View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Remarks by Governor Laurence H. Meyer

At the AEA Panel on Monetary and Fiscal Policy, New Orleans, Louisiana
January 5, 1997

The Role for Structural Macroeconomic Models
I am in the middle of my third interesting and active encounter with the development and/or
use of macroeconometric models for forecasting and policy analysis. My journey began at
MIT as a research assistant to Professors Franco Modigiliani and Albert Ando during the
period of development of the MPS model, continued at Laurence H. Meyer & Associates
with the development of The Washington University Macro Model under the direction of
my partner, Joel Prakken, and the use of that model for both forecasting and policy analysis,
and now has taken me to the Board of Governors where macro models have long played an
important role in forecasting and policy analysis and the MPS model has recently been
replaced by the FRB/US model.
I bring to this panel a perspective shaped by both my earlier experience and my new
responsibilities. I will focus my presentation on the role of structural macro models in the
monetary policy process, compare the use of models at the Board with their use at Laurence
H. Meyer & Associates, and discuss how the recently introduced innovations in the Federal
Reserve model might further advance the usefulness of models in the monetary policy
process.
I. Structural Models and Monetary Policy Analysis
I want to focus on three contributions of models to the monetary policy process: as an input
to the forecast process; as a vehicle for analyzing alternative scenarios; and a vehicle for
developing a strategy for implementing monetary policy that disciplines the juggling of
multiple objectives and ensures a bridge from short-run policy to long-run objectives.
1. The forecast context for monetary policy decisions
Because monetary policy has the ability to adjust quickly to changing economic conditions
and because lags in the response to monetary policy make it important that monetary policy
be forward looking, monetary policy is very much influenced both by incoming data and by
forecasts of spending and price developments. Forecasts are central to monetary policy
setting. Models make a valuable contribution to forecasting. Therefore, models can make an
important contribution to the setting of monetary policy.
Models capture historical regularities, identify key assumptions that must be made to
condition the forecast, embody estimates of the effects of past and future policy actions on
the economy, and provide a disciplined approach to learning from past errors. I attribute
much of the forecasting success of myself and my partners at LHM&A to the way in which
we allowed our model to discipline our judgment in making the forecast. A model also helps
to defend and communicate the forecast, by providing a coherent story that ties together the

details of the forecast. It also helps to isolate the source of disagreements about the forecast,
helping to separate differences in assumptions (oil prices, fiscal policy, etc.) from
disagreements about the structure of the economy or judgments about special factors that the
model may not fully capture.
At the Board, the staff forecast, presented in the Greenbook prior to each of the eight FOMC
meetings each year, is fundamentally judgmental. It is developed by a team of sector
specialists who consult, but are not bound by, a number of structural econometric equations
describing their sectors, and further armed, in some cases, with reduced-form equations and
atheoretical time series models. The team develops the forecast within the context of agreedupon conditioning assumptions, including, for example, a path for short-term interest rates,
fiscal policy, oil prices, and foreign economic policies. They begin with an income
constraint and then participate in an interactive process of revisions to ensure that the
aggregation of sector forecasts is consistent with the evolving forecast for the overall level
of output.
Models play an important supporting role in the development of the staff forecast. A
separate model group uses a formal structural macroeconometric model, the FRB/US
Model, to make a "pure model" forecast which is also available to the FOMC and is an input
to the judgmental forecast process. The model forecast is conditioned by the same set of
assumptions as the judgmental forecast and statistical models are used to generate the path
of adjustment factors, avoiding any role for judgment in the forecast. The members of the
model group also actively participate in the discussions as the judgmental forecast evolves,
focusing in particular on the consistency between the adjustment factors that would be
required to impose the judgmental forecast on the model and the pattern of adjustment
factors in the "pure" model forecast.
There are two important differences from the private sector use of models for forecasting, at
least based on my experience at LHM&A. First, the staff is not truly making a forecast of
economic activity, prices, etc., because the staff forecast is usually conditioned on an
unchanged path of the funds rate. Thus the staff is projecting how the economy would
evolve if there were no change in the federal funds rate (which does not even always
translate cleanly into no change in monetary policy). The rationale for this procedure is to
separate the forecast process from the policy making process, and therefore avoid appearing
to prejudge the FOMC's decisions. This procedure may be modified when there is a strong
presumption that conditions will unambiguously call for significant action if the Committee
is to achieve its objectives. But it does, nevertheless, make the forecast process at the Board
fundamentally different from that in the private sector where one of the key decisions in the
forecast is the direction of monetary policy. It is ironic that, at the Board, where the staff is
presumably more knowledgeable about the direction of policy than in the private sector,
forecasting is constrained from using that information in developing the forecast. On the
other hand, the practice at the Board may be very well suited to the process of making
policy by forcing the FOMC to confront the implications of maintaining an unchanged path
for the funds rate.
A second difference relative to my experience in the private sector has to do with the way in
which judgment and model interact in the development of the forecast. My first impression
of the process at the Board was that the judgmental team made its forecast without a model
and the model team made its forecast without judgment, leaving the blending of model and
judgment to be worked out in the process of discussion and iteration as the judgmental
group looks at the model output and the model group joins the discussion of the forecast.

The process is, I have come to appreciate, more complicated and subtle than this caricature.
For example, when there have been important shocks (e.g., unexpected rise in oil prices or
an increase in the minimum wage), model simulations of the effect of the shocks will
provide a point of departure for the initial judgmental forecast. But it is nevertheless, a
different way of combining model and judgment than we used at LHM&A where the model
played a more central role in the forecast process. An advantage of the Board's approach is
that it makes the forecast less dependent on a single model (perhaps desirable given the
diversity of views on the FOMC) and forces recognition of uncertainties in the outlook
when alternative sector models yield very different forecasts.
Return to top
2. Policy alternatives and alternative scenarios to support FOMC policy decisions
A second valuable contribution of models is to provide alternative scenarios around a base
forecast. I will focus on three examples of this use models at the Board, though there is also,
of course, widespread use of alternative model-based scenario analysis in the private sector.
First, the staff regularly provides alternative forecasts roughly corresponding to the policy
options that will be considered at the upcoming FOMC meeting. The staff first imposes the
judgmental forecast on the FRB/US model and then uses the model to provide alternative
scenarios for a policy of rising rates and a policy of declining rates, bracketing the staff
forecast which assumes an unchanged federal funds rate. While this is the most direct use of
the model in the forecast process, it is recognized that it has become a problematical one,
especially given the structure of the new FRS/US model that otherwise treats policy as
determined by a rule, a prerequisite to the forward-looking approach to expectations
formation that is a major innovation in the new model. Indeed, it might well be that the
presentation of a forecast that incorporates a simple monetary policy rule might be a more
useful complement to the staff's judgmental forecast than the mechanical bracketing of the
judgmental forecast with pre-determined paths of rising or falling rates.
Second, the staff, on occasion, uses the model to provide information about the projected
effects of significant contingencies: e.g., the return of Iraq to oil exporting under the U.N.
agreement for humanitarian aid or the effect of an increase in the minimum wage. Models
are particularly well suited to providing this information.
Third, the model can be used to evaluate the consistency of alternative policies with the
Federal Reserve's long-run objective of price stability. One of the challenges of monetary
policy making is to ensure that the meeting-to-meeting policy deliberations maintain a
disciplined focus on the Federal Reserve's long-term price stability objective. To facilitate
this focus, five-year simulations under alternative policy assumptions are generally run
semi-annually, to coincide with the FOMC meetings preceding the preparation of the
Humphrey-Hawkins report and the Chairman's testimony on monetary policy before
Congress. These simulations have recently focused on policy options allowing for more
gradual or more rapid convergence over time to long-run inflation targets, allowing the
FOMC to focus on both the different time-paths to achieve the long-run objective and the
alternative paths of output and employment during the transition to the long-run target.
Return to top
3. Policy rules to inform discretionary monetary policy

A third contribution of models to the monetary policy process is through simulations with
alternative rules for Federal Reserve action. At LHM&A we designed our model to offer
users four policy regimes: setting paths for the money supply, nonborrowed reserves or the
federal funds rate or turning on a reaction function according to which the federal funds rate
responds to developments in output, unemployment and inflation. While we increasingly
used the reaction function in our analysis of alternative fiscal policies, we did not routinely
take advantage of the reaction function to forecast monetary policy. Another irony is that
there is a much more active interest in the implications of monetary policy rules at the
Board, where discretionary policy is made, than in the private sector, where estimated rules
might be effectively used to forecast monetary policy.
The staff has examined a number of alternative rules, including those based on monetary
aggregates, commodity prices, exchange rates, nominal income, and, most recently, Taylortype rules. These rules, in effect, adjust the real federal funds rate relative to some long-run
equilibrium level in response to the gaps between actual and potential output and between
inflation and some long-run inflation target.
Such a rule can be interpreted as either a descriptive or normative guide to policy. If the
parameters of the policy rule are estimated over some recent sample period, the rule may
describe the average response of the FOMC over the period. Alternatively, parameters can
be derived from some optimizing framework, dependent on a specific objective function and
model of the economy. Stochastic simulations with such a rule can provide some confidence
that following the rule will contribute to both short-run stabilization and long-term inflation
goals in response to historical shocks to the economy and the rule, in turn, can provide
discipline to discretionary policy by providing guidance on when and how aggressively to
move interest rates in response to movements in output and inflation.
The focus on rules is much more important under an interest rate operating procedure than
under an operating procedure focused directly on monetary aggregate targets and is also
more important under an interest rate operating procedure when the monetary aggregates, as
has been the case for some time, do not bear a stable relationship to overall economic
performance and therefore do not provide useful information about when and how
aggressively to change interest rates. Taylor-type rules, in this environment, provide a
disciplined approach to varying interest rates in response to economic developments that
both ensures a pro-cyclical response of interest rates to demand shocks and imposes a
nominal anchor in much the same way as would be the case under a monetary aggregate
strategy with a stable money demand function. For this reason, I like to refer to the strategy
implicit in such rules as "monetarism without money."
This should not suggest that we can write a rule that is appropriate in all circumstances, to
all varieties of shocks, and to all the varieties of cyclical experience. Rules, at best, can
discipline judgment rather than replace judgment. A particular problem with Taylor-type
rules is that we do not know the equilibrium real federal funds rate and, whatever it might be
at one point in time, it likely varies over time. There is considerable research under way at
the Board in an effort to find specifications and parameters for rules which achieve an
efficient balancing of inflation and output variability and provide guidance about patterns
and aggressiveness of interest rate adjustments consistent with the stabilizing properties of
high performing rules.
Return to top

II. The FRB-US Model: Rational Expectations in a Sticky-Price Model
The newly redesigned model at the Board, the FRB-US model, replaces the MPS model.
The MPS model, developed in the mid to late 1960s, revolutionized macroeconometric
modeling and set the standard for a considerable period of time. The Board participated in
the development of the MPS model and then became its home and the Board staff kept the
faith alive during the lean years when such models lost respectability in academic circles,
even as their usefulness and value in forecasting and practical policy analysis was growing
in the "real" world. The FRB-US model retains much of the underlying structure in terms of
equilibrium relationships and even more of the fundamental simulation properties of the
MPS model, but significantly modernizes the estimation of the model and the treatment of
expectations.
The vision in the new work is to separate macro-dynamics into adjustment cost and
expectations formation components, with adjustment costs imposing a degree of inertia and
expectations introducing a forward-looking element into the dynamics. The net result is a
structure that integrates rational expectations into a sticky price model. In this respect, the
new model follows closely the approach pioneered by John Taylor. Finally, the estimation
technique makes use of co-integration and an error-correction framework.
Financial and exchange rate relationships are based on arbitrage equations, with no
adjustment costs but with explicitly forward-looking expectations. The specification of
nonfinancial equations, in contrast, incorporates both adjustment costs and rational
expectations.
Rational expectations are implemented in two alternative ways. First, expectations can be
specified as "model consistent" expectations; that is, the expectations about future inflation
can be set to equal future inflation (perfect foresight) through iterative solutions of the
model. Model-consistent expectations may, but need not, assume that the private sector has
complete knowledge of the policy rule being followed by the Federal Reserve. In the second
approach, expectations are also viewed as being model consistent, but in this case the model
relevant to expectations is not precisely the same as the FRB/US model. Instead,
expectations are formed based on a simpler VAR model of the economy. The VAR model
always includes three variables--the output gap, a short-term interest rate, and inflation.
When expectations of additional sector-specific variables are required, the system is
expanded to include the additional variable. A unique aspect of the VAR expectations is that
these equations also incorporate explicit forward-looking information through an error
correction specification. For example, the VAR equations include a term for the gap
between actual inflation and the public's "long-run" expectations of inflation, based on
survey measures of long-run inflation expectations which, in turn, might be viewed as based
on a combination of the public's perception of the Federal Reserve's reaction function,
including its tolerance of inflation over the long run. The equations also include the gap
between actual short-term interest rates and the public's long-run expectations of short-term
rates, gleaned from the yield curve.
The model retains the neo-Classical synthesis vision of the MPS model--short-run output
dynamics based on sticky prices and long-run Classical properties associated with price
flexibility--and therefore produces multiplier results, both in the short and longer runs, that
are very similar to those produced by the MPS model. The result is that the model produces,
for the most part, what may be the best of two worlds – a modern form and traditional
results! But the better articulated role of expectations in the new model also allows a richer

analysis of the response to those policy actions which might have immediate impacts on
inflation and/or interest rate expectations.
The model has several advantages. The first is it may be more credible to a wider audience
because of its modernization in terms of cointegration and error learning specification on the
one hand and explicit use of rational expectations on the other hand. Second, the model is
much more flexible in terms of research potential. It allows one to study in particular how
the response to monetary or fiscal policies depends on features of the expectation formation
process. Third, the model forces the user to make assumptions explicitly about expectations
formation that otherwise could be avoided or hidden.
Let me give two examples of policy options that can be analyzed more effectively in the
new model. First, consider a deficit reduction package that is credible and promises to lower
interest rates in the future. In models like MPS and WUMM, the mechanical fiscal policy
simulation would ignore any "bond market effect" associated with changed expectations
about future short-term rates. One could, of course, add-factor downward the long-term
bond rate in the term structure equation to impose a bond market effect, but the structure of
the model neither immediately points you in this direction nor provides any guidance about
how to intervene. In FRB-US, in contrast, one cannot avoid making an explicit assumption
about the credibility of such a policy (through assumptions about future short-term interest
rates in the VAR expectations or in the context of model-consistent expectations) and the
assumption made about credibility will importantly affect the short-run dynamics though not
the long-run effects of the policy.
Second, consider the transitional costs of reducing inflation. The transitional effects on
output depend importantly on the assumptions made about the credibility of the inflation
commitment. Note, however, that there are significant transitional output costs of
disinflation even under full credibility and the model-consistent specification of rational
expectations, arising from the sticky price implication of the adjustment cost specification.
For my part, I prefer the FRB-US simulations based on limited rather than perfect
credibility, because I do not believe that credibility effects significantly diminish the
transition costs of lowering inflation. But I also value having a disciplined approach to
showing how the costs of disinflation would vary with the differing degrees of credibility.
References
Brayton, F., A. Levin, R. Tryon, and J. Williams. "The Evolution of Macro Models at the
Federal Reserve Board." mimeo. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
November 1996.
Brayton, F. and P. Tinsley. "A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconometric Model of the United
States." FEDS 96-42, 1996.
Reifschneider, D., D. Stockton, and D. Wilcox. "Econometric Models and the Monetary
Policy Process." mimeo. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, November
1996.
Taylor, J. "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice." Carnegie Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy, vol. 39, 1993.
Return to top

1997 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: January 6, 1997 12:00 PM