View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

AN ADDRESS BY

L. WILLIAM SEIDMAN, CHAIRMAN
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION
WASHINGTON, D. C.

BEFORE THE

INDEPENDENT BANKERS ASSOCIATION OF AMERICA

THE INSURANCE PROBLEM IN OUR BOARD ROOMS

Las Vegas, Nevada
March 11, 1986

DRAFT #3

3/4/86

Good morning. It is a pleasure and privilege to have the opportunity to speak
to you today. I’d like to talk about several related topics of concern to you and
to the FDIC as your insurer and supervisor.

First, I would like to address the very serious problems in certain insurance markets
vitally important to the entire banking community. I am referring, of course,
to the markets for bankers’ blanket bonds or fidelity bonds, and directors’ and
officers’ liability insurance. Some people have suggested that ’’problem” is now
an understatement, and that ’’crisis” is more appropriate. I would also like to
share with you some of the things that FDIC is doing to address the problem
and to suggest some ways that you can and must contribute to a solution. Finally,
I intend to propose for your consideration an idea which I know from personal
experience has been successful in other industries. While my suggestion won’t
be an immediate cure-all for the insurance problem, it could reduce the likelihood
of claims against directors and officers, D<5cO insurance policies, and fidelity




bonds by improving the performance of many boards of directors. Strong, effective
boards benefit us all. They help you and your institutions, your private fidelity
and D&O insurers, your federal deposit insurer, and the general public.

Before moving into my discussion of insurance, I want to comment briefly on
the subject of non-bank banks. I prefer to call them ’loophole banks”. I will
dispense with this subject quickly by giving you my views. Loophole banks have
no place in our banking system. We like competition in banking, but institutions
that don’t offer the full range of services are unfair competitors.

The symptoms of bank insurance problems are obvious. In the case of the fidelity
bond, some banks cannot obtain any coverage. Fortunately only a small number
of institutions are in this position. Most banks, however, have found that both
their premiums and deductibles have increased dramatically. Limits of liability
have decreased and new provisions in the bond may contract the scope of the
coverage. The D&O liability insurance picture is even worse. Many banks cannot
obtain any coverage at any price. Those banks who have been able to continue




prior coverage have found that their premiums and deductibles have soared,
limits of liability have been slashed, and policy terms are limited to-one year.
Equally, if not more significant, the policy is frequently riddled with exclusionary
provisions which severely contract the breadth of the coverage — sometimes
to the point where it is difficult to tell what if anything is covered by the
insurance. The important consequence of this situation is that many of you have
experienced difficulty in recruiting or retaining good directors because of their
heightened sensitivity to potential liability and concern about adequate liability
insurance coverage.

If misery loves company, we in the banking community have a full house with
whom we can commiserate. The insurance problems facing banks are far from
unique. Virtually all lines of property and casualty insurance have been poor
performers.

As a result, hardly a day goes by without reading about doctors,

lawyers, day care centers, fire departments, parks, or even entire towns and
cities who face prohibitively expensive liability insurance coverage or no coverage
at all.




V

There is much finger-pointing going on trying to explain these problems. Insurers
generally say that our society is too litigious, and that the judicial system is
in need of repair. They also state that heavy losses have reduced their surplus
accounts, and thus their capacity to write these types of insurance. Insurers
spread their risk in reinsurance markets, of which Lloyd's of London has
traditionally been a leader. The availability of reinsurance, however, has decreased
markedly due to reinsurer's own large losses, resulting in a further contracting
of insurance capacity.

Others contend that the insurers have no one to blame but themselves for their
losses. These people point to sloppy underwriting, and a period of intense rate
competition fueled by a desire to capture premium dollars to invest at the
prevailing high interest rates. In reality, there is probably at least a grain of
truth in all of these explanations. Most complex problems have multiple causes.

In the case of bank insurance problems, I am troubled by suggestions I have heard
that the FDIC is a major cause of the problem. As most of you know, when a




bank fails, the FDIC is almost always the receiver or liquidator of the bank.
In that capacity, lawsuits may be brought against former directors and officers
on behalf of the creditors and stockholders of the failed bank.

Please indulge me for a few moments as I dispel some of the myths that seem
to have grown up around these lawsuits. Contrary to what you may have heard,
the FDIC does not file suit against former officers and directors of every failed
bank, nor do we include in our lawsuits every former director or officer from
the beginning of all time to the date of the bank’s failure. We do not always
file a lawsuit if there is D&O insurance available, or ignore a potential claim
if there is no insurance. No lawsuit is filed without having been preceded by
an investigation.

As a part of this investigation, we attem pt to evaluate the

conduct of individual directors and officers, recognizing in particular the
difference between inside and outside directors. A recommendation that a lawsuit
be filed must have not only the concurrence of some of our most senior officials,
but also my personal approval. Many of our lawsuits involve criminal activity,
fraud, or insider abuse. In other cases we have found a serious divergence from




appropriate standards of care which have resulted in large losses to the bank
and exposed your FDIC fund to significant risk.

~~

When these situations do exist, we have an obligation on behalf of the failed
bank’s creditors and stockholders to pursue a claim. Some of you may have read
that historically the FDIC has filed lawsuits against directors and officers in
approximately 2/3 of our failed banks.

You should remember, however, that

in prior years far fewer banks failed; indeed, few among us could deny that in
our industry's past era, marked by heavy regulation and light competition, failure
could be achieved only by the most inept or abusive bankers.

More recently,

we are seeing large numbers of failures attributable primarily to powerful
economic forces beyond the control of the most astute banker. In such cases
it is quite possible that there has been no fraud, insider abuse or even negligence.
Many farm bank failures, for example, may fit this latter model, and it would
not surprise me if the percentage of cases in which we bring suit in the future
decreases significantly.

Finally, the amounts recovered by the FDIC on D&O

and fidelity bond claims in past years have been an extremely small component
of these insurers' total loss experience.




We do not perceive the FDIC as the problem. We do, however, want to be a
part of a solution. If competent directors, particularly outside directors, are
unwilling to serve on boards because they cannot obtain insurance, we all lose.
As insurers ourselves, we are vitally interested in risk management. Competent
and effective bank directors are seen by us as essential to maintaining an
acceptable level of risk in the system.

We at the FDIC have been meeting regularly with bankers, trade associations,
and insurers. I must compliment your own representatives, Chip Backlund and
Ken Guenther. They were among the first to contact us to express their concern
and to offer their -assistance. We have shared with numerous domestic insurers
many of the comments I have made today about FDIC's activities and procedures
in the D&O and fidelity bond claim areas. These insurers have been pleasantly
surprised, and have indicated that the meetings have been helpful — so helpful,
in fact, that we all believe it would be beneficial to meet with leaders of the
reinsurance markets.

My staff and I expect to meet with representatives of

Lloyd’s in the near future.




A number of groups, including the IBAA, also have been exploring alternative
insurance possibilities such as captive insurers. We have been working’-with these
groups, offering our evaluations from supervisory, legal, and practical standpoints.
We favor any such ideas that would serve to increase capacity in the insurance
or reinsurance markets.

At the beginning of my remarks I mentioned that you, the bankers, must also
play a major role in addressing this problem. Although most banks are well run,
some are not. Poorly run banks generate claims against directors and officers
and D&O policies and blanket bonds. The converse represents a simple truth
also: Well run banks spawn fewer claims, and fewer claims cannot help but have
a positive impact on the insurance markets.

I won’t presume to deliver a lecture on your responsibilities as bankers and those
of your outside directors in managing and monitoring the affairs of your banks.
I would like to share with you some basic rules of thumb or "Do’s" and ’’Don’t's"
that could take you a long way towards limiting your potential for losses and




minimizing your exposure to claims from shareholders or others. First, establish
effective oversight and control systems, including periodic reporting to the bank’s
board in order to provide directors with a clear understanding of the volume,
quality, risk and profitability of the bank’s loan and investment portfolios. Time
after time when banks have failed we have discovered that systems and policies
designed to assure sound banking practices and effective monitoring by directors
were never established, ignored, bypassed, avoided or compromised.

Second, there must be well-defined lending and investment policies and an
effective means of monitoring their implementation. Nothing is more critical
in determining the overall level of risk a bank will assume and its long-range
success. In this connection, it is clear that poorly run banks share some common
characteristics: (1) unnecessary concentrations of credit; (2) extensions of large
amounts of credit to unknown ro out-of-territory borrowers; (3) 100% financing
for various types of real estate ventures; (4) reliance on repurchase agreements
- written or otherwise - in loan participations rather than independent analysis
of credit quality. Well run banks, on the other hand, seem to avoid these pitfalls




for the most part. Such banks also seem to have certain similarities in approach.
They tend to limit and place high standards on insider credit; to monitor overdraft
reports carefully; to pay very close attention to their funding sources and rates
being paid and to monitor closely trading account activities for compliance with
investment policies. Finally, well run banks recognizing that most markets are
inherently unpredictable and limit their downside loss potential by making
reasonable assumptions about market conditions and revising their lending and
investment philosophy as those conditions change.

These then are some of the areas that especially merit the attention of the
managements and boards of directors of banks.

Let me conclude by setting out the modest proposal I alluded to in my opening
comments. To set the stage, I will share with you some of my general philosophies
of corporate governance. I am a firm believer in the need for a strong, independent
slate of outside directors. A well-informed, active board of directors is better
able to exercise sound business judgment which, in today’s highly competitive




and complex environment, is essential to success and, indeed survival.

I say

this knowing that those of you who are CEOs may privately disagree, preferring
instead a passive directorate that can be dominated or manipulated. Some CEOs
subscribe to the theory that the way to deal with their directors is to employ
good mushroom growing techniques: Keep them in the dark but well-nourished
with natural fertilizer.

I believe that outside directors should be knowledgeable of the bank’s business
— not every day-to-day decision or development — but certainly the most
significant ones.

Furthermore, outside directors should be able to recognize

principal areas of exposure or potential problems, and in those situations become
more actively involved in the bank’s affairs and less reliant on management.
Some of you may think this is an unfair burden to put on outside directors. I
do not, nor does the American legal system which imposes personal liability on
those directors who fail to meet such minimal standards of care and diligence
as I just outlined. But I believe outside directors could use some help in dealing
with the increasingly complex issues of today’s marketplace and my proposal




is an attem pt to provide that help.

Both the independence and capabilities of outside directors could be strengthened
if banks made a separate budget available to the outside directors. This budget
could be used at their discretion and would not have to be large. Outside directors
could choose to retain independent counsel to assist them and even attend board
meetings with them. They could occasionally choose to retain an auditor, an
accountant or a consultant. Outside directors might meet separately from the
full board to consider reports from their consultants and to take up other issues
such as evaluations of management. In the mutual fund industry, with which
I am familiar, outside directors several years ago began employing independent
counsel. Not only were they more effective directors, but they also found that
this action helped insulate them from liability claims. This process should also
have the effect of better protecting bank management from claims, as well.
Courts have shown some reluctance to second guess decisions that result from
the proper exercise of business judgment by outside, independent directors.




As I’ve said, this suggestion is certainly not a panacea. In addition, some of you
may view it as yet another intrusion into management’s prerogatives.

Some

may fear that it will foster divisiveness in the board room. While disagreement
or contentiousness for no good reason is obviously not desirable, I should also
point out that many of our failed banks had amazingly harmonious, agreeable
boards.

Our experience indicates that the boards of most failed banks relied

totally on what they were told by bank management.

My proposal would help

directors to do their own research and form their own opinions which is no less
than you would expect them to do when making personal decisions.

Finally, some may be worried about the'cost, particularly for smaller community
banks like many of yours. The monetary cost is certainly a legitimate concern.
However, in addition to asking ’’can we afford to do it?’’ perhaps we should also
be asking ’’can we afford not to do it? ’’.

I have offered this suggestion for discussion purposes only. I welcome and value
your opinions on this or any other portion of my presentation.