, we have an unprecedented opportunity to institute some of
these changes. I t is significant to note that Section 108 of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act
requires the Federal Reserve to report semi-annually to the Joint Economic Committee
of Congress in order to outline the Fed's planned expansion of monetary aggregates consistent with the President's economic plans . . . and to report why past growth targets have
or have not been met. These requirements make control of monetary aggregates part and
parcel of the economic policy of this Nation and call for policies that will seek to maintain the aggregates within agreed-upon ranges.

In closing, let me emphasize that I am not suggesting that monetary policy ever be
conducted in a mechanical, inflexible manner. We must remain sensitive to social, political, and economic practicalities, and we must be prepared to make adjustments in monetary policy as required by national and world conditions.

Ours is a constantly changing world, and monetary policy must be flexible and
adaptable to match changing conditions.

What I am suggesting is that changes in

policy be made for clear, specified reasons, and not be the result of a belief that there
must be an immediate reflexive reaction to every movement in the economy, however
slight.



-8-

Sixteen months ago, Business Week noted, correctly, I think, that "the Fed cannot
entirely ignore interest rates, but it can let them fluctuate within a considerable range
without damaging the economy."

I fear we do not have another 16 months in which to

debate and theorize. My remarks today have been offered because I view our efforts to
reduce inflation and to avoid a recession as deadly serious business. The future course of
this Nation . . and the rest of the free world . . could well depend upon our action or inaction within the coming weeks and months.

We have capabilities to make important

inroads on inflation, not next year, but now. It can be done if we are prepared to change
what needs changing and retain what merits retention, based on solid experience rather
than doctrinaire thinking.

In the field of monetary policymaking, targeting on interest rates at the expense of
stabilizing the growth of the money supply has brought us to the situation we face today.
If we are satisfied with the present condition of the U. S. economy and with our ability
to adapt to ever-increasing inflation in the future, let us continue to function as we have
in the past. If we think we can do better . . . and I firmly believe we can . . . I suggest
that now is the time to act!




-9-