View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

R E I C H S B A N K

O P E R A T I O N S

1876 - 1914

Karl R. Bopp
President,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

19 5 3
(1964 - Minor Revisions)




ELMER WOOD
Teacher: colleague: friend

Motto

da QAViht von dzinm IJaieAn k<ut,

EAW-i/ih &6 , urn £6 zu bo^itzm .

Goethe ? FauSt
What you have inherited from your forabe.
Earn it, so it may become part of you.

Page

X
II

purposes and Functions of the R e i c h s b a n k .............. ........1
Reichsbank Procedures and the Availability of Credit.

7

A. D i s c o u n t P r o c e d u r e s .................................. ........ 9
1.

Characteristics

o f

c u s t o m e r s ................. ........ 1 0

2. C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s of b i l l s ..................... ........ 11
B. Discounting at Preferential R a t e s ................ ........ 17
C. Lending against Collateral (Lombarding). . . . .

18

D. A v a i l a b i l i t y of C r e d i t ............................ ........21
III.

Rate Policy and the Cost of C r e d i t ..................... ........29
A. Aftermath of Monetary Reform ..................... ........31
B. Easy Money and Preferential R a t e s ................ ........36
Ll 'P

C. Prolonged P r o s p e r i t y .......................................^
1. Seasonal variations .......................... ........^

2. Other facets of p o l i c y ....................... ........53
(a) Crisis operations ..................... ........53
(b) Open Market o p e r a t i o n s ................ ........53
(c) Devisen p o l i c y ..........................
(d) Issuance of small n o t e s .............. ........56
(e) Increasing m inimum clearing balances.

57

D. Crises and Reappraisal of P o l i c y ................ ........59
E. Impressions of Major Influences on Rate Policy .
IV.

Basic Problems of Control




68(a)
71

Page
X

Cus t o m e r s of the Reichsbank, November 15, 1910.

...

11

XI

Local and Consignment Bills at the Reichsbank . . . .

12

XI.

Size of Domestic Bills Falling Due July 1September 3°, 1907................................... ....13

IV.

Preferential Discounting at the Reichsbank: 1880-1896

19

V.

Discounts and Loans at the Reichsbank before and
after the Change of Policy in June 1 9 1 1 ........... ....52

VI.

Selected Accounts at the Reichsbank in 1 9 1 0 .............73

CHARTS

I.
II.

Reichsbank and Open Market Discount Rates, 1880-1898.

17(a)

Reichsbank Rate and Related Factors
A.

1876 - 1885 .....................................30(a)

B.

1886 - 1895 ..................................... 30 (b)

c.

1896 _ 1 9 0 5 ..................................... 30 (c)

D.

1906 _ 1 9 1 4 ..................................... 30 (d)

STATISTICAL APPENDIX

Reichsbank Rate and Related Factors




81-90

PREFACE

This study owes its genesis to a request that I contribute an essay

memorial volume in honor of my first teacher in economics, Harry Gunnison
f the University of Missouri.

I hoped to produce something interesting

Brown o j-

-n the allotted time by analyzing the early history of the Reichsbank because I
had

written a number of unpublished fragments and had collected many bits of

information on the subject over a period of more than twenty years.
I started with two simple ideas.

The first idea was that —

reasons developed by Keynes in his Treatise on Money —

for

a central bank must

have firm control over the volume of reserves of commercial banks if it is to
pursue an effective monetary policy.

The second idea was that the Reichsbank

was one of the powerful central banks in the golden age of central banking
before the First World War.

This idea, though widely held, was not shared by

Keynes.
As I worked over my materials, I found myself forced -- for the
reasons summarized on pages 72 to 7^ —

to conclude that:

(l) before the

First World War the Reichsbank paid virtually no attention to reserve balances
and ordinarily did not know what their magnitude was; (2 ) it did not try to
establish their amount at predetermined levels; (3 ) it was not in position to
do so quite apart from any question of controlling its assets because of the
roagnitude and variations in its other accounts; and (4) German banks did not
roaintain either their reserve deposits or their total primary reserves at any
stomary relationship to deposits.

These judgments tempted me to conclude

the Reichsbank had been a weak institution.
consistent with other bits of information.




This conclusion, however,
For example, the overriding

■
p thp Reichsbank was to maintain convertibility; and it had achieved
objective of tn
.
this objective -

not without effort! —

throughout the period.

At this point, I was farther from a memorial article than I had
thought l wab

when I began.

•aiq at hand.
the materia.Lt>

I could envision no conclusion consistent with

And, of course, I now had many more unanswered questions.

4-v,
circumstances I interrupted the study to rewrite an unpublished essay
Under tnese
the Bank of France for Professor Brown.
s

discharged, I was compelled —

As soon as this enviable obligation

for reasons that Harry Brown preeminently

would appreciate _to return and wrestle with the unfinished business of the
Reichsbank.
My attention was attracted by that tempting though slithery concept:
availability of credit.

Many of the difficulties that troubled me would have

been resolved if the Reichsbank had changed appropriately the administration of
the rules under which it granted credit.
was both frustrating and rewarding.

Search for an answer to this question

The frustration came because, although the

Reichsbank published annual reports, they are virtually barren of policy state­
ments before 1914.

The reward came from an unexpected source.

One day, while

reflecting about possible.sources of information, I remembered that the Reichsbank
was required under certain circumstances to pay a tax on some of its notes.

It

was possible that this source of revenue would be discussed when the Reich budget
was before parliament.

It was this tenuous line of reasoning that led me to the

Stenographic Reports of the Reichstag.
and other operations.

They proved unexpectedly fruitful on this

I have presented in Chapter 2 the evidence that led me to

conclude that the Reichsbank did not control the money market by changing systemically the eligibility or acceptability of paper on which it extended credit.

Erifrl

At this point I returned to Elmer W o o d ’
s profound and discerning study
T'Vi
------of Central Banking Control. He demonstrated that a central




^

may be in position to pursue an effective policy even though it is not

able

to establish a given asset (such as the volume of its discounts) or a

given liability (such as reserve balances or notes) at some predetermined level.
Once

I grasped the real implications of this idea, my materials fell into place.

Ky indebtedness to Professor Wood has been mounting for more than three decades.
I have taken the liberty of dedicating this study to him as a token payment on

a debt that can never be liquidated.
A translation of the original manuscript was published in the
tfeltwirtschaftliche^_Archiv in 195^ under the title "Die TStigkeit der Reichsbank
18?6 bis 1914.”

von

One of the abiding satisfactions I derive from studying central banking
is

the continued warmhearted generosity with which outstanding men in the field —

theorists and practitioners alike —

have discussed and criticized my work.

I

cannot express adequately my appreciation of their contributions to my intellectual
development over the years but neither can I fail to list those who strengthened
this

particular essay through oral discussion and written criticism of preliminary

drafts.

They are:

James W. Angell
Benjamin Haggott Beckhart
Arthur I. Bloomfield
Harry Gunnison Brown
Howard S. Ellis
J. Herbert Furth
L. Albert Hahn
Charles M. Hardin
Arthur B. Hersey
Henry K. Heuser




Miroslav A. Kriz
Arthur W. Marget
Abbot L. Mills, Jr.
Lloyd W. Mints
Hans Neisser
Melchior Palyi
J. Frank Rehfuss
Sir Dennis H. Robertson
Harold V. Roelse

Robert V. Roosa
Jan Smit
Allan Sproul
Woodlief Thomas
Jacob Yiner
Charls E. Walker
John H. Williams
Elmer Wood
Ralph A. Young

REICHSBANK OPERATIONS;

1876-1914

Karl R. Bopp
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

j

Purposes and Functions of the Reichsbank
Politically, the Germany established by Bismarck was torn by

conflict between the forces of centralization and federalism.

In the

Bank Act of 1875, the centralizers were able to establish the Reichsbank
and endow it with responsibility for regulating the monetary circulation
of the whole Empire; but the federalists were able to continue the authority
of other banks to issue notes.
The original draft related generally to banks of issue and con­
tained no provision for a Reichsbank. At its first meeting the Reichstag
commission of inquiry deferred discussion until it received a parliamen­
tary directive as to whether such a bank should be established. The
original draft appears in Stenographische Berichte iiber die Verhandlungen
des Deutschen Reichstages (hereafter cited as S.B. The exact title and
the method of numbering the volumes were not maintained throughout the
the period.), 1874-1875* Vol. Ill, pp. 648-652. The vote to defer dis­
cussion appears at Vol. IV, p. 1,147. Ludwig Bamberger, secretary and an
influential member of the commission, is reputed to have said: MI will
accept no law without a Reichsbank; and I will accept any law with a
Reichsbank.” See Karl Helfferich's introduction to Bamberger's selected
speeches and articles, published under the title: Geld-und Bankwesen,
Berlin, 1900, p. 70. I shall follow the suggestion of C. F. Dunbar,
Chapters on the Theory and History of Banking, New York, 1891, p. 190,
by translating "Privatnotenbanken” as independent banks of issue. The
complications resulting from the continuation of such banks created
certain difficulties, but the centralizers won the substance of the
argument though they may appear to have lost the form.

Economically, the new Empire was primarily an agricultural country
the verge of incredibly rapid strides toward industrial and commercial
°pment. The period from 1876 to 1914 may usefully be divided into two
01'V'Q1 Q -P
0 roughly equal length. Until the middle nineties, despite the




g term price decline in the western world, the German economy made slow

progresb, interrupted by long depressions.

After the middle of the nineties,

rid prices began a recovery, and the German economy expanded at unprece­
dented rates, interrupted by occasional crises.
policy will find it desirable —
Section

Students of Reichsbank

for reasons that will become apparent in

I I I _to devote particular attention to the first few and the last

few years of the entire period.
The Reichsbank was ambitious to be the great bank of the Empire
and to contribute to the great expansion.
excess

It began with reserves far in

of minimum requirements and competed actively Hto employ its funds.”

With the rapid development in the second half of the period, the Reichsbank
found it increasingly difficult to maintain adequate reserves without having
the

German economy become too heavily indebted abroad at short term.

Foreign

funds became less dependable as political tensions mounted.

^
H. Neisser, MDer Internationale Geldmarkt vor und nach dem Krlege,"
in Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 29, 1929, pp* 183-194.

The Reichsbank began operations on January 1, 1876, as successor
to the Bank of Prussia which had been established on January 1, 1847, to
replace the Royal Bank founded by Frederick II in 1765*

The head of the

Bank of Prussia had been directed by statute (§87) to maintain discount and
interest rates as stable as possible.
^ per cent.

The Bank did not reduce its rate below

Until the 1850’
s it was limited by the usury laws and did not go

beyond 5 per cent and rationed credit periodically.

Although it did not cease

ationing with repeal of the usury laws, it did rely more on the rate, increas­
es it, for example, to 9 per cent for two months in 1866.

The Reichsbank,

^ iring the personnel and experience of the Bank of Prussia, began as a
*ull..fled g ed central bank.




It was authorized to engage in various transactions of which
the following were most important:

1 . To buy and sell gold and silver;
2 . To discount, buy, and sell bills having a maximum

maturity of three months and signed by at least two usually three - names of known solvency;

3 . To buy and sell debt obligations of the Reich, German
states, and domestic cooperative corporations; and
to discount as well as buy and sell such obligations
with a maximum maturity of three months;

4.

To extend loans for not over three months on speci­
fied collateral;

5 . To collect maturing obligations and to transfer funds;
6 . To accept deposits, including interest bearing deposits;
7 . To issue notes - these were made legal tender on
January 1, 1910.

The Reichsbank was directed "to regulate the monetary circula­
tion of the

whole Empire, to facilitate clearings, and to see to it that

(1 )
available capital is productively employed .M
Enmeshed in its monetary
XT)---------------------------------------

Section 12 of the Bank Act of March l4, 1875• The third duty reads:
fur die Nutzbarmachung verfugbaren Kapitals zu sorgen." This was trans­
lated for the National Monetary Commission (hereafter cited as N<,M*Co) as
to utilize available capital." (N»M»C., German Banking Lavs, p. 39• )
•Evidently the translator was not an economist.
policies were operations as fiscal agent for the Reich, various state
governments, and other public bodies, as a nationwide center of payments,
clearings, and collector of maturing bills, and as a large bank of dis­
count and deposit for private customers:
Understanding of Reichsbank policy is facilitated by keeping
mind that the three statutory tasks did not necessarily indicate a
Qnnn°n Program of action.




In some respects, indeed, the obligation to

e m°netary circulation had a contractive bias, whereas the

j.- o +n assure productive employment of available capital had an
• ^ -h-iflq• The management was not unaware of the practical evidence
expansive
of tne

conflict, especially because of the wide seasonal variations in

currency demand discussed in Section III-C.
The dominant objective in case of conflict was to regulate the

irculation so that the Reichsbank could always redeem its notes in gold.
To assure that this objective would be achieved, the law placed limitations
on the issuance of notes,

The Reichsbank was required to maintain full cover

in cash and eligible bills against its outstanding notes.
was required to keep at least one-third in cash.

Of this cover it

Cash for this purpose was

defined as current German money (gold, silver, nickel, and copper coins),
Treasury notes, and gold in bars or foreign coins valued at Ml,392 per German
pound f i n e . ^

In addition, the Reichsbank was required to pay a tax at the

The German pound is equal to one-half kilogram. The mint law provided
that 139| ten-mark pieces be coined from one pound of fine gold; there was a
seigniorage or brassage charge of 3 marks per pound.

rate of 5 per cent per year on its outstanding notes in excess of cash reserves
plus a quantum specified In the law.

For purposes of determining the taxable

issue the definition of cash reserves was expanded — logically
to include the
(2 )
notes of other banks of issue.
Generally speaking, of course, the greater
I27- ------ -----------------Both the volume of reserves and the reserve ratio could be influenced
rectly by legislation and Reichsbank operations, quite apart from the
k ^ r e c t effects of monetary policy. For example, originally the Reichswas not authorized to issue notes of less than M100. The 'Treasury
ICL2oaU^ 0^ Ze<^
issue sniall notes (M5, M20, and M50) in amounts up to
flrst^i^^011*
-^-906 the Reichsbank was authorized for the
ized t ^
^ssue no‘
t©s of M20 and M50 - and the Treasury was authorjjj circulSSU6 no^0s
By substituting its notes for Treasury notes
ratio
*tion'
®an3£ could increase both its reserve and its reserve
the Bank t n° C^ange ^-n 'total monetary circulation* This change enabled
I907 ,, 0 Eleet the quarterly drain of cash in September and December
volunjg
below the one-third minimum ratio. See memorial
The Inipi^ 0 ^ei^ s^aRk : 1901 -1925 (hereafter cited as R.B. Ill),, p. 23•
were nn+ f 10ns
such c h a n g e s d e s i g n e d to meet practical problems }
X always f m i y understood.



rve the more certain was maintenance of convertibility,
the resex
Maintenance of excessive reserves, however, would not assure that

available capital was productively employed.
e s t a b l i s h e d

No objective criteria were

to test achievement of this objective.

One might interpret the

Xaw as implying that the amount of such capital was a magnitude independent
of Reichsbank policy itself.
doctrine,

The management, believing the real bills

felt that it could and should invest heavily in self-liquidating

paper and that it should not maintain reserves in excess of its judgment as
to the amount needed to assure convertibility.
seems

At any rate this conclusion

to reconcile partially the apparently contradictory claims of the
that it should not accumulate "idle11 funds and also that it

management

should not strive to maximize profits.
S.B., 1880, Vol. I, p. 135;
Vol. I, p. 203.

(1 )

The concept idle funds was vague

1881, Vol. I, p. 121; and 1889-1890,

and was not related to idle real resources in the economy.
The Reichsbank vigorously pursued the objective of facilitating
clearings, especially during the presidency of Dr. Richard Koch, a tech­
nical specialist.

It actively fostered the growth and use of clearing

(giro) and deposit accounts.
efficiency.

Primarily this was viewed as a matter of

Debits per mark of deposit were clearly greater than payments

per mark of currency.

Hence a given volume of cash might be considered

more efficient as reserve against deposits than against notes.

Occa­

sionally one gets the impression that a more efficient clearing machanism
Was v^ewed also as a means of reconciling the other objectives, especially
since the law required no minimum cash reserves against deposits.
is view was not held consistently.

But

The management recognized that

P°sits were sight liabilities that could be called and that their very




fficiency might make them even more vulnerable than notes.
It is difficult to describe the role of profits in the policy
f the Reichsbank.

As we shall see, the Management recognized it had public

responsibilities that could not be discharged if it sought to maximize its

profits.

It deliberately engaged in operations that reduced profits when

it believed the public interest would be served, as when it paid premium
prices for gold, granted loans free of interest on the importation of gold,
or held its discount rate below 5 per cent when it became subject to a
5 per cent tax on additional note issues.

Nevertheless, the management

was not indifferent to profits, primarily because it did not fully compre­
hend its role as central bank.

Specifically, it did not feel that it could

be expected to hold an "unreasonably” large proportion of its assets in the
form of non-earning reserves.

Desire for earnings appears to have been an

important factor not only in the introduction of preferential rates in the
1880's but also in the seasonal reductions in the rate during the prolonged
prosperity of the last quarter century.
The management argued that "In the general interest of stimulating
national economic activity, the central bank must constantly take into con­
sideration maintenance of as low and stable a discount rate as conditions
permit."^ ^

In retrospect it would appear not merely a coincidence that a

program to achieve this objective would also be in the immediate profit interest
of the Reichsbank.
(1)

-

Dubl • u * Von

------------------------

Umm> "Diskontpolitik," p. 135* In 1912, director von Lumm
Y1 1^hed a series of four articles under this title in Bank Archiv,
serI
’
_PP* 129-136, 145-150, 162-167, and 179-187; hereafter this
]_^p0S
°ited as "Diskontpolitik." The series was reprinted in
lQm
1926. See also speech of President Havenstein, S.B.,
1*07- 1909 , p. 4 ,209.
— '




pptchsbank Procedures and the Availability of Credit

22

The Reichsbank blanketed Germany with a head office in Berlin
gjid a network of branches that increased from 182 bequeathed to it by
the Prussian State Bank in 1876 to U 87 in 191^.
bought

Since the head office
(1 )
less than 20 per cent of the volume of bills,
it is necessary

Memorial volume, Die Reichsbank: 1876 bis 1910 (hereafter cited as
r B. II)> P P • 13^-135• The discount earnings and therefore average
holdings at the head office were relatively far less: 6 - 8 per cent
(pp. ll+O-lJ+l) except in the early years, indicating that it bought
shorter bills.
(See lo^low, notel, p.12.) The proportion of bills
bought at the head office was even smaller when the preferential rate
described in II-B was in effect.
to consider the relationships between the head office and the branches
The head office kept itself informed of business conditions through
reports from the branches:

semi-annually from the independent 'branches

in larger cities and annually from the subordinate branches in towns
and villages.

The President held annual conferences with local branch

directors in various cities to discuss business and credit developments
and prospective changes in organization and procedures.
fice audited and examined all branches.

The head of­

It also established larger

lines of credit for individual customers;, acting on recommendations of
the branch officials and directors.

Apparently the equity of the cus(2)
tomer was a primary consideration in establishing the line.
Once

12)--------- —

—

-----

R B

M^moria-1- v°lume, Die Reichsbank: 1876-1900 (hereafter cited as
P* 83 . Inference drawn from discussion of cooperative
C etl-e s • See also NoMoCo, Renewal of Reichsbank Charter, pp. 207-208.

he line was established, the branch apparently had almost complete
edom so




long as it did not exceed the maximum.

Thus, although the adjective "independent" had a legal origin -

fficials of such branches could obligate the Reichsbank - it had a
vider meaning; such branches had, considerable latitude in their opera­
tions o In fact, the managers of such branches received a percentage

of the profits of their branches.

The management said that,

"The pur­

pose of this arrangement is, on the one hand, to stimulate as much as
possible the activity of the branch by means of providing a direct
interest to the manager in the financial success, and, on the other
hand

to give assurance that only good and safe business will be

done.

(l)
°
H

Th® arrangement, it should be noted, was not directed

\l)

R„Bo I, p» 36° Payment of the share of profits was deferred until
the manager left the bank and all of his transactions which might r e ­
sult in losses had matured,
toward operating efficiency - though that might have been an incidental

by-product; it was directed toward securing as much profitable business
as possible.

Since the prices - discount and loan rates - were deter­

mined at the head office, the initiative of the branch managers could
show itself only in increasing volume.

This objective, of course,

would conflict with a monetary policy of contraction.

On balance, it

(2 )
seems to me that the profit motive prevailed when such conflicts arose=,
The judgment is consistent with the general tone of Reichsbank
publications. A fragment of supporting evidence may be found in N„MoC.,
Renewal of Reichsbank Charter, pp. 66 and 206. This volume contains
translations of a series of articles from the Frankfurter Zeitung and
of articles by Dr. Richard Koch, former President of the Reichsbank,
The newspaper said that as a result of this arrangement some branches
resorted Hto artificial methods of attracting discounts.... and have
+3en "t>ried to obtain bills while a rise in the bank rate was imminent,
th«+ ren^-ering the bank's own discount policy ineffective;" and also
real
'*D:ranc^es tended to be lax in applying the principles of the
that
d.°ctrlne „ Dr 0 Koch defended the arrangement but admitted
^-s Possible that younger managers of the numerous subbranches
at
Veer>red at times in this respect /promising renewal of discount
a mi ^
27 ^eing misled either by an excess of business zeal or by
sconception of the true state of things."




IX.

A'

Discount Procedures
The management of the Reichsbank, in common with that of many

other central banks, accepted the "real bills" doctrine and operated
primarily in what it at any rate believed to be such bills.

From 1876

until 189U, the annual volume of bills drawn or payable in Germany in­
creased with population from about M 12 billion to about M15 billion,
and the a v e r a g e amount outstanding increased correspondingly from about

M 3 billion to about M3-3A

billion.

After the middle nineties, the

volume of bills increased much more rapidly than population, reflecting
the very rapid economic development of Germany.

Roughly one-third of

all bills drawn passed through the Reichsbank; but for reasons to be
analyzed later, the average portfolio of the Reichsbank varied between

10 and 15 per cent of the average amount of bills outstanding.^^
TTJ

—
—
—
The following data are taken from R.B. II, p. l6l, for 1876, 189^,
and 1910; and from Enquete-Ausschuss, Die Reichsbank, Berlin, 1929,
p. 28, for 1913 t

Amount of Bills Drawn or
Payable in Germany
Total:
Marks
Purchased
Year Mil. marks per capita by Reichsbank

I876
I89U
1910

12,37^
l1*,7^8
31,005

1913

287
287
U 80

33«3
32.1
35*0

Average Amount of Bills Outstanding
Million
marks

3,169
3,777
7,838
8,500

Marks
per capita

$ Held
by Reichsbank

7^

12.7

7b

l4A

121

10-9
12.1

Although the Reichsbank discounted or bought only bills with
a maturity not exceeding three months and having at least two - usually
signatures of known solvency, the volume of eligible bills outthe Bank was always adequate to permit expansion of its portfolio.




On the other side,

although it never resold bills,

its portfolio

Since the Reichsbank was authorized to sell bills, this was a
tter of administrative policy, not legal compulsion. The policy was
Tstified officially on the ground that the Reichsbank "is the strongt and last source of credit in the land; it pannot, like other banks,
claims for credit on a higher institution.” R.B. I , p. 76 ; com­
are pp* 19 an(i 132 * This justification reflected a literal rather
than a functional interpretation of the phrase "lender of last resort."
<?ee J. Plenge, Von der Diskontpolitik zur Herrschaft uber den Geldmarkt,
(hereafter cited, Diskontpolitik), Berlin^ 1913, ppT 1 9 5 - 1 9 ^ 20y-204,'
and notes pp. 383-389* W. Conrad, "Von der Diskontpolitik zur
B e h e r r s c h u n g des Geldmarktes: eine Erwiderung" in Bank Archiv, Vol. 11,
3^0, cites as reasons for not rediscounting bills that the customers
discounted bills with the understanding that they would be held by the.
Reichsbank until maturity and that the Reichsbank did not want to give
hanks an insight into its business for fear of losing customers to them.
was always large enough and its maturity distribution such that —
possibly, in slack seasons —

save,

the Bank could enforce its terms, if necessary

through contraction.

1.

Characteristics of customers

The Reichsbank was authorized to acquire bills with at least two
and "as a rule,” §13, three signatures known to be solvent.

The third sig­

nature was frequently added by a bank which sold the bill to the Reichsbank
shortly before maturity for collection.

The Reichsbank, however, was a large

commercial bank as well as a bank for bankers.

It established lines of credit

for each of its thousands of discounting customers.
said:

"With us, anyone may discount —

President von Dechend

every solid ordinary person and every

solid good firm without respect to his wealth. 11^

As is shown in Table I,

T?)------ -------- ----- —

1889-1890, Vol. I, p. 600. He was contrasting the Reichsa. w ith^the Bank of France which, he said, admitted only the socalled presentateurs.
ke great bulk of the lines of credit were small.

Of more than 66,000

1910, less than 1,000 were for more than M|- million.




Even of the

q

large

more were open for industrial borrowers than for banks.

TABLE I
Customers of the Reichsbank
November 15, 1910

r

Total

t 0

d

i s c o

u

n

l^ lln only

66,681

2,361

2k ,128

21,2kk

9,854

1,026

8,068

914

148

323

344

10

35

5^

lk-9
205
195
403
34l

9,915
5,784

5,531
4,224

5,369
2,317

142

3,838
1 , 95 ^

2,559
3,091

2,1+55
3,^56

828

1,^63
1,218

2,211

313

2,942

218

142
225
155
152

98

425

IT

18

t

glsssified according to
;guc of line of credit
1 000-10,000 marks 24,944

14,676
7,028

11*000-20,000
21. 000-30,000
31.000-60,000
61,000-100,000
101,000-500,000
501,000 and over

Agriculture
Banks & Merchants
Bankers & Commerce Industry & Related Cooperatives Others

8,752
4,819
5,525
937

725
3^3

192

792

Source: R.B. II, pp. 154-157-

2.

Characteristics of bills

The Reichsbank distinguished between local bills, payable in

the district covered by the purchasing office (Platzwechsel), and con­
signment bills, payable outside (Versandwechsel).

A comparison of

T D -----------------------Consideration of foreign bills will be deferred to Section III,

the two types is given in Table II.
From 1876 through 1910, the Reichsbank bought 33 million local

H® for M 80 billion, giving an average size of about M2,500.

Average

ities varied from k2 days in 1910 to 60 days in 1894 and 1896.




Sh-9

785
336
270
36

TABLE II
Local and Consignment Bills at the Reichsbank

L o c a l

C o n s i g n m e n t

B i l l s

B i l l s

Purchases
Average
Average
Average
Size Maturity Portfolio
No.
Value
Size Maturity
(marks) (days)
(mil. m) (thous.) (mil jn)f. (marks) (days)

Purchases
Value
No.
(mil.
m)
(thous.)

Tear

Average
»ortfolio
(mil. m)

1816

17^

531

1,107

2,085

57

227

2,028

1 ,1+86

27

297

798

1/791

2,243

60

2^8

2 ,3^0 2 ,914-0 1,256

30

lj-81

1,558

k, 065

2,609

k2

373

3,680 6,778

1,814-1

19

1910

3,016

Source: R.B.

During the same period it bought 89 million consignment bills worth
1CL35 billion, giving an average size of about Ml,500.

Average maturi­

ties varied from 19 days in 1910 to 31 days in each of the years 1886
to I889 inclusive.
m

~

The average size and. maturity varied considerably among the
various branches as is illustrated in the following data taken from
Yerwaltungsbericht der^.Reichsbank fur das Jahr (hereafter cited as
R,B^V>B. fur) 1896:~
"

Variation in average size and average maturity of discounts
and loans at Reichsbank offices in 1896
S i z e
type
*e*lbui8
^•Ignment bills
taribara
(*) borrowing
rePayment




Min.

Max.

M a t u r i t y

Berlin

Aver.

Min.

Max.

Berlin

Aver.

1,000

6,703

3,673

Z,kk0

21

81*-

21

52

537

^,600

2,796

1,^59

12

71

12

28

k

233

28

27

2,800 68,670
2,200 72,^60

27,627
31,517

15 ,914-14
16,707

Local bills increased gradually in importance.

In 1891 they

half the average portfolio of domestic bills for the first
cotiPrl3e
Their lowest proportion was 42.5 per cent in 1883 and their

time.

highest was 64.8 per cent in 1906.
For a number of reasons, including a desire to counteract
that it was Insensitive to the credit needs of small business,

the

Reichsbank

published data on the size of domestic bills.

There

(1)
was no minimum, and the Reichsbank discounted bills as small as M10
N.M.C., Interviews on Banking in England, France, Germany,
Switzerland, and Italy (hereafter cited as Interviews), p. 341.
The distribution of bills falling due in the quarter July 1 - September

30, 1907, which illustrates the data published for other periods, is

shown in Table III.
TABLE III
Size of Domestic Bills Falling Due July 1 - Sept. 30j 19Q7

Consignment Bills

Local Bills
Number
(thous.)

£88 than 200 marks
200 to 400
**01 to 500
501 to 1,000

73
74

M 01 to 3,000
3>00l to 10,000
than 10,000

86
42




33
84

19

Per cent

Cumulative
per cent

Number
(thous.)

Per cent

17-7

328

36,1
20.3

Cumulative
per cent

17.7
17.9
8.1
20.4

35.6

184

^3-7
64.1

60

6.6

134

14.8

36.1
56.4
63 .O
77-8

21.0

85.1

122

13*4

91,2

10.3
4.6

95-4
100.0

52

5-7
3-1

96.9

28
—

100.0

909

-

100.0

100.0

The maximum maturity of bills that the Reichsbank was authormirchase was three months.
ized to pux
^
in the case of farmers.
except in

It did not customarily renew bills,
The average maturity from 1876 to

X910 varied between 28 days (in 1910) to 4l days (in 189^) and usually
varied

only a day or two from the mode of 35 days.

But these ayerages

conceal some of the dynamics of discounting at the Reichsbank.

Roughly

l8 per cent of the portfolio matured within a week, and 28 to 30 per
cent within two weeks.
w

(2 )

Roughly half, or a little less, matured

r

T h e s e averages were computed from holdings
months from February to December inclusive, and
The proportion of short bills was probably even
a month.

on the 7th day of
on the 31st of December
greater at the end of

within a month.
In terms of credit operations, customers discounted at the
Reichsbank for a variety of reasons.
lection, especially by banks.

Many bills were handed in for col­

Since the Reichsbank charged discount for a

minimum number of days, such bills were discounted when they had that many
/O \
days left to run.
Another group came from commercial, industrial, and
131------------ — —
The exact number of days depended on place of payment, amount of
ill, a n d similar factors. Some of the handbooks for merchants and
raders reflected this practice in the sections devoted to the eomputabir? °
f discounts. They show how to compute discount for, say, a 90-day
. k y u s i n g the commercial bill rate for 85 days and the Reichsbank
»
for 5 days. See, for example, L. Rothschilds’Taschenbuch fur
58th Edition, edited by Christian Eckert, Leipzig, 1920,
recall
■
^ern^)urg> as a member of a commission of inquiry in 1926,
that when he was active before the first World War his bank
■^turit^6^
kill 8 ^ days and provincial bills 10 days before
E&Quet ^ ^ecause that was the best and most convenient way to collect.
va8
U 8sctluss, Die Reichsbank, p. 136 . His distinction for Berlin
as niade fOUrse * identical with that between local and consignment bills
y the Reichsbank. See also, W. Conrad, Loc. cite, p. 3^ 0 .




a£ri-cul
bank*

yal customers who were seeking credit accommodations from "their
Tnnfrer bills came from this source.

The difference in purpose be-

-iection and borrowing helps explain why average maturities were

1
tween co-u-

for local than consignment bills. Finally, in times of pressure,
longer
h n the prime market rate touched bank rate, as happened frequently toward
the end of the year, banks and possibly other dealers in credit discounted
-omewhat longer bills.

I cannot cite contemporary evidence, but it is probable

that the maturities depended on the composition of their own p o r t f o l i o . ^
^
gjH VrnRr^Schacht, who had 1)6611 an alternate director at the
Dresdner T^nk as early as 1908, did testify - but in 1926 at the age
of 49 - that when a banker had to meet large payments "he begins to
leaf through his portfolio for 3 > 4, 5, 10 , 15 -day bills, and then
says, I must go to 30 days; or, as the saying used to b e , we had to go
to 50 days at the Reichsbank, that is, we had to take our bills up to
50 days to secure the money." The italics did not appear in the
original. Enquete-Ausschuss, Die Reichsbank, p p . 136-137*
Ordinarily, however, the Reichsbank did not acquire prime —
top quality —

long bills.

that is

Such bills were discounted in the market at

less than the official rate.

Some writers have placed great emphasis

on the mere fact that bank rate was above market rate.

They seem to

infer that since both were rates at which bills were discounted a dual
pricing system was in effect. Actually the rates usually related to
articles of different quality.

In fact there was more than one market

rate; the published rate referred to .'prime bills, other rates were
n®gotiated for bills of less than prime quality.

Bank rate, however,
/p \
W*S ^iformly applicable to all eligible and acceptable bills.
Und p^00 J *.F ‘Sckar and H. Reccius,"Die Spannung zwischen Banksatz
ivatdiskont", in Bank Archiv, Vol. 11, pp. 65-?0»
Most of the bills acquired by the Reichsbank were collected
^ity.



Nevertheless, the collection experience of the Reichsbank

d*cates that it acquired many bills of inferior quality.

Between 2

r Cent of all local bills were not paid by the drawee upon
and 3 Pe
(1)
sentation at maturity.
In general these were small bills; in
pfe
R.Bo II, P* 127= The data relate to the years 1895-1910, inclusive.
Ather data on which this paragraph is based appear at pp. 126-131 ,
& - 2 W -

value, the proportion varied between k/lO and 8/l0 per cent.

The p r o ­

portion for bills of M100 and less was usually 6 per cent or more - 8
per cent in 1895.

The record for consignment bills was not as good.

Of

such bills roughly 5 per cent in number and 1 to 1^- per cent in value
nere not paid by the drawee upon presentation.

Again, the poorest record

vas with the very small bills, as many as 10 per cent of which fell in
this category.

The chief reason for the difference in experience b e ­

tween the two categories is that local bills were bought only after a c ­
ceptance, whereas the Reichsbank endeavored to secure acceptance of
consignment bills after purchase.

The losses sustained by the Reichs­

bank were, of course, far less than these proportions.

Only MI 58 per
(2 )
Million of bills bought between 1876 and 1910 seemed uncollectible.
The proportion varied between M2 per million in 1897 to M 8l 8 per
■illion in 1901.
Of this amount, only 1/3 was written off; and perhaps 80 per cent of
the amounts written off, in turn, was recovered ultimately.

The im­

portant point for our; purposes, however, is not the immediate or ultimate
effect on the profits of the Bank-

The important point is that the

ichsbank year after year acquired many second rate bills.

Its ap-

ent immediate losses tended to concentrate in years of economic
iculty, but this did not deter it much - primarily through its




branch managers -- from acquiring more bills of the same quality.

Small

‘and that it was almost the only lender in parts of eastern

Germany.

nr

G.
von Schulze -Gaevernitz, "Die deutsche Kreditbank" in Grundriss
A*r Soziar6konomik Vo 2. Bankwesen, Tubingen, 1915, p. 7 5 . The author
points out that earnings of branches of the Reichsbank from local bill)
in 1908 were: for Frankfurt a. M . , M253;000 with an average maturity
Of 15 days; for Glogau, M603,000 with an average maturity of 71 days;
for Flensburg, M6l5,000 with an average maturity of 63 days; and for
Stralsund, M626,000 with an average maturity of 73 days* See also K.
yon Lumm, "Diskontpolitik", p. 146*

H. B.

Discounting at Preferential Rates
From 1880 to 1896 the Reichsbank frequently discounted prime

bills at preferential rates, primarily to meet the competition of independent banks of issue.

After a few months of experimentation, uniform

rules were established for such discounting.

Only prime bills for at

least M3,000 and having at least six weeks to run were eligible.

Be-

8k*ning in l88l, operations at the preferential rate were suspended
*fcsn the official rate reached 5 per cent - reduced, apparently in 1895 ^
^ Per cent - or when exchange rates reached the gold export point /




1> PP» 81 -82 , 148.

^

REICHSBANK AND OPEN

M ARKET DISCOUNT RATES

1880-1896

PER CENT

PER CENT

1 7(a)

1880




1882

1884

1886

1888

1890

1892

1894

1896

Bills were not purchased at the preferential rate at the head
ffice in Berlin/'1 ^ The preferential rate was approximately the going
S Be, I 889-I89O, Vol. I

p. 2.0k; K. von Lumm, "Diskontpolitik",

p.

r»te on prime bills in centers outside Berlin.

The relationships b e ­

tween the official rate, the preferential rate, and the open market
rate on the Berlin Bourse are shown in the chart.

From 1880 to 1885

tjie official rate was not reduced below k per cent; but the prefer­
ential rate was frequently reduced to 3 per cent, and in l880-l88l was
2| per cent for short periods.

From 1886 to 1896 there was only one

year (1890) in which the official rate did not touch 3 per cent, with
the preferential rate frequently as low as 2 per cent.
The importance of preferential discounting at the Reichsbank
Is shown in Table IV.

II • C.

Lending against Collateral

(Lombarding)

In addition to buying or discounting bills, the Reichsbank
loaned on collateral.

The Bank recognized the important functions per-

foraed by collateral loans but, believing the real bills doctrine, felt
they were far less important than discounts to modern banks of issue
"because they cannot be used as collateral against notes»

From time to time the Reichsbank established a maximum for
lombard portfolio, although it occasionally exceeded the formal
The average lombard portfolio varied between 8 and 16 per cent




TABLE

preferential Discounting at the Reichsbank; 1880-1896

Average size (marks)
of domestic bills

■0. of
jays i-n No. of All bills At preforate
effect Changes
0

m
I

si

170
231
185
3IK)
350
288
348
3^3

19
31
14
24
29
20

28

1,423
1.507
1,5-92

n»a.
n

1,681
l, 66l
1,699
1,633
1,635

4?
36
38

1,663
1,588
1,670

9,07^

76

12

1.727

10,673

m
J 93
&

200

17
37

896
IftT

0

a

m
*90

323
273

0
339

3^6

267
61

16
18
9

Percentage of
Average maturity (days) bills acquired at
preferential rate
of domestic bills
Average
At
All bills
pref.rate No, Value Portfolio

1,637

1,5^9

1,627

1.507
l,6l4
1,739
1.727

8,007
7A99
10,777

11,677
11,306
11,368
11,297

35
35
33
33
34
36
37
38
40
39
39
35
35
40
39
41
40
37
35

75
77
75
75
76
76
76
75

76
77
78
78
76

n=a

8

18

n
n

7
7

17
15

11

11

16
18

22

38
35
45
52
48
42

5

12

22

4-2

14

28
49
36

17
23

28
26

26
18
5

11

®ource: R-B* II, pp. 130-133=
n.a. - not available
This table illustrates the slithery ground on which one walks in trying to
l*terpret times past. Take the year 1887 as an example., A few bills (1 out of 20)
discounted at the preferential rate; but they are relatively large (5 or 6
dliuvL I**6 averaSe ) and they are longer (almost 2 times the average ) so that bills
at the preferential rate comprise over half the average portfolio. Such
J?iJiaerations also account for the fact that inauguration and elimination of the
^^®*ential rate had only slight effects on the relation between local and conhills and on the average size or maturity of bills 0
°f the total earning assets of the banko

The securities and commodities

eligible as collateral as well as maximum loan values were specified in
^ law.

The Reichsbank itself at times imposed more stringent condi-

°ns.

The value of the collateral had to be maintained at the specified

leVels “
throughout the loan




The law permitted the Reichsbank to lend on collateral for
, no
pgrioas
uy to three months; but, except for a short time beginning in
^880 when it made some fixed maturity loans at preferential rates, all
loans were callable either by the Bank or the borrower.

Interest was

vable only for the period that the loan was outstanding, except under
the special circumstances discussed in Section III-C-1.

Although the

character of the borrower was not ignored, the basic condition of loans

vas the value of the collateral.

The Reichsbank stated that "in lorn-

bard operations, as with bill purchases, the rate of interest has been
the most important means used by the ~Bank to regulate its portfolio.
In this way it was always possible for the Bank to extend a loan on

every application supported by eligible collateral.

It was never

obliged in collateral loan operations to introduce more or less capricious restrictions which impose a hardship on the borrower.*».

„ (1 )

R.Bo I f p. 106 ; see also R. Koch, in N 0M»Co, Renewal of Reichsbank
Charter, p 0 222.
The management approved the legal provision that lombard loans
should not be used as collateral for notes.

Since such loans were not "self-

liquidating,”the management stated the risk of loss was too great.
its losses on collateral loans were less than on bills.

Actually

In part, this was

because the collateral loan value of securities and commodities was
°nly a fraction of their market value, whereas bills were bought at dis­
counted value 0 The management never integrated its collateral loan ex­
perience -with its theory of note cover.

Instead it cited its favorable

e3tPerienee as evidence that it operated conservatively in a business
Was inherently suspect for a central hank ~




II

D . &valiability of Credit
The discount and loan procedures have been described to form

basis for judgment as to availability of credit at the Reichsbank.
On balance, I am strongly of the opinion that credit was always avail­
able on specified terms and that the Reichsbank did not modify its

rules or Interpretations as a deliberate means of exerting or releasing
pressure on the money market.

Operating procedures, including rules

governing eligibility and acceptability of bills for discounting and
of collateral for loans were formalized and generally known.

(1 )

As an illustration, in 1912, C. Letzel brought out the eleventh
edition of R. Telshow's, Per gesamte Geschaftsverkehr mit der Reichs­
bank; Ein Handbuch fur das Publikum mit Benutzung amtlichen Materials.
A translation of the rules in effect at the time is given in N,M.C.,
German Imperial Banking Laws, edited by R. Koch, pp. 135-218.
Some evidence could be cited on the other side, but it is not
convincing.

For example, the Bank stated that "it had to acquire from

direct observation an adequate and continuous insight into credit de­
mand and credit supply" and that it could do so only by securing a
i

(2)

large portion of the outstanding domestic bills.

It might seem

------------------------------------------------- ----—

R-B- I, p. 79
that a purpose of this insight might be to refuse "improper" demands.
Actually, however, it appears to have been to distinguish among demands
as
(^ )
S a means of determining how to proceed with the rate. "
T5)
--- —
Dp t
^
for —
P* 126, where distinctions are drawn between gold demanded
over83^ 101"1" anc^ ^or internal circulation and between demands based on
ment Pe^u^a'*:ion and overproduction and those arising from normal paythe n a ,^uS* See also K. von Lumm, "Diskontpolitik," pp. 132-135? and
quotations on p. 3 0 , as follows*




A number of writers of the time mentioned glibly the virtues and
even the

necessity of having a central bank observe many bills directly in

understand real developments in the money market.
order to uriu
..

that tne

I must confess

fflnr,p i mull over this approach the more weaknesses I find in it

c

reliable it would appear to have been.

and tne -lc

First of all, top management certainly did not observe all the bills.
Even had thev been disposed to do so —

and we have no evidence that they were

so disposed_the mere number and location of the bills would have cooled
their ardor.

Second, although we have evidence that the head office did not

always know what the branches were doing in the way of discounting, I have

found no evidence that the management had established an adequate system of
classifying and reporting the characteristics of discounts on a continuing
basis.

Nor was a representative sample constructed; and there would be

reason to doubt that the bills discounted at the Reichsbank were a repre­

sentative sample of all bills.

Third, even if the management had had an

adequate system of continuous reporting, it is not easy to see exactly how it
could interpret objectively the summaries and analyses in terms of rate policy.
An expansion in all industries would have been reflected in the totals of bills
drawn which would, in turn, have been reflected in tax receipts on bills and
possibly in total discounts at the Reichsbank.
been ascertained without ever seeing any bills.

At any rate, it could have
Expansion in some industries

and contraction in others might indeed have been reflected in detailed analyses.
how should such relative changes be interpreted in terms of the rate?
Fourth, in the light of these considerations, it appears improbable
the management had any systematic procedure for actually observing bills
0n c^anges in broad categories. It seems much more likely that the
itself formed an impression on the basis of reports from members of
Control



committee —

some of whose members were well informed on the market

but none of whom had as much knowledge of bills actually discounted
generally
Reichsbank as the discounting officials and clerks of the Reichsbank
at th
and from impressions of its own staff who, probably at one or more
itself
had actually seen the discounts because they had completed transremoves,
actions

TTn+h customers.

In summary, when I try to think what a member of

gement should do about the rate as a result of what he might learn from
th's approach, I conclude that, though he might have become informed on many
facts he would find the whole collection of details inadequate to form a
rational opinion on the rate.
Another bit of tentative evidence that the Reichsbank might have
adjusted the administration of the discounting mechanism as a method of control
is that the Preussische Bank had rationed credit —
January I856, and even as late as 1872.

(1 )

for example, in July 1853)

Since von Dechend, who was presi-

^ A l b r e c h t Sommer, Die Reichsbank unter Hermann von Dechend (18651890), Berlin, 1931? PP* 128, 13^.

dent at the time, continued as the first president of the Reichsbank, it might
be supposed that the practice would have been continued.

Actually, however,

the new rules adopted by the Reichsbank in keeping with the law excluded
paper of the kind discriminated against by the Preussische Bank In 1872.
With the rapid industrial development and the emphasis of the
nanag0merit on profits, managers of branches became rather lax in applying
legibility rules.
8n

In December 1906 —

that is when consideration was being

increasing the rate from 6 to 7 per cent -- the managers of the

ches were reminded of their obligation to examine the business origin
bills tendered for discount.

They were directed to be cautious about

hich might be supposed to have been drawn to provide permanent working




(1 )
- or rnerely to "acquire money.”
capital

Renewals were to be limited to a

7lY

r.b. Ill, p. 25. See also Die Bank, 1908, pp. 619, 923, 1058. The
.“
Managers did not necessarily treat all customers alike. Those who
bfanc t insist on being paid in gold but accepted notes or silver and those
^ discounted regularly at the Reichsbank rather than shop around for lower
^
"''were given preferential treatment. Die Bank, 1909, p. 288.
p3t
singie extension for agricultural bills only.

The warning was repeated in

June 1908, after Havenstein became president, and the branch managers were
pmohatically directed to rid their portfolios of ineligible bills. These
moves by the Reichsbank were an attempt to make operations at the branches
conform to established principles.

They did not reflect a change in those

principles and did not inaugurate a move in the direction of changing accept­
ability standards from t ime to time depending on economic developments. The
primary interest of the Reichsbank in taking these steps was in the quality
or character of its portfolio rather than in the total amount.
When Ernst Fischer asked what policy the Reichsbank would follow
with respect to discounts, President Havenstein requested him "to quiet the
doubts of those who are afraid that the Reichsbank intends, as a matter of
principle, to restrict its credit business in the next ten years, and to say
to them that what the Reichsbank has in view is only a securing of its solvency;
that therefore it desires to have only such bills as it may use as legal security
for its notes, but that it has no desire to bring about in any way a systematic
limitation of the business of dealing in credit.”
---- ---------- —
(2!
Op
*M.C., German Bank Inquiry. Vol. I, p. 102^. G. v.Schulze-Gaevernitz,
count^ h
"The Reichsbank is not indeed required by law to redisbills,,»
business world has confidence that it will never decline good

At the German Bankers Convention which met in Munich in September 1912,
wabach of Bleichroders cited letters from managers of large industrial




to the effect that branches of the Reichsbank required them to
companies

7TT"

r-handlun^en des IV. Allgemeinen Deutschen Bankiertages zu Munchen
-^nd 18. September 1912, Berlin, 1912, pp. 87-88. The reasongiven
80 i h t the branch needed reimbursement for its trouble. .In one instance,
waS q0 day bills were required; in another instance some ^5-day bills. In
s°me ^ “tances the industrial customer had to buy appropriate bills from a
s0ine
bank. A branch did not feel that a minimum clearing balance was
a d e q u a t e compensation

Heifferich of the Deutsche Bank gave a similar report and said some branches

reqUired the discount of bills ’
’
which the customer often does not discount
(2 )

happily and which the President and Board of Directors in Berlin do not wish.”
T2T "

"

Ibid, p. 79; see also pp. 77-78. The quantitative effect of the new
discounting policy is impossible to estimate. Helfferich inferred it was
a reduction in total discounts. Another contemporary observer estimated
the reduction at M150 to M200 million. Die Bank, 1911, p. 529* The official
Memorial Volume, published in 1925, was probably in error when it gave the
impression that there was no quantitative effect by commenting: "The measure
had the desired effect; the place of finance bills was taken for the most part
by solid commodity bills.” R.B. Ill, p. 26. Arthur Feiler, editor of the
Frankfurter Zeitung, said that managers of many provincial branches attracted
discounts artificially. Die Probleme der Bankenquete, Jena. 1908, p. 30.

A final consideration is the periodic complaints, especially from
agriculture and small business, that the Reichsbank was too restrictive.

These

complaints, however, were directed against the law and the rules rather than
against variations in conditions for granting credit.

It should be remembered

that the management of the Reichsbank believed the "real bills" doctrine.

In

lts reP H e s to charges of discrimination, it defended its eligibility rules;
it did

not allege that eligible discounts of other origins were ever turned

down.




It is likely that in periods of expansion, at least some
customers touched the ceilings of their lines of credit at the Reichsbank;
but I i i n

j n0 evidence of complaint on this score and do not conclude

h t it was a significantly restrictive factor.
There were also complaints that the Reichsbank was too
us in granting credit, especially at preferential rates.
©
President von Dechend replied that the law had specifically forbidden
the Bank to engage in any business other than discounting and lending on
collateral.

"Now I ask you,” he said, "can one demand of us that we

should not cultivate the single business that we are directed to do,

but instead content ourselves with what other people do not wish to
have?”^

^

S.B., 1881, Vol. I, p. 126.

Emphasis not in the original.

On balance, it seems to me that the Reichsbank did not modify
its ambition to be active in discounting by tightening its acceptability
rules periodically.
Our greatest interest, of course, is in the assumptions on
which customers, particularly commercial bankers, operated.
^tely, as to this, we have positive evidence.

Fortu-

The commercial bankers

took it for granted that the Reichsbank would in fact always discount




•gible PaP er even though they made no secret of the fact that they
ised

^

c r e d i t

-granting procedures that would create such credit.

N.M.C., Interviews, pp. kQ6-k07.

for example; Messrs. Mankiewicz and Blinzig of the Deutsche Bank told
the National Monetary Commission that "the great strength of our finan­
cial system in Germany is the Reichsbank.

Under that system the ques­

tion of our own cash reserve is of secondary importance, as we can at
n1i times convert our holdings of commercial paper into cash at the
Reichsbank."„ ( 2 )
Tz)

N.M.C., Interviews, pp. 373-375.
Similarly, Messrs. Schuster and Nathan of the Dresdner Bank

testified "...we are practically indifferent to the percentage (of cash
on hand and in the Reichsbank to deposit and acceptance liabilities) as
long as we know that we have on hand a sufficient amount of prime
bills., oIf we should have a debit in the Clearing House of more than
our cash in the Reichsbank, we would immediately send over bills with
our endorsements, and establish a credit sufficient to pay the amount
of our debit."
T5T—
th

Interviews, pp. 395-3 9 6 . They also said they regarded

elr b ills discounted" as a practical reserve - "it is immediately
convertible into cash at the Reichsbank."
Max Schinkel, testifying before the German Bank Inquiry in
1908

> contrasted the discount procedures of the Bank of England with

8e of the Reichsbank, and concluded "if the quality of the bill
sfies the Reichsbank, it takes any amount that is sent to it, at




the official r

+

..(D

o T T m X 9 German Bank Inquiry, Vol. I, pp. 377-378*
• u d g w e n t of Arthur Feiler, op* cit., pp. 1 1 - 1 2 .

This is also the

The contrast between these statements and those of J. W.
Gilbart, an English banker, with respect to the Bank of England after

the crisis of 1847, is illuminating.

Gilbart said;

"It will not be

safe for practical bankers to calculate w i t h too much confidence upon
the suspension of the Act (of l 8 ¥ 0 -

They should make their arrange­

ments on the supposition that it will not be suspended.” He also said:
"Banks should not only avoid depending on the Bank of England, or on

bill brokers; they should also avoid depending on other banks.

I2)

(2 )

J. W. Gilbart, A Practical Treatise on Banking, New York, lo51,
pp. 76 , 79-80 .
A practicing banker would not operate on the assumption that
a source of funds was absolutely reliable if he had known an occasion
when it had failed or had been contingent on meeting conditions unspeci­
fied in advance.

The confidence of German bankers undoubtedly was

based primarily on experience with the Reichsbank.

It was reenforced

by the Reichsbank's published acknowledgment of its responsibilities
as ^-en(ier of last resort.

Thus, when Vice President von Glasenapp and

Director von Lumm were asked what would happen if the Reichsbank’
s cash
eserve were to fall below the statutory minimum of one-third of Its
issue, they replied, "We should have to go on discounting bills.
ould simply have to do it.




We could not stop it.

If we did, it

uld bring about the greatest panic we ever experienced .

fl)

■

NoMc,Cc, Interviews, p. 35o* In its memorial volume the Bank, dis­
cing methods of control over its earning assets, said: "Since the
hank cannot without great harm capriciously decline applications for
c r e d i t that meet the requirements of the law, it is expected to regu­
late the demand for credit indirectly by determining the rate at which
it stands ready to grant credit." R-Bo I, p. 125- See also Karl von
Lubhh, Die Stellung der Notenbanken in der heutigen Volkswirtschaft,
Berlin, 1909, PP* 19“
20.




TtB-te Policy and the Cost of Credit

jjj

From its foundation to the First World War, the Reichsbank
lied primarily on its rate of rediscount to achieve its monetary obJectives<.

(1 )

In 1901 it expressed its judgment with respect to the

k / The following brief excerpts from statements on the rate by top
fficials during the whole period are illustrative s Von Dechend,
p r e s i d e n t 1876-1890, "One can secure respect for his currency only i f
he is not embarrassed really to increase the rate of discount until
pie see that one knows how to protect his metallic r e s e r v e SoB.,
l88l Volo I, p» 122. Koch, President 1890-1908, " 000An increase in
the rate is in fact the only effective means available to defend the
g o l d reserveo” S 0B 0, 1898-I9OO, Volo I I I , p» 2017° Eavenstein, Presi­
dent 1908-1923, "Bank rate00ois the only effective means to protect
the gold holdings of a c o u n t r y I t should be mentioned that Havenstein believed that the central bank would have to follow the market
rate and could influence it only within narrow limits„ S.B., 1907-1909.?
Vol. Ill, P« 2^13; Volo IX, p 0 7072c Von Glasenapp, Vice President,
and von Lumm, Director, "We increased the rate of discount. We consider that this measure is the only effective one<>” N 0M 0C 0, Interviews,
1910, p. 357°
rate in these words s

"The rate of interest is the only effective in­

strument for regulating the domestic demand for money„

It is not in­

deed the only instrument to influence the movement of metallic money
between home and foreign countries; but as all authorities acknowledge,
it is by all odds the most important and effective instrument „

described the operation of the rate in these words s

(2 )

It

"A high rate of

interest limits the applications for credit and operates on the one hand
•Gfcinst an excess of expansion of notes and on the other against an ex­
cessive reduction in the reserves of the Bauko.a »At the same time, a
-A

0I* ra^e offers a very favorable investment opportunity to interi°oal funds and is appropriate to draw gold from foreign countries




or

to

TIT

prevent

an export of gold to foreign countries.

„(!)

R .B. I, P- 125
The reserve ratio and market rates were the most important

guides to policy.

The Bank did not, however, follow any formula.

The

general level of reserves for example, was permitted to decline signi­
ficantly during the presidency of Richard Koch.
vbb expressed in these words:

The need for Judgment

"In determining the discount policy of

a central bank, account must be taken not only of the size but also of
the character of the monetary demands made of it.

An export of gold,

requires sharper countermeasures than a temporary withdrawal of gold
into domestic circulation.

A monetary demand based on over speculation

and overproduction requires sharper restrictions than a periodic in­
crease in monetary demand at the turn of the quarter or year which is
grounded in the whole structure of the normal process of payments.
These differences cannot be expressed, in numbers and therefore discount
policy cannot be regulated according to a purely mechanical prineiple."^
w
R . B . I. p .

126.

Although the management of the Bank probably would have sub­
scribed to this statement of principles throughout the period under
discussion, economic and monetary developments varied considerably.
It is convenient, therefore, to divide the entire period into intervals
^aSe<^ on the character of problems that confronted the management*

The

Period immediately following the establishment of the Bank was marked
^ l&I*
ge total reserves of which, however, only a smal 1 part was In the
°r®

gold.




As a result, the rate was changed frequently and

CH A RT

r EICHSBANK




RATE

AND

H

A

RELATED

1876-1885

FACTORS

CH A RT

REICHSBANK

AND

RELATED

FACTORS

1886-1895

METALLIC
RESERVE
RATIO




RATE

H B

REICHSBANK

RATE

H C

AND RELATED

FACTORS

1896-1905

METALLIC
RESERVE
RATIO




CHART

CHART

REICHSBANK

H

D

RATE AND RELATED FACTORS
1906-1914

METALLIC
RESERVE

INTEREST

RATES

RATIO




iv during this period in response not only to total reserves hut
}\)Ad.6iL**y

J.SO to the composition of reserves.
The second period began early in the l880’
s and lasted until
th middle l890's.

During this period the German economy was develop-

jjjg rather slowly and the Reichsbank was seeking ways to invest its

Only once was the rate increased beyond 5 per cent; the most
common

official rate was 3 per cent; and the Bank discounted exten­

sively at preferential rates as low as 2 per cent.
After the middle 18901s the German econoir^ entered a period
of unprecedented expansion.
and

A rate as low as 3 per c e n t became uncommon

rates beyond 5 per cent were frequent.

The Reichsbank did not, how­

ever,

increase its rate sufficiently to maintain its reserve ratio,

which

reflected progressive deterioration.
The last interval was ushered in by the crisis of 1907 which

led

to a parliamentary inquiry and extensive discussions of Reichsbank

policy, including methods of reinforcing discount policy.

HI*

A.

Aftermath of Monetary Reform
Otto Michaelis, a leading author -- with Ludwig Bamberger -- of

the German Bank Act of March 14, 1875s felt that the English principle of
limiting the fiduciary issue was sound, but that Peel's Act was too rigid
and provoked or aggravated panics when the fixed limit was approached.

He

ried to develop the principle into a semi-automatic rule for regulating bank
r&t6. TTo

proposed that each bank of issue be required to pay a tax at

the rate nf* ^

1

> P er cent per year on its fiduciary issue in excess of a

turn established for each such bank in the A c t .^
cluded^a 0ri^ na^ Pr°P°sal was more complicated.

The purpose of

For example, it in-

*8 a reve^r°VxS^0n ^or a ^ P er cent tax on the entire fiduciary issue

^ions thatUe~ra^S^n^ measure* "^ut this and a number of other conrplica■were not adopted are of less immediate interest.




~,r-ia-inn vas described in the —Motiven
this provisxui
---- - advanced in support of the

leg islation in the follow inS terms:
"The higher tax induces banks to counter a rising
demand of the money market with rising prices, as is
the natural rule on all other markets; it enables them through the higher discount rate, which pays the tax to meet the extraordinary demand which occasioned the
rise; it operates through the increase of discount
rates to attract capital and to moderate the speculative
spirit; finally it gives the banks an interest to con­
tract their issues within their normal limits as soon
as the extraordinary demand is past. By inducing banks
to timely increases in discount rates, the tax will tend
to moderate fluctuations in discount rates and without
any disturbing interference will counteract the danger­
ous tendency of trade to retain the expanded issue of
uncovered notes in circulation." (l)
S.B., 1875> Vol. Ill, p. 655’ By "higher tax,1* Michaelis meant the
5$ tax which he was contrasting with the ifo tax mentioned in the preceding
footnote. The emphasis on the word "timely” appears in the original. In
the same paragraph of the report emphasis is also placed on the effect of
the tax in gradually increasing pressure on the entire uncovered note issue.
The second independent clause is ambiguous: authority to issue additional
notes — not payment of a tax for the privilege — would enable the banks
to expand. It would be consistent with the general line of thought to in­
terpret this clause as follows: "Authority to issue taxable notes enables
the banks to meet the extraordinary demand without loss — because of the
high discount rate, but also without much profit ~~ because of the tax."
The semi-automat ic rule got off to a bad start*

It is not

clear that the management of the Reichsbank accepted the logic on which
it was based;

(2 )

but even if they had, the transition of Germany from

I* r — — — — —
H.
von Dechend, the prospective president, had not been asked to
testify«, In 1890, vice president - later president - R. Koch described
principle as "important, but of doubtful v a l u e S e e his Die
_eichsp:esetzgebung uber Munz-und Bankwesen, Berlin, 1890, p. 6l, note
•
Director von Lumm said the Bank had never been influenced in its
policy by the provision. See his "Diskontpolitik", p„ 135*
uOwlg Bamberger, secretary and influential member of the Reichstag
^®*ission on the Bank Act, opposed the idea. He favored giving the
Karl^R11611^
Reichsbank complete discretion. See his letter to
ferich, reproduced in part in the latter's introduction to
erger's Geld-und Bankwesen, p p c 73-7^*’




silver to a gold coin standard created difficulties (1 )

This transi-

X n c i d e n t a l l y , the president of the Reichsbank had favored b i ­
ll
ism. He d i d not believe that silver could be-demonetized per^nently* See Albrecht Sommer, Op. cit., pp« 100-125.

tion was facilitated and indeed made possible by the French indemnity,
but it was far from complete when the Reichsbank opened.

The method

adopted by the Reichsbank was to sell silver, received from circulation,
0n the London bullion market, and to use the proceeds for the purchase
of gold to be minted and paid into circulationr But there was a hitch
in the process. There was no fixed price for silver and the amount
that could be sold without disrupting the market vras far less than the

Reichsbank was acquiring<, As a consequence, silver replaced gold to a
considerable degree in the metallic reserves of the Reichsbank.,
W)

(2 )

a.B. I, pc lhl
Metallic keaerves of the R eichsbank
iMillion marks)
Amount on hand
Jan. 1, 1876
Total
Gold

3^6

78

Silver

100

22

Total

khS

100

Purchased

Sold

I876-I878

I 876 -I878

320
M+7

Amount on hand
Dec,31, I 878
of
Total

180

38

292

62

^72

100

la other words, net, the Reichsbank received Mb39 million of silver
0m circulation and paid M ^-86 million of gold into circulation.
The ratio of reserves to notes in the first decade is given in the
blowing table taken from R„B, I, p, 304o




On

Ratio of Reserves to Notes, 1876-1885

G OL D
Average

*
41.9
31.4

1876
1877
1878
1879
1880

33.3

1881
1882
1883
188^
1885

32-9
30.7

27.9
28.0
38.3
38.3

38.1

Lowest
Date
*

Highest
Date
i

2/29
■2/15

54.4
35-9

Ij-l.o
44,3
36.3
6/7
2/23 36.3
3/23 33.2
3/15 45.9
3/23
3/23

2/23
12/15

M E T A L L I C

46.2

47.7

12/31
12/31
1/7

iP/7
12/31
10/7
10/7
10/7
12/31
1/7

27.5
25 .O
25.7
22.5

23-8
18.7
20.9
29.1
26,2
27«3

1 Highest
Date
i

Average

7^-55
75.27
79.35
80.0
76.47
75.26

6/7
3/23
6/7
3/23
6/7
2/23
3/23
3/15
3 /7
6/7

73-49
81.64
90.74
80.57
... ......

86.4
83»3

88,2
96.3
84.9
88.4
84,8
93-8

92.8
91.2

Lowest
Date
*

62 >k
63.2
6k,9
i/7
65.6
10/7
12/31 64 c8
12/31 59-9
9/30 61,0
12/31 67-3
12/31 60.6
63*1
1/7

1/7
12/31

May 18, l879> the Chancellor suspended sales of sliver and compulsory
withdrawal from circulation of the remaining Thaler coins.

Commerce,

however, continued to turn in silver.
The Reichsbank also initiated practices to facilitate the
importation and to impede the exportation of gold.

(1 )

It facilitated

TT)----------------------R qB„ I , p . 146.

g o ld

imports by granting loans free of interest for 5 days, exception-

ally for 8 days, on them.

It also authorized some of its branches to

P®y premium prices for larger amounts of gold*

The official price was

Hi j392 per pound; but the management authorized payment of Ml, 393 for
®®ounts between M500,0G0 and M 2 million, and Ml,393^ for amounts over
with these minor encouragements to gold imports
di d

not confirm expectations when they were introduced; and it was




h rtly recognized that they could have only temporary success.

l)

R.B. I, P*

‘1

Therefore, interest free loans were granted only in special cases for

amounts of a million marks or more..

Premium prices were suspended in

1881.
The chief method of impeding exports was under certain cir­
cumstances

to require prospective exporters of gold to secure the metal

at the head office in Berlin rather than, as was usually permitted, at
the branches in Hamburg or Bremen*

This procedure increased costs of

exporters "by the charges for conveyance from Berlin to the port.

The

management insisted that it never refused to pay out gold in Berlin and
never charged a premium.

Bamberger alleged that the Bank had on occasion

imposed unnecessary technical difficulties in securing gold rapidly at

the head office, but this was denied by President von Dechend.
m —

(2 )

-----------—
S.B., l88l, Vol. I, pp. 122, 125-126,
The Reichsbank was confronted with a dilemma.

Its metallic

reserve ratio increased, its fiduciary note issue and earning assets
decreased, and the money market was easy.

Except for a "slow revival"

in 1877 and "recession" in early 1878 , Thorp describes the entire period
from 187^ into 1879 as one of "depression".
W. L. Thorp, Business Annals, New
a reduction in bank rate.

These forces pointed

York, 1926, pp. 208-209*

But the declining gold reserve, especially

i*1 a country that had only recently established the gold standard,

P inted to caution.




These conflicting considerations explain the

latively frequent changes in hank rate in the earlier years.

When

foreign exchange rates became unfavorable and the bank lost gold, it
its rate rapidly, at times far above open market rates.

raised

When

such p r e s s u r e s relaxed, the official rate was reduced to record low

(i)
levels.
The Prussian Bank had never reduced its rate below if per cent.
The R e i c h s b a n k reduced its rate to 3i per cent on May 1 8 , 1 8 7 6 , and to
3 per cent on March 2 1 , 1 8 7 9 .

HI.

b

. Easy Money and Preferential Rates
President von Dechend was concerned with the accumulation of

reserves in the Reichsbank.

In 1889, recalling earlier days, he said,

"You will remember that for many years we simply did not know what
would happen to the money that was accumulating in the Bank, so slight
were the opportunities for investment."

(2 )

XTj
S.B., 1889, Vol. I, p. 591.
He was particularly disturbed that foreign banks purchased
large amounts of the best bills without, of course, assuming any re­
sponsibility to make funds available in difficult times. Meanwhile,
the funds of the Reichsbank continued to grow and earnings became
smaller.
The core of the problem as he saw it was the independent banks
issue.

The Bank Act of 1875 allowed, these banks to continue, provided

met conditions that were formally similar to those Imposed on the
hsbank, including authorizations for tax free fiduciary issues of




notes•(l)
^ n u m b e r of banks relinquished the right to issue notes immediately

others did so subsequently. As these banks relinquished their
lights of issue, their contingents of tax free notes were added to that
of the Reichsbank.
One of the requirements of the Bank Act was that the Reichs­
bank

(§15 ) an<^- each independent bank of issue

of discount and its rate on collateral loans.

(§i|4)

publish its rate

In periods of slack busi­

ness and easy money - which was most of the time during the first two
decades of Reichsbank history - however,

these independent banks, fol­

lowing a full investment policy, actually bought bills at rates con­
siderably below their published rates.

As a result, they acquired bills

and the Reichsbank "lost contact with the open market" and acquired
"idle funds".

The Reichsbank complained to the Bundesrat, but after

the latter decided that the practice was admissible, the Reichsbank it­
self began in January 1880 to discount below its official rate in
. . .of easy money. (2)
periods
T?!President von Dechend said the independent banks based their case
on paragraph 13 , subparagraph 2, of the Act which authorized banks of
issue to buy and sell as well as to discount bills, whereas the para­
graph dealing with rates mentioned only the discount and the lombard
rates. Bamberger, who participated in the discussions that resulted
in the Bank Act, said that no one had thought at that time that the
Bank would discount below its official rate. The purchase provision
ad been included to facilitate dealings in very short bills for col­
ection, S.B., l88l, Vol. I, p. 121, von Dechend, and pp. 12^-125,
■Bamberger.

The practice was questioned almost immediately in the Reichstag.
In reply to Representative Bamberger who said the purpose of the manage­
ment waq +0

^0 secure earnings, President von Dechend said,

I can assure

that at no time and under no circumstances has the management of the




gank taken an action for the purpose of paying the highest possible
^ v id.e;QJis * °»But, gentlemen, I cannot be completely indifferent as to
yhether

funds of the Bank are employed or lie sterile in its vaults * .

^ I see it, the Reichsbank should not look for business but neither
should it decline a proper opportunity to invest its idle funds in
gafe, bankable paper.«(l)

The preferential rate was discussed in the Reichstag again
(2 )
on March 3, l88lo
Attention was focused particularly on the events
T S y —

SoBo, 1881, ¥o l0 I, pp« 118 »130 R
in August and September of 188O 0 Between June 28 and August 3* the
preferential rate had been reduced in four steps from 3j per cent to
2% per cent a Then, in two weeks, it was increased in three steps to
per cent before preferential purchases were discontinued on Septem­
ber 3o

The official rate was also increased from 4 to 5 per cent on

August 18 and to 5i per cent on September K.
Representatives Sonnemann and Bamberger said it would not
have been necessary to increase the official rate so much if the Bank
had not previously reduced the preferential rate so low In its zeal to
acquire bills<> President von Dechend replied that a rumor was being
circulated in August that the future of the mark was in danger« He
®*id,

One can secure respect for his currency only if he is not em-

^rrassed really to increase the rate of discount until people see that
/ wn V

knows how to protect his metallic reserve<.”




He said this principle had been proved in 1866 when, by inreasing the rate 2 per cent in one day, the Prussian Bank had dissi­
pated
gaid

fears as to the currency resulting from the outbreak of war.
that exchange rates had improved immediately.

He

The same results

vere achieved with the dramatic increase in rates in August and Septem­
ber of l880*

Within a few weeks the rate could again be reduced.

The Reichsbank was annoyed that independent banks of issue
competed

through issuance of their own notes to the tax free limit in

periods of easy money and then rediscounted at the Reichsbank - rather
than issue additional notes, which would have been taxed - when condi­
tions tightened.

Incidentally, the Reichsbank Commission which reported

on the initial draft of the Bank Act of 1875 anticipated that the inde­
pendent banks of issue, operating for profit, would probably not be
constrained by the tax on excess issues but that the Reichsbank, because

of its unique public character and responsibility, would not lose sight
of the principle on which the tax was based and would strive earnestly
to remain within the tax free limit.

(l)

ITT
S.B., 1875, Vol. k, p. 115^.
The Commission was correct in assigning different motives to

the Reichsbank and the independent banks of issue, but the results were
the reverse of those forecast * The independent banks generally followed
a

investment policy.

Instead of using their own taxable notes,

however, they found it more profitable to rediscount bills at the
Reichsbank.

The latter, placing its social objectives above profits,

^creased its rate to 5 per cent and even beyond at times when there
no prospect of exceeding the limit; and despite the tax, frequently
tained a rate below 5 per cent when its circulation exceeded the




limitvas

Its management, however, felt a sense of guilt when the limit

Qvr»peded frequently and by large amounts,
The full investment policy of the independent banks meant,

f course,

that the Reichsbank had to bear the full impact of varia-

(l)
tions in the volume of not es .

The Reichsbank did not see that their full investment policy
negatived

the power of the independent banks to expand or contract

against the wishes of the Reichsbank and thus promoted rather than
hindered its ability "to regulate the monetary circulation of the whole
Bnpire"

Instead, it said that the competition of the independent banks

provided the market with cheaper money than the Reichsbank felt was
justified.

But the reaction of the Reichsbank was to join in making

• -U-, (2 )
even more cheap money available.
T2)

~
“
Bamberger pointed this out in the R e i c h s t a g S B ,» iQQl, Vol«. X,
p. 12k,
—
'

Perhaps it confused the issue of control with another on

vhich it had ground for complaint. In effect, the law subsidized the in­
dependent banks-with an interest free loan in the amount of the tax
free fiduciary issue, but this was a question of earnings or equity
rather than of monetary control =
Much later the Reichsbank explained the introduction of the
eferential rate in these terms

**Only when its (the central b a n k ’
s)

°unts are large even in times of easy money can we be sure, in case
threatened drainage of gold or under other circumstances which
increase in interest rates desirable^ that it will be able to




r

B

I, P*
Director von Lumm was sharply critical of preferin his articles of 1912. See "Diskontpolitik", pp. 146-1^7.

err

of course, is as applicable to the official rate as to a preferential
rate.

There were additional reasons for establishing the preferen­
tial rate.
flooded
ly

One was a desire to acquire prime bills without being

with other bills.

Another was a desire to maintain a relative­

stable official rate.^2 ) Stability of official rates was one of the
ly. von Luimn, "Diskontpolitik", p. 146.

criteria frequently employed in judging the quality of central bank
managements.

The criterion was not applied to preferential rates which

were adjusted frequently to changing conditions in the money market.
Eventually the Reichsbank secured an agreement from the inde­
pendent banks that they would not discount below their official rates
when the Reichsbank indicated that it anticipated a loss of gold.
development was recognized in the law of June

J,

This

1899, which authorized

the Reichsbank to discount at preferential rates when the official rate
was not over 4 per cent and tied the discount rates of the independent
banks of issue loosely to Reichsbank rates.

By this time, however, the

long period of relatively easy money was over so that the Reichsbank
did not in fact continue a preferential rate after the privilege was




specifically granted "by lav.

(l)

Tbe move to tie the discount rates of the independent hanks of
sue to that of the Reichsbank was opposed vigorously by decentralizers
agricultural interests* See Martin Goldberg, Geschiclrte der deutschen
Munzgesetzgebung seit der ersten Erneurung des Reichsbank^
As a result of the amendment, three
banks relinquished their right of issue. Of the four remaining indepen­
dent banks of issue, three apparently were able to escape the intention
through a loophole in the law. The law did not bind lombard rates and
these banks loaned on. the collateral of bills at. lower rates rather than
discount at the rate bound to the Reichsbank rate. Nevertheless, their
business did not keep pace with that of the Reichsbank or of commercial
banks. See Ibid, pp. 109-112. See also K. von Lumm, "Diskontpolitik”,
p. 187*
In March 1884, the Reichsbank also established a preferential
lombard rate on Reich and State securities.

In part the purpose was to

facilitate investment in such securities and in part to secure earning
assets.

But the money market was easy and no rush to borrow ensued.

In the developing prosperity of 1889 and 1890, however, and again after

1895> the volume of collateral security loans increased rapidly and
total lombard loans even exceeded the established limit.

The preferen­

tial rate was removed on July 1, 1897j and the volume of lombard loans
declined.

HI*

C.

Prolonged Prosperity
The general background of Reichsbank policy changed signifi­

cantly in the middle 18901s .
commercial expansion.

Germany began an unprecedented industrial

In modern terminology, investment - includ­

ing long-term foreign investment - exceeded domestic savings»
These underlying forces were reflected in many money market
Actors.

Baak rate rose to higher levels.

From 1886 to 1898 the offi-

rate was as low as 3 per cent in all years save 1890, and the




rential rate was frequently as low as 2 per cent.
preic

The preferential

te was abandoned in 1896, and after 1899 the official rate was reduced
below b per cent in only three years (1902, 1905, and 1909)*

Further-

money rates were generally higher in Berlin than in London and
•d r 1*q- foreign exchange rates on major money centers became unfavorable
more frequently; and Germany became increasingly indebted at short
tenn*^1 ^

expansion was financed also in part by newly created m o ne y.

See Hans Ueisser, "Der Internationale Geldmarkt vor und nach dem
Kriege" in Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 1929> PP- 171* - 226*. On m a r ­
ket rates of interest, see the seasonal chart on p. 214*. Annual aver­
ages are shown in N.M.C., Financial Diagrams, Plate 9* On central bank
rates, see Plate 10. Direct comparisons between official central bank
rates should be used with caution because discount procedures varied
and because of lack of uniformity in the instruments to which the sever­
al rates applied, Palgrave labels his elaborate tables in Bank Rate
and the Money Market, New York, 1903^ "minimum" rate; but his averages
are computed from official or public rates - at least for the Reichs­
bank for which I made sample verifications. On exchange rates, see
R.B. II, pp« 210-211. On short-term indebtedness, see EnqueteAusschuss, Die deutsche Zahlungsbilanz, Berlin, 1930, pp. 130-133*
Reichsbank notes increased more rapidly than reserves, despite rapid
development in the i^se of checks (.giro); 'the .reserve ratio decreased.
These developments led to a subtle and gradual change of
emphasis by the management of the Reichsbank in its discussions of what
it considered its basic problems.

During the period of easy money, the

Reichsbank had large reseryes and the major complaint was inability to
secure adequate earning assets because of the competition of the inde­
pendent banks of issue.

It also objected that these banks assumed no

responsibility for assuring convertibility; but this aspect received
^esB emphasis.

As the reserve ratio decreased, emphasis gradually

lifted from earnings to convertibility,

What was considered excessive

^Petition of banks - by now, the so-called "great" commercial banks V & s S 1"i 1 1

a

deplored, but the emphasis was on their failure to contribute




dequately -- by maintaining larger reserves -- to the costs of maintain­
ing convertibility.
Instead of these complaints, a logician might have anticipated that

the general theory of the management would have led it to adopt still lower
rates over the period of easy money and still higher rates after the mid-1890's.
Actually it seems to me that, though the management generally believed, it did
not really comprehend and therefore follow consistently the theory professed by
its vocal and literary representatives.

Lack of comprehension was rooted in

failure to distinguish between utilization of real resources on the one hand
and of monetary resources on the other.

As a consequence, day-to-day decisions

were influenced by empirical notions of "just price*' and of political expediency.
In retrospect one feels at times that expressed principles were an obscuring
facade rather than a comprehensible rationalization.

The Reichsbank did not

reduce its official rate still more in the 1 8 8 0 ’
s primarily because the manage­
ment felt it had already gone as far as could reasonably be expected in this
direction by reducing its rate to record low levels.

It did not maintain a

higher rate level after the middle 1890*s, partly because it was unduly
sensitive to the common criticism that its rate was already higher than those

of other central banks with which it liked to be compared, but primarily b e ­
cause of developments in the seasonal demand for currency.
Seasonal Variations
So important were seasonal variations in monetary phenomena
that a brief analysis of them is essential to understanding Reichsbank
Policy during this period.
the German people.

The problem arose out of the payment habits

Before the First World War it had been customary

0 Pay rents, social insurance premiums, fees for professional services,
uition, interest on mortgages, salaries, and even some wages on a
Quarterly basis and in cash.




In the fall and winter additional cash

was

tice
ublication

of their year-end balance sheets.

gee my, "Der Geldumlauf in Deutschland1' in Bankwissenschaf t,
Berlin, 1933, Vol. 10, pp. 257-264.
Given these habits, seasonal variations in interest rates,
cash in circulation, or both were bound to occur.

The advantage

of

an elastic currency to meet temporary needs was widely discussed and
What is more important, the management of the

12T

See, for example, J. Landmann, System der Diskontpolitik, Kiel #nd
Leipzig, 1900, pp^ 126-130; K. Helfferich, Studien fiber Geld-und Bankwesen, Berlin, 1900, pp> 165-167 , 213-218; F. Bendixen, Geld und Kapital,
Jena7'i922, pp. 146-149, 158-162, 166-182; J. Plenge, Diskontpolitik,
pp. 166-172, 379-380.
Reichsbank was aware that, to cite its own words, "There can be no doubt
that no limitation of note issue could prevent the Reichsbank from
satisfying the fluctuations of money demand, rooted as these fluctua-

tions are in our economic life *" (3)
T3T

R*Bc I , p, 218,
Nevertheless, it is clear that the Reichsbank, especially for
the period 1886 to 1912, responded to these seasonal variations by increasing its rate in the fall and decreasing it after the turn of the
During this period, the Reichsbank decreased its rate 51 times

year,

increased it 4 5 timese Of the decreases, only 1 was in the second
k*1** of the year (from 5J to 5 per cent in July 1900); of the increases
5 vere in the first half of the year (from 3 to k per cent in May
May 1893, and April 1898; from 4- to kj* per cent in June 1899j and
fr°
m ^

to k Per cent in June 1903).




Of the 51 decreases, 19 were in

January

and 19 in February; of the 45 increases, 11 were in September, 15 in

October, and 7 in November.

There were only 4 years without a reduction in

either January or February, and only 8 years without an increase in either
September or O c t o b e r / 1 ^

In 1911 the Reichsbank published an analysis of

T I T The seasonal ebb and flow of pressure was at times even greater
than that revealed by these data. Discounting at the private rate, for
example, was made more expensive or even suspended at times when seasonal
demands for currency were heavy.

the causes that induced it to increase its rate.

Of the 42 increases from

1886 to 1910, only 4 were attributed to loss of gold or unfavorable exchanges,
25 to increased domestic demand for money and 13 to a combination.
R»B» 11? P* 222.

(2 )

See also details on pp. 214-221.

The corresponding figures for the period 1876-1885 were 9 because of external
factors, 3 because of internal factors, and 4 because of a combination.
The enthusiasm aroused when one first sees these tables is dissi­
pated by study of the role of the Reichsbank.

Initially one feels that he

is being taken behind the scenes to observe the actual determination of
policy.

After comparing the detailed table with other information, one

concludes that it is merely a tabulation of some of the easily ascertainable
objective facts that were relevant.

It does not include all of these.

T51- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

For example, Havenstein, S.B., 1908, Vol.229, pp. 2413-2415, said
t an important reason for not reducing the rate in 1908 was that the
e of new bills drawn was so large, but that magnitude is not given
ln the table.

The tables are not without value, however.

f0

example, relates only to increases in the rate.




The summary table,
This helps confirm a

dgment reached on the basis of other information that the Reichsbank
^

called

upon to justify increases but not decreases in its rate.

One is tempted to fall into the trap that caught the management of the

Bank in drawing conclusions from the tables.
that domestic developments gradually became
national developments less important.

One such conclusion is
more important and inter­

The basic problem of the

Reichsbank after the middle 1890's, however, arose from the fact that

Germany developed more rapidly than most other countries.

If one has

arrived at this judgment in advance, the detailed table will confirm it
by showing that the Reichsbank reserve ratio declined even though its
rate almost uniformly was higher than the other rates listed.

however, one does not start with this judgment —

If,

which comes from

comparisons over long periods rather than comparisons from rate change to
rate change on which the tables focus attention —

one is apt to conclude

that the rising domestic demand for currency alone was the important
development.

The basic problem was obscured because, though the manage­

ment knew much about seasonal variations, it did not comprehend their real

significance —




or lack of it —

for monetary policy.

What extenuating circumstances account for such seasonal
variations in bank rate despite the professed principle of elasticity?
perhaps most important was an inability to adjust to the speed with
v b i c h most economic magnitudes were increasing.

Growth was so rapid

that almost every fall the Reichsbank seemed to be confronted with
something more t h a n a seasonal increase in currency, especially because
atten ti o n was directed to the absolute amount rather than ratio to

trend.

Even as astute an observer as Karl Helfferich greatly under­

estim a te d the rate at which the circulation would increase in the first

decade of the twentieth century..

(i)

At the same time, the management

In commenting on the increase in the tax-free fiduciary issue from

293.U to ^50 million, effective January 1, 1901, he judged that it

would not be necessary in the ensuing decade to exceed the limit as
frequently or in as large amounts as had been necessary befor e. K.».
Helfferich, Pp., cit,, p» 218. Yet by 1906 the amount and irk.1907 the
frequency of taxable issues established new records. Helfferich was
fully aware that Micha^lis, the father of the Bank Act, had greatly
underestimated the eventual expansion in circulation when the original
limit was established. See Ibid,, pp. 15^- 160, 167-173°
was not insensitive to the running criticism because its rate was always
above that of the Bank of France and usually above that of the Bank of
England.

It tried to keep its rate as low as possible and reduced it

as soon as it thought it could; that was usually when currency began
to return after the turn of the year 0
Another factor in the autumnal rise in rates was the fear of
e management that the large increase in circulation might imperil
ready convertibility of notes into specie.

They were particularly con­

cerned as to the consequences if a large sudden demand were to coincide




kQ .

with the seasonal peak.

(l)

rphe threat or outbreak of war was one such emergency they had in
v iron T.nmm. D i p S+,e=>l 1•nru? dpr Nnt.pn’
hankpn. na.f5sim. pan.

A** Ueltkriegs, rauuxuii CL1XU. xjcxj^^s, A.y.v.y, jj. |- eu. ujajxc wj.xuucu xu.
^
iUi a,ilc^dote is told that during the Morocco crisis the Kaiser
asked several banking and financial authorities whether Germany could
finance a war with a major power. The apparent answer was a weak,
apologetic "no".
The Kaiser is reputed to have replied: "When I ask
v o u this question again, gentlemen, I expect a different answer,"
D i e Bank, 1912, P° 286 0
A related factor was the concern of the management with the
legal limitations on note issue.

Increases in the circulation took

the form of Reichsbank notes, Treasury notes, and coin, and therefore
had a dual impact on both the reserve ratio and the fiduciary issue.
The management was not sympathetic with the fiduciary limit, but it
was restive because it knew that frequent and large issues of taxable
notes

violated the spirit and intention of the law.

On the other

hand, it was very much concerned about the reserve ratio, even when it
exceeded the legal minimum; it was particularly concerned about the
gold reserve ratio concerning which there was no legal minimum as such.
There were many proposals and the Reichsbank introduced a

number of new procedures to deal with the quarterly drain.-

To under­

stand the changes in procedures it is necessary to recall several
in it ia l differences between the two basic means of access to the
Reichsbank:

discounting and borrowing on collateral or lombarding,

Relevant differences were:

first, that the rate on loans was \ to 1

cent higher than the discount rate; second, that funds initially
ould be borrowed for the exact period that they were needed, whereas
ill had to be discounted to maturity; and third, that the Reichsbank




uid u se discounts but not lombard paper as collateral for its notes
n u vhs based on and the management believed in the "real bills'*
the ia>'
doctrine.
Under these conditions, banks tended to discount their short
bills and to borrow rather than discount longer bills to.meet the quar­
terly d r a i n / T o discourage borrowing, the Reichsbank changed its
^
Of course, they also discounted long bills when they expected a
rise in the discount rate. See my "Die Politik der Deutschen Reichs­
bank seit der Stabilisierung” in Weltwirtschaftliches Arctiiv, Vol. k 2 ,
1935> P* ^ 9 , note 2,
procedure, in the l880 's by charging a minimum of three d a y s ’interest
on loans extended on the last four and the first business day ,o f each
month.

In l88l the minimum was increased to 5 and later to 8 dayso

In 1887 the minimum interest charge for borrowing that began during the
quarterly drain was set at

lk

(2 )
days 8
The results did not exactly

m -------- —
—
—
R.B, I, p. 116.
meet expectations.

The banks continued to borrow; but since they needed

the funds for only 3 or 4 ‘
days, they promptly reloaned them for the en­
suing 6 or 7 days as call money.

As a consequence, the strains at the

end of the quarter were not relieved but were followed immediately by
extreme ease in the money market.

Apparently the practice was abandoned

for a time; it was reintroduced in March 1905. ^
TT5---------- ------------P-B. Ill, p. 26
Discussion of seasonal variations continued especially when
neval of the Reichsbank charter was under consideration,
&O1B0

The nature

ji
tne proposals is reflect,ed in one of the limited number of




estions

on which witnesses were asked to. testify in the Bank Inquiry

of 1908:
Question V. Is it desirable to take into consideration
—
a diminution of the demands on the Reichsbank?
A.

Through a diminution of the credit demands of ljusiness,
especially at the quarterly periods? What measures
might be taken to cause a spreading out of the quar­
terly requirements by altering the time of payments
(mortgage-payments, salaries, rents) which tradition­
ally fall due on the first day of the quarter? Would
it be desirable to enhance the cost of obtaining money
from the Reichsbank on collateral security, at the
close of the quarter, by increasing the number of days
for which interest is charged? (l)

T O N.M.C«, German Bank Inquiry of 190o, Vol. I, Washington, 1910,
p* 8 and passim.
Almost without exception the witnesses testified that limited
success could be expected from efforts to change the habits of the
people, and they opposed the proposal to make borrowing more expensive
at quarter days.
As a result of the inquiry the system of the fiduciary limit
was modified to allow for seasonal variations by establishing two magni­
tudes, one of which (M750 million) was applicable to the quarterly
periods and the other (M550 million) was applicable at other times.

In

principle this made some sense, but since the difference (M200 million)
was less than the actual swing in circulation, the quarterly limit was
the more restrictive.
G. H. Loewy, a banker, thereupon revived the suggestion that
been so generally opposed in 1908 that the cost of lombard loans be
increased at the quarter days.

He suggested that the pressure be limited

borrowing because he accepted the self-liquidating theory of commerCijLl

Paper and because the law did not admit lombard loans as collateral




for notes.
C

H

This suggestion was followed by the Reichsbank

Loewy, "Der Zinsfuss im Lombardverkehr der Reichsbank" in
Nov. 15, 1910, pp. 61 -62 .

jjay 1911 when it established a new rule on borrowings in excess of
(2 )
yQO 000 that spanned the "quarter days".
The new rule required

7*2 )
R.B. Ill, P- 2 6 *
that in general interest must be paid for ten days in addition to the
period for which the funds were actually borrowed. Again the results
were somewhat unexpected.

The demands on the Reichsbank - to use the

phrase of the Bank Inquiry - were not reduced.

The new policy made

borrowing after the 27th so expensive that banks shifted to discounting
bills even though they secured funds for a longer period than they desired them,

(3)

as is shown in the following table..

To some extent

m

Die Bank, 1911, P* 532, contains a statement that "before the
change of June 1911 a bank would prefer to lombard for 10 days at 5 per
cent rather than discount for 20 days at 4 per cent; after the change
it would be cheaper to discount for 20 or even 30 days at 4 per cent
rather than lombard for 4 days at an effective rate of 17 ^ per cent.
(it must be remembered that the bank could relend the proceeds of the
discount for 16 or 2 6 days*) See also, Die Bank, 1912, p. 109°
banks also borrowed on the 27 th in anticipation of needs.

As a conse­

quence, borrowing increased earlier and the monetary ease which followed
the quarter days continued for a longer period.

Furthermore, the great

differences between costs of borrowing at the end of the quarter and at
other times made the maturity date of bills important and led to dif­
ferential rates.

Whereas formerly all bills with a maturity between

and 90 days were discounted at the same rate in the market, schedules
ates were now established based on the maturity dates of the bills.




p-iscounts and Loans at the Reichsbank before and after
‘
—
the Change of Policy in June 1911
(Unit:

M 1,000,000)

Before the Change
Loans
Discounts

----------

1910 June 23

837

76

256
120

30
July 7

1,188
1,036

Sept. 23
3P
Oct. 7

1,112
1,53*+
1,3^

210

Dec. 23
30
1911 Jan. 7

1,052

96

1,106

371
117

Ma r, 23
30
Apr. 7

890

1,324

1,315
1,130

After the Change
Discounts
Loans

1911

70
117

60
261
125

1912

June 23
30
Ju]^ 7

1,163

Sept* 23
30
Oct. 7

1,247
1,785
1,511

D e c . 23
30
Jan, 7

1,389
1,793
1,566

117

Mar, 23
30
Apr 0 7

1,075
1,652
1,458

64
ill
78

92k
1,355

55
7^56
51
91

63
69
69

It should perhaps be mentioned that the Reichsbank did not
adopt the subsequent suggestion of Mr. Loewy that it increase the difficulty of discounting short bills before the quarter drain*

(1 )

Could it

TT]
"Diskontpolitik" in Bank Archiv, August 15, 1912, pp. 357* 3^ 0 ,
especially p. 358- For suggestion of N. E» Weill that the Treasury
issue M600 million of notes at quarter days, see "Reichsbank und
Kreditbanken" in Bank Archiv, May 1, 1912, pp» 235-24-2 „ For a criticism
of this proposal, see J, Plenge, Diskontpolitik, pp= 167 , 3 8 0 , Most
®odern analysts would probably agree with Plenge’
s general judgment
j
7 ) on most of the suggestions for dealing with the quarterly
n.„*alles vergebliche Muhe!”

^e» that it appreciated that to do so would have placed it in the anomalous
P sition of agreeing that the expansion in currency had to be permitted and
y t of making more difficult each successive method employed by the economy

secure the currency?




2 „ Other Facets of Policy
Although the discount rate remained the primary instrument of
v the management was disturbed by the persistent reduction in its
policy)
reserve ratio and coniplaints that its rate was generally higher than it

had been before the middle 1890’
s and higher than rates at the Bank of
gngland and especially at the Bank of France.
fore

The Reichsbank, there­

initiated certain changes in operations and in legislation to r e ­

inforce the effectiveness of its rate policy and to increase its r e ­
serves-

Just after the turn of the century it was also confronted with

a domestic crisis in confidence.
(a)

Crisis operations
The Reichsbank discharged its obligation as lender

of last resort in the series of bank failures that culminated in June
1901 in the failures of the Credit institute for Industry and Trade in
Dresden and of the Bank of Leipzig*

Runs developed on many banks.

The

Reichsbank discounted and loaned liberally to enable other banks to
maintain payments and participate in appropriate supporting actions»
It maintained its official rate at 3\ P er cent, to which it had been
reduced on June 18, despite an unprecedented increase of M 323 million
(to Ml, 175 million) in earning assets and a decrease of over M1Q0
Million (to M900 million) in reserves during the last week of June.
(b)

Open Market operations
Before the turn of the century, the German govern-

aent occasionally borrowed from the Reichsbank in small amounts and for
hort periods through the medium of Treasury bills.
e®ker 1900, the amounts were increased.

Beginning in Sep-

The first large extension of

dit to the government was liquidated from the proceeds of the Reich
611

April 1901.




In the ensuing years, however, the government was

n v a continuous borrower from the Bank in widely varying amounts
virtuaiiy »
Up tO

11200-^-00 million, exceptionally even up

to M500 million.

<jhe maximum of discounts was in the order of M 2 billion,

1

In February 1901, the Reichsbanfe for the first time
sold soi’
i3 of these bills to influence market rates of discount.

In

its official memorial volume published in 1925, the Reiehs'bank explained
this early operation as follows:

MBy means of rediscounting Treasury

bills* it was possible for the Reichsbank to withdraw money from the
market and thereby force up private rates when it appeared to the Bank
that they were being held artificially low.

In this way the Reichsbank,

while simultaneously relieving its own position, could increase the in­
fluence of'bank rate on foreign exchange rates and thereby, under cer(2 )
tain conditions, smooth the way for a reduction in its rate,’
*

151---------R.B. Ill, p. ,10.
Ordinarily sales of securities b y central banks are associated

with increases in the rate.

It seems contradictory to sell securities,

forcing market rates u p , to "smooth the w a y 1' for a reduction in bank
rate,

Apparently the actions of the Reichsbank were based on a concern

for its own position, primarily its reserve ratio.

Sales of Treasury

hills would tend to increase the reserve ratio: by reducing liabilities,,
An increase in market rates would tend to make Berlin a less attractive
aarket in which to borrow and a more attractive market in which to lend.,

would. thus attract international funds for investment.,

To the extent

the^e funds took the form of gold, reserves would rise and the re80j*Y0 -p 1 .
a 1(*- w°uld be increased still further, A high reserve ratio

tVlQn enablfe the Bank to lower its rate.



Apparently the Reichsbank feared that an initial reduction
its rate - which would seem to be a direct approach to the problem w ou l d drive market rates still lower*

Since its desire was to reduce

the differential between hank rate and market rates and to attract gold,
it began the process by forcing up market rates.

Although the Bank said

this operation in 1901 was successful, it admitted - without realizing
the implications - that the increase in the reserve ratio was caused
primarily by a return flow of funds from internal circulation 0

In other

words, it was seasonal in character as is shown in Section III-C-1.
The Reichsbank explained the open market policy of 1905 in
more conventional terms.

Treasury bills were sold ’
’
under suitable cir­

cumstances to counteract anticipated tension in its own condition with­
out resorting immediately to an increase in the rate»” In other words,
sales of securities supported bank rate or smoothed the way for an
increase - rather than a decrease.
Although the Reichsbank sold securities from time to time to
withdraw funds from the market, it did not have a continually firm con­
trol over its investment portfolio.

Apparently it had little or no

choice in acquiring Treasury bills.

It acquired them at the official

rate when the government needed f u n d s T h i s meant in effect that
RoB, h i , pp. 12 , 19;
diskontpolitik”, *pv l48«

ILMoCoj Interviews, p. 3^+9,

K. von Lumm,

the market had access to Reichsbank credit without the necessity of
discounting.

As the Treasury spent the funds it had borrowed from the

Reichsbank, they became available to the market*

It should not be in­

erred, however, that discounts and Treasury bill holdings varied insely.

Frequently bill holdings increased when the seasonal demand




f r currency rose.

Discounts then increased also, but not as much as

0uld have been the case if holdings of Treasury securities had re­
mained constant.

The Reichsbank did not have complete control over r e ­

ductions in its portfolio.

The government could take the initiative in

this direction by repayment from tax receipts or the proceeds of refund­
ing operations*
(c)

Devisen policy
Until 1898 the Reichsbank dealt in foreign exchange

primarily to enable its non-banking customers to buy and sell foreign
(1 )
monies at all its branches.

In that year it began to accumulate

ITT

This is the reason given in R.B., III, p. 37* From the relatively
large holdings shown in R.B. II, p p . 158-159, and from the introduction
of the preferential rate on prime bills, it seems not unlikely that
earnings or some other factors were also involved from, say, 1880 to
1887. Thereafter until. 1898, however, the portfolio was small - from
M2 to M3 million as contrasted with an average of 17 million and a high
of 31 million in 1886, The new policies inaugurated in 1898 and 1908
are reflected clearly in the data.
long bills in foreign currencies and deposits with foreign correspon­
dents - primarily English - to be in position to influence foreign ex­
change rates, especially through sales to prevent them from reaching
the gold export point.

Under this new policy both the portfolio of

foreign bills and correspondent balances were greatly increased« Aver­
age bill holdings of 1907 were M 44 million and average balances were
M20 million. The Reichsbank drew heavily on these foreign assets in the
crisis of 1907 .
(d)

Issuance of small notes
At the time of the Morocco crisis in 1905; the paper

m°
ney of Germany consisted of bank notes with a minimum denomination of
and Imperial Treasury notes in denominations of M5, M 20, and M 5 0 ,




The

total issue of Treasury notes, however, was limited to M120 million,

^ amount that had not been changed since January 1, 1891 = Primarily

as a result of this limitation, most of the money of these denomina­
tions was in the form of gold coinso

The Morocco crisis created a favor­

able atmosphere for the Reichsbank to secure authority to issue notes of
gmaller denominations. On February 20, 1906, it was authorized to issue
notes

in denominations of M20 and M50.

On June 5, 1906, Imperial

Treasury notes of these denominations were discontinued and the Treasury
was authorized to issue notes of M10 as well as M5»

Parliamentary opponents

insisted on a limitation of M300 million on the total of small notes; but
the chancellor relieved the Bank of this restriction on quarterly days
after 1911 until the limit was removed by law in 191 .3 * ^

ID

~

The story of the episode is given in M. Goldberg, b p > cite,
pp. 129-13^' There were widespread differences of opinion concerning
the nature, advantages, disadvantages, and implications of the issuance
of Email notes to replace gold coin in the domestic circulation, Con­
trast, for example, J* Plenge, op, cit», pp» 142-150 with G* von
Schulze-Gaevernitz, op. cit-, pp« l8 o-l 8l«.
(e)

Increasing minimum clearing balances
In October 1906, as reserves declined and the rate

was increased, the Reichsbank, in an attempt to attract cash, increased
the minimum balances required of the customers who used its clearing
(giro) system.

It also announced that the Head Office would henceforth

establish uniform rules concerning such minimum balances, rather than
leave them to be determined by the branches ,

One factor in establishi­

n g the minimum was the average volume of transfers (by red checks);
the other was the earnings of the Reichsbank from the discount and lomrd business done with the customer»

The first factor, it might be

tioned, was akin to a reserve requirement based on debits to the
a°count 5



Dr. Koch probably was led to this move because he was an
, • p. expert in the field of collections.
He was probably thinkopc^’
^'
about securing compensation for the services rendered by the
ing
iChSbank rather than about monetary control. What he saw was a per-

siStent increase in the debits and credits per mark of average clearing

balance from 237 in 18?6 to 494 in 1906; or, in other words, a decline
from three days to one day in the average period for which a deposit

remained in the account.

1

r.B. Ill, Appendix pp. 48-49

We do not have frequent periodic data to establish the effects
of the new policy.

We do know, however, that although the sum of the

minimum private clearing balances increased from M82 million on Septem­
ber 15, 1906, to M114 million on March 31> 1908, the total private
clearing balances over the same period decreased from M288 million to
(o\
M260 million, although "float” increased by M34 million.
Perhaps some
T 2T
R.B. Ill, Appendix pp. 5^-57■

private customers felt they had been carrying excessive balances until
application of the new rules taught them what a "reasonable" balance was,
and
(3)
n Perhaps others found the new procedure too expensive.

753- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

nuiriber of private accounts continued to increase after
Feiie° nea^ly as rapidly as before. R.B. Ill, Appendix p. 48. Arthur
Systprr
wany large institutions inaugurated a special clearing
throu
t3lemsel'ves and that other clearing customers sent payments
the postal
—j
- ■ pp. 29-30*
— —
system. O-p . cit.,




jjj-

d

. Crises and Reappraisal of Policy
The tight money markets in the winters of 1906 and 1907^ ^

Bank rate was increased to 7 per cent on December 18, 1906, and to
pgr cent on November 8 , 1907* as a consequence of the money panic in
the United States.
1

fanned

into flame smoldering dissatisfaction with the management of the

Reichsbank.

Reactions were prompt.

On January 8, 1908, Dr. Havenstein,

President

of the Seehandlung (Prussian State Bank) replaced Dr. Koch as

President

of the Reichsbank.

On January ±h, the government announced

that it would launch an inquiry into the German banking system*

(2 )

12)

The announcement Was in response to an interrogation made of the
chancellor on November 22, 1907* by Count von Kanitz as to what he p r o ­
posed to do to counteract the inconveniences resulting from the exist­
ing high rate of discount at the Reichsbank. The Reichsbank prepared
a six-point outline to guide the discussions. The inquiry was conducted
by a commission consisting of Havenstein as chairman, von Glasenapp,
Vice President of the Reichsbank, as vice chairman, and twenty-three
members selected from German banking, industry, trade, and education.
Representatives of the Imperial and State governments attended the meet­
ings. Translations of the proceedings of the full commission were
published in two volumes by N*M.C*, German Bank Inquiry of 1908, The
outline is published on pp. 7*8 of Volume I. A brief summary of the
work of the commission and of the amendments to the Bank Act influenced
by it are given in R*B* III, pp. 26-3*+. See also M. Goldberg, o>p° cit,
------PP. 136-156, 166-1737----- The new president gave the Reichs'tag'.'.his views on bank rate
in the following words

1

"it is not the policy of a central bank which makes the
discount rate, rather, bank rate is essentially deter­
mined by the economic circumstances of a country. In
the first instance it is dependent on the country's
capital and credit conditions, and on its position in
the yorld economy, and therefore on the conditions in
the international money market. In this connection,
bank rate is also the only effective means to protect
the country's gold reserve against domestic as well as
foreign withdrawals that are unjustified, not required
by economic conditions, or dangerous. I emphasize
repeatedly, therefore, that the central bank, in its




interest and discount rate, can generally only follow
the rate in the money market. It can affirm the market
rate Taut cannot determine it* Only under certain cir­
cumstances and within measurable limits can it influence
the market rate." (l)
1907-1909, Vol. Ill, p. 2413; of. Vol. IX, p. 7072.
The phraseology as well as the ideas are reminiscent of the
testimony of the regents of the Bank of France before the parliamentary
(2 )
inquiry in 1865, with which Havenstein undoubtedly was familiar,

12)

’ "
See my "Die Politik der Deutschen Reichsbank seit der Stabilisierung"
j_n Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. k-2, p. ^ 67 , and "Bank of France
Pnlicv" in The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Volo 11,
1952, pp.

238-239.

~

~

—

-

-

-

This approach probably explains why the Reichsbank did not launch a
frontal attack on what it considered the two basic aspects of its
problem.

These aspects were to increase the gold reserve of the bank­

ing system - especially that of the Reichsbank - and the influence of
the Reichsbank in the money market.

A frontal attack would have in­

volved granting credit somewhat less liberallya

Specifically, the

Reichsbank might have kept the money market under firmer control by not
reducing its rate so promptly in the summer.
prevented market rates from falling so low.

Such a program would have
Instead, however, the

Reichsbank tried to compete with the market by reducing its own rate,
3y adding funds when the market already had a plethora, it tended to
viden - rather than narrow - the spread between the bank rate and the
Market rate on prime bills.

Perhaps the chief reason for not adopting

this frontal attack was that the Reichsbank confused monetary policy
ith credit policy.

This confusion is reflected in the reasons advanced

the many-sided but unintegrated program of reform proposed for the
rman monetary and banking system.




There was widespread, though not of course unanimous, agreement
issues.
on a number of
uj.
tender.

The purpose, as in the case of issuing notes of smaller

ominations,

vas

recognized

payment,

but

One of these was to make notes of the Reichsbank

was to draw gold from circulation into the Reichsbank.

It

that Reichsbank notes were in fact accepted as a means of
was felt that a crisis might bring with it refusals to

it

accept them and that making them legal tender during a crisis might not
only take time

but

also aggravate the crisis.

The notes were made legal

tender on January 1, 1910.
A second point on which there was general agreement was that the

Reichsbank should pursue a more active gold policy, tolerating if not pro­
moting a wider variation in the effective price of gold.

It was recognized

that relatively little could be accomplished without raising doubts as to
the monetary standard.

At the same time, it was felt that judicious exten­

sion of loans free of interest could at times bring to Germany gold that
might otherwise go elsewhere.
promoting gold imports in 1901.

Such loans had been considered effective in
Another practice viewed with favor was the

payment of slight premiums on gold bars and foreign gold coins.

The Reichs­

bank began a rather aggressive policy in this regard and began to show con­
siderable losses for the first time in its gold operations.
TT3------- ---------------

M1 7 -*^* ^ • PP* 3^+-35* Profits on gold operations had varied between
lQn \
^ an(^ M221,000 (1892 ). During the entire 32-year period (1876 lQoft total profits were Ml,227,000. Losses from gold operations in
In t 1 9 0 9 ’and 1910 Were ^ 7 , 0 0 0 , Ml67,000, and M128,000, respectively.
_ ° er wo:rds, the losses in these three years wiped out half of the
its of the preceding 32 years.
Light weight coins also were delivered to gold exporters.
°ther hand, neither significant departures from par such as were
/ed by the Bank of France which could redeem in silver, nor the




On

ation of a gold market, such as existed in London, was recommended,'
v r 7. Schilling* Uber die Frage der Errichtung eines deutschen
^idmarktes, Karlsruhe, 1913Such minor blemishes on the simon pure gold standard as were
adopted

were among the curiosities of the years preceding the First

World War.

Central banks used them to compete against each other to

attract and retain gold.

Yet collectively they tended to cancel each

other so far as the distribution of gold was concerned.

For example,

the effort of one central bank to retain gold by paying out light

weight coins could be nullified by the premium prices paid by the
recipient central b a n k .
Another recommendation was that the Reichsbank develop still
more its devisen policy.

It will be recalled that liquidation of a

substantial part of its holdings had proved useful

in the crisis of

1907* The Reichsbank, therefore, created a foreign exchange depart­
ment whose director attended the exchange to supervise the determina­
tion of rates.

It also increased further its own operations.

Director

von Lumm cited as another reason the desire to have a defensive measure
against possible liquidation by foreign banks, especially central banks,
of their large and

(2 )

rising portfolios of mark bi ll s.

In 1911 average

T2T
K. von Lumm, Die Stellung der Notenbanken, p, 39
holdings reached a peak of Ml62 million of bills (15 per cent of all
hills held) and M 78 million of balances.

011

These holdings were called

meet part of the deiqand arising from the Morocco crisis,

After

hat, though the Bank remained a relatively large dealer and investor
foreign bills and currencies, it tended to prefer gold«
9

On July 1,

it held M128 million of foreign bills and M 78 million of deposits




ter

the outbreak of war, most of the former were collected, In part

through neutral countries, whereas enemy countries blocked most cf the

latter *
Despite some exaggerated claims to the contrary by others, the
Reichsbank,
tions

initially at least, recognized that foreign exchange opera­

could not affect Germany's fundamental balance of payments

p o s i t i o n .

would
gold,

Holdings of foreign exchange were the practical equivalent

R*B. I, PP* 99-102. It recognized that purchases of foreign exchange
tend to force up the exchange rate and might lead to an export of
which is the opposite of what it desired.

of gold, were accumulated instead of importing gold, and could be sold
instead of exporting gold.

The distinction between gold and foreign

exchange was not unimportant at a time when gold movements were watched
closely and exerted great influence on business decisions» Tactically,
of course, dealings in foreign exchange enabled the Reichsbank to in­
fluence rates within the gold points and to smooth out erratic
fluctuations.
The Reichsbank gradually developed a number of related p ro ­
posals to deal with deposit banking*

Point VI of the bank inquiry

asked whether banks should be subjected by law (l) to reserve require­
ments ajid (2 ) to publishing periodic balance sheets in prescribed
(2 )
forms. -

^•M.C., German Bank Inquiry, Vol. 2, pp, vii-ix
On October 15 , 1908, as the commission was discussing Point
Chairman Havenstein announced that he had received a coimnitment

111

ei&ht large Berlin banks that they would voluntarily publish




^monthly statements.

This agreement related to the second question

The latter is printed in

German Bank Inquiry, Vol. 1,

pp. 687-689and further discussions of the entire Point VI were postponed*

When

they were resumed on November 23 , 1909,? the witnesses called attention
to certain excesses and evils, but they did not, in Havenstein?s words
feel "it necessary to set fixed limits by way of legislation, limits
•which are likely to put a restraint upon that freedom of movement which

(2 )
is, after all, indispensable to living forces.”
Havenstein, too,
T 2I

N.M.C*, German Bank Inquiry, Vol, 2, p. 801.

hoped it would not be necessary to have recourse to legislation; but he
warned that the evils had to be rooted out.
Many banks joined - some not voluntarily - in publishing b i ­
monthly statements.

But the objective of publication - sufficient

pressure to increase primary liquidity - was not achieved.
expressed it in 1912:

As von Lumm

"Despite the demand raised at the bank inquiry

for an increase in primary reserves, they have not in the interim been
(q )
improved in the least."
xtj

---------------K. von Lumm, "Diskontpolitik”, p, 182.
The Reichsbank, therefore, advanced a number of ancillary p r o ­

posals to make acceptance of its reserve proposals more palatable and to
increase its influence over money rates.

The Reichsbank*s analysis

prj------- -— _
_
Presi^ 16 ^roP°Bals apparently were discussed with bankers privately by
lugs f* havenstein over a period of time, probably in the monthly meetvised0th^ 16 cent’
ral committee, a statutory group of stockholders who ad"banks tLdirectors and which included individuals from most of the large
8erie' ^h.ey were published by director von Lumm as the fourth in his
s of articles in Bank Archiv, See "Diskontpolitik", pp, 179-18?.



of tne

evil ran in "t^le following terms.

The great hanks had expanded

nnously* much more so than the Reichsbank.

They competed aggress

for deposits by allowing high rates of interest; but this meant in
turn that they had to keep fully and continuously invested.
sequence

every demand for currency, as at the end of the year, forced

them to rediscount at the Reichsbank or borrow abroad.
acquired

As a con­

Then as they

funds, they became independent of the Reichsbank and invested

these funds at whatever rate they could secure.

By thus forcing the

prime rate down, they encouraged abuse of credit, speculation, new
issues - including foreign issues, and excessive and unsound credit
extensions.
The proposed solution was based on this analysis„

If the

hanks would enter a binding agreement on maximal rates they would allow
for deposits - tying the maximum to bank rate - they would save expenses
and would not be forced to compete so actively to employ their funds.
If, then, they would also agree on minimum rates of discount - again
tying the minimum to bank rate - they could maintain income without ex­
tending questionable and .unsound credits.

And finally, the reduction

in credit would enable the banks to increase their reserve deposits and
the Reichsbank its gold holdings.

The minimum reserves that the Reichs­

bank proposed were to be maintained only on the average so that banks
could themselves meet part of any drain without being forced immediately
to rediscount at the Reichsbank.

The expected accomplishments would be

to reduce the size of the ReichsbankTs job, to ^increase its ability to
handle it, and to make its rate effective.

The expected costs would be

essentially only the elimination of .unsound credit.
The whole analysis and each point in the solution were attacked




harply and at onoe, especially t>y Professor Plenge of Leipzig. ^

T I T Initially in the same magazine in which von Lumm had published his
•eS
See Bank Archiv, Vol. 11, 1912, pp. 219-226, 2b2-2k6, 251-261.
serl g'became dissatisfied with the treatment he received from the ediand published a book on the subject: Von der Diskontpolitik zur
y ^ p f t . uber den Geldmarkt, Berlin, 1913.
Plenge pointed out that a reduction in credit and acquisition

of cash by a banking system are not identical, since loans would be repaid
with deposits as well as cash.

The reduction in credit would have to be a

multiple of the acquisition of cash.

To follow the recommendations of the

Reichsbank until they resulted In a significant increase in its gold hold­
ings, therefore, would produce not an almost painless transition but a

severe depression.

Plenge also pointed out some of the implications - in­

cluding that of rationing and its administration - and disadvantages of the
rate (price) fixing proposals of the Reichsbank.
Plenge favored legal control rather than private agreements under
the aegis of the Reichsbank, replacing gold in circulation with small notes,
and above all a less avid search for earning assets by the Reichsbank, which
he considered the primary cause of its inadequate gold reserve.

In retro­

spect Plenge would appear to have had the better of the argument not only
* von Lumm but also with those like Arnold^f2 J*) who wrote in his defense.
with
There Is one aspect of the problem on which, even in retrospect,
it is difficult to come to a firm conclusion except somewhat arbitrarily.
aspect is the role of foreign funds.

One of the difficulties in

forming a judgment is the lack of reliable data on the development of
—

---------------

der
Arnold, "Die Barreserven der Kreditbanken und die Inanspruchnahme
thp ®ichsbankf' Bank Archiv, Vol. 11, pp. 363-315" Arnold was head of
he M i s t i c a l Division of the Reichsbank.




rmany's international financial position.

It is almost certain^1 )

^ ^ E l v e n this is not certain. One could cite data that were long taken
authoritative to prove the reverse. Although these data are now
aS .pect so is the method used to correct them! See Enquete-Ausschuss,
dpntsche Zahlungs'bilanz, pp. 130-133, and Der Bankkredit, pp. 80-8l,

that over-all Germany was a net creditor, that she was a large net credi­
tor on long-term, and a net debtor on short-term.

In individual years,

she was apparently a net debtor.
The Reichsbank and Plenge disagreed on the question of foreign
funds.

U n f o r t u n a t e l y - again in retrospect - the case of neither is

really c o nvincing.

The case advanced by the Reichsbank contains incon­

sistencies, both internal and in relation to its program as a whole.

Director von Lumm, for example, objected both that German banks paid
"too high" rates for short-term foreign funds and that, by borrowing
short funds abroad to take advantage of the higher rates in Germany, they
widened the spread between bank rate and market rates and thus defeated
the purposes o f the Reichsbank.

He also objected both that the banks

came to the Reichsbank in such large measure to meet the quarterly drains
and that they borrowed abroad to meet it - without indicating that he
understood that these might be alternative sources of funds.
other inconsistencies.

There were

Nevertheless, von Lumm did emphasize the dangers

of short-term foreign indebtedness, especially to countries that might use
threats or actual withdrawals for political purposes.
Von Lumm’
s discussion was a variation of the argument developed
later by S c h a c h t / 2 ^

p a l m a r




Schacht, Eigene oder Geborgte Wahrung. Berlin, 1927; PP-

h cht said that the German banks could defeat a restrictive policy of
h

Reichsbank b y borrowing abroad.

On at least one occasion he seri-

sly advanced the opinion that an increase in the Reichsbank rate would

lead to so much borrowing abroad that market rates would be reduced.

It

seems more reasonable to suppose that the net effect of tightening any

source of credit that is being used will be to tighten the entire market.
In other words, not all of the tightening b y the Reichsbank would be

dissipated through borrowing abroad.
Plenge, the skilled logician, attacked the Reichsbank case on

foreign funds with typical scorn.

He argued, among other points, that

the extent of short-term indebtedness had been exaggerated, that German
short-term claims had been underestimated or ignored, and that foreign
long-term securities could - and had been - liquidated to cover w i t h ­
drawal of short-term funds.

But above all, he argued that if the

Reichsbank would maintain adequate gold reserves it could meet foreign
withdrawals.

To help achieve and especially to maintain such reserves

in the long run, he felt that the Reichsbank would have to be less avid
in seeking discounts, would have to maintain a relatively higher rate.
A major weakness in his position is that he did not analyze the effect

of such a program on the volume of short-term foreign indebtedness.




The banks agreed that the reserves of the German economy
^

enlarged.

peration

They praised Havenstein for favoring voluntary

and opposing legislation as a means of achieving the goal;

b t though they lauded his leadership, they did not follow his recom­
mendations .
On January 30* 191^-* Representative Warmuth charged that no
progress had been made through voluntary cooperation since the program

had been launched in 1908.

He therefore proposed that a law be passed

to regulate deposit b a n k i n g . H a v e n s t e i n emphatically denied Warmuth

S.B. , 191^* PP* 6878-6879* Havenstein's reply appears at pp. 6902
6905.

charge.

As evidences of progress, he mentioned a resolution of the

German bankers association which specifically recommended an increase
in cash reserves and local agreements among banks to limit competition.
But he did admit that there had been no improvement in primary reserves
which was the goal of the program.

He attributed the lack of objective

results to special circumstances.
Havenstein took the opportunity to restate his position:
"What the Reichsbank considers necessary and wishes to
achieve is not a contraction of the credits necessary
and desirable for our economy but solely a gradual and
careful repression of excesses and exaggerations in the
use of deposits and other external funds for excessively
long-term or unhealthy purposes."




jf

this were done, he said that the hanks would he able to increase

their cash reserves and thereby strengthen the whole credit structure
oxxij

at the same time, reduce their demands on the Reichsbank,« I$y

holding their larger reserves as deposits at the Reichsbank - which the
"bankers associations also favored - the Reichsbank, in turn, would he

able to increase its gold holdings 0
Apparently Havenstein had not been impressed by the analysis
0f Plenge and still held a “
productive credit”theory of central hanking
in the belief that if each credit was ’
"proper" the total volume would
take care of itself-

He hoped that the banks would strengthen their

reserves sufficiently to meet out of their own resources a significant
part of any periodic increases in demand for liquidity by the economy*
In other words, he wanted a higher average reserve ratio, but expected
the ratio to fluctuate m o r e 0 Apparently he did not appreciate that this
policy would reduce rather than increase the power of the Reichsbank "to
regulate the monetary circulation 0

IIIo

E„

Impressions of Major Influences on Rate Policy
In retrospect, it appears that the Reichsbank was trying to

achieve four objectives that were not inherently consistent<> The over­
riding purpose, in case of conflict, was to maintain convertibility<>
The management increased its rate to whatever extent it believed neces­
sary to achieve it»

A second purpose was to keep rates as low as p o s ­

sible 0 This purpose conflicted at times with the first«

These con­

flicts were resolved by increasing the rates to unusual levels only
when compelled to do so by developments in the money market as reflected
i*1 high and rising market rates and by reducing bank rate as soon as




•
,, U >
m r ket developments permitted,

1,

The charts would seem to portray some exceptions« I have a hunch
that they arise from the fact that the market rates shown in the charts
are monthly averages, whereas bank rate is actual. A short, sharp
squeeze in the money market might be reflected clearly in bank rate but
not in monthly averages of market rates. I have not as yet had an op ­
portunity to analyze daily market rates.
A third purpose was to maintain as stable a bank rate as
possibleo

This purpose explains why bank rate was not adjusted to mar-

ket developments below a level that was clear-cut, at least during the
first two decadeso

The management appears to have had a general judgment

as to the minimum rate it could hope to maintain for any considerable
period.

Only rarely did it reduce its official rate below this point;

because it felt that stability of the rate was desirable.

During the

first decade this ''normal minimum *1 rate was 4 per cent, the lowest rate
that had ever been charged by its predecessor, the Prussian State Bank;
during the second decade it was 3 per cent; after the middle nineties
it was less specific but generally somewhat higher<> When this purpose

conflicted with maintenance of convertibility, it was sacrificed» When
it seemed to conflict with keeping rates as low as possible - in periods

of easy money - it was maintained on the general ground that it would
produce lower average rates in the long run even though not always the
lowest rate at every moment of time e
A fourth purpose was to maintain a large pprtfolio of b i l ls .
The ostensible purpose was to enable the management to observe at first
hand developments in the money market, although desire for profits
should not be ruled out entirely.

This purpose, like the second and

third, was subject to the. primary objective of maintaining converti­
bility,

The management devoted much time and thought to resolving the




periodic conflict in periods of easy money between maintaining a con­

tinuously large portfolio and maintaining a stable bank rate.

The issue

was made acute by the large seasonal variations in the demand for cur­
rency* which forced wide variations in either the portfolio, in market

rates, or both.

The Reichsbank objected to the wide spread that devel­

oped between bank rate and market rates when both were low.

It did not,

however, withdraw funds from the market in such periods to force market
rates up; because, to do so, would have reduced its earning assets.

Instead, it adopted a highly flexible preferential rate in the period

1880-1896, tried to secure agreements among the commercial banks that
they would not compete so actively through rates, and tried to induce
the banks to maintain larger average reserves.

None of these efforts,

of course, really reconciled the inherent conflict.
In establishing its own rate the Reichsbank clearly paid close
attention to the market rate on prime bills, apparently on the assumption
that this rate measured or reflected accurately the strength of basic
economic forces.

As one analyzes the composition, general orders of

magnitude, and sources of changes in the accounts of the Reichsbank, h ow ­
ever, it seems likely that the market rate varied at times "by accident”,
quite apart from "manipulations”attributed at times to the dealers who
I*
(1 )
"established" the rate.
As a single illustration:

the Reichsbank did

XT)-------- -------------Plenge, Diskontpolitik, pp. 184 and 3$ 2 , note 6k.
not distinguish regularly between reserve balances of banks and other
deposits; yet a shift from the former to the latter would tighten the
money market and a shift from the latter to the former would ease it.




[V.

Tta-slG P r o b l e m s o f Control

Can one integrate this episode in the history of a particular
central

bank into general principles of central banking?

tion, of course, could be inaccuratej
in time and space.

The

descrip­

one cannot really transpose oneself

But was the Reichsbank in position to pursue an effec­

tive policy if the description is essentially correct?
In forming a judgment on this question, it is important to r e ­
member that there are numerous ways in which a central bank may influence
the supply, availability, and cost of credit.

One should not, therefore,

judge effectiveness on the basis of a specified procedure.
recalled that Keynes came c l o s e to exclusiveness when,

It may be

in his Treatise

on Money, he developed the principle that the best measure of a central
bank's influence is its ability to establish the volume of member bank
reserves at predetermined levels.
~)

J. M. Keynes, A Treatise on Money, New York, 1930, Chapters 2, 25,
and 32 .
A few years later, Seymour Harris concluded that ’
’
Central banks
ought to concentrate their attention on the cash balances of member banks;
it alone is the variable to be controlled if they have any serious inten­
tion of exercising control over the money market.

UJ~~
->•

---- ;---------Harris, Twenty Years of Federal Reserve Policy, Cambridge, 1933?
I
quoted this statement with approval in a review of Harris* book
ln —el^w irtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. ^0, p. 7*

This conclusion, though widely held, is based on an overly
e-hdniotic view of central banking, deposit creation, and the flow of
ixerman monetary developments during the period under survey




cannonf bp
uc understood in terms of commercial bank reserves.

This negative

inc-inn is based on a number of considerations.
conclusion
In the first place, the Reichsbank did not publish data on
reserve

balances either in its weekly statements or annual reports .

Information is available only for isolated dates in its memorial volumes,
"he reason is that the management did not focus its attention on such
balances or try to establish them at predetermined levels.
In the second place, the Reichsbank could not have established
and maintained reserve balances at a predetermined level quite apart from
any question of controlling its own earning assets.

It should be recalled

that the volume of reserve balances was determined not exclusively by
changes in earning assets but by changes in all other accounts at the
Reichsbank as well.

The major items were cash reserves, other deposits,

and notes in circulation.

We may use the year 1910 for purposes of

analysis because June 15, 1910, is one of the few dates for which we have
the necessary information.

Reserve balances at M90 million were only a

small fraction of the size of other relevant accounts or even of annual
variations in some of them.

Since these accounts were not subject to

control or, in most cases, even to immediate influence by the Reichsbank,
it follows that the Reichsbank could not have controlled reserve balances
3-t predetermined levels.




1'ABLE VI
Sele cted A c c o l ints at the Reichsbanl
3.n 1910 (l ) ...
(in ml.11 ion marks )
Account

Notes
Metallic reserve
Deposits
public*
private*

Maximum

Minimum

2,073
1,183

1,379

921
476
55^

Spread

908
495
144

693
275
k-26
332

326

228

Public
Private
Banks***
Other financial
Other

Size on
June 15, 1910 **

303

260
90
53
117

*
Including float
** Excluding float
*** Joint stock banks

irj-----------------------R.B. II, pp. 31 , 41, 83 , 85 -86 , 113 .
In the third place, balances at the Reichsbank were only part
of the primary reserves of commercial banks.
tered and fragmentary information.

Again we have only scat­

The Reichsbank estimated that of

M773 million of primary reserves held by commercial banks in 1913, M532
million were in their own vaults and M2^1 million on deposit at banks
(2 )
of issue.
in other words^ control over reserve balances would not
Untersuchung des Bankwesens, Part II, p. 36 ° Savings banks divided
eir
million of primary reserves equally between vault cash and
ePosits at banks of issue.
been synonymous with control over total reserves.




In the fourth place, German banks did not maintain their
rimary reserves at any customary relationship to deposits.
not

required to hold minimum reserves against their deposits.

Banks were
The

Reichsbank did require minimum balances of all its customers including
banks,

but the purpose was to compensate it for services rendered in

cleari n g ,
not

transferring, and collecting payments.

Unfortunately, we do

have as frequent data on the condition of German banks as would be

desirable.

Prior to the agreement to publish bimonthly statements, we

have only the annual year-end statements.

It was common knowledge that

banks ’
’
dressed their windows” for the occasion.

From the middle 1890's,

when the great industrial expansion set in, until the reexamination of
policy, discussed in Section III-D, the ratio of the great banks fell
by half from about 15 per cent to about 7*5 P er cent.

The inquiry pro­

duced no significant improvement; but the decline was halted.

Bimonthly

reports revealed much lower ratios as well as significant variations in
the short run.
cent.

(1)

On February 28, 1911, lor example, the ratio was 3*7 per

Banks were not afraid to permit their primary reserves to run

"^l"J”
~

”
"1(
Karl Nordhoff, "Uber die Liquiditatsfrage,** in Untersuchung des
Bankwesens. Part I, vol. 2, p. ^91* N.M.C., Statistics for Great
Britain, Germany and France, 1867-1909, p* 21^, gives annual consoli­
dated balance sheets for German banks. The ratio for February 28, 1911,
is from von Lumm, "Diskontpolitik,” p. 182.

so low because they felt comfortable in the conviction that their port­
folio of eligible bills could always be rediscounted at the Reichsbank.
Confronted with such a loose-jointed system, one might be
tempted to conclude that the Reichsbank had little power to enforce its
will.

The impediments to an effective policy seem too formidable.




But

-this
the

conclusion

he premature.

The warranted conclusion is that

volume of reserve balances was only one - and by itself a relatively

unimportant

and

would

one at

conditions

in

“ of many connections between Reichsbank policy
the money market or the flow of expenditures.

It is important not to overestimate the independent power of
the G e r m a n c o m m e r c i a l banking system to expand its d e p o s i t s by reducing
its d e m a n d f o r liquidity - its primary r e s e r v e ratio.

Had an individual

hank attempted to expand in this way, it would, of course, have lost reserves in an amount almost e q u a l to the expansion.

Had all commercial

hanks moved in step, they would have lost cash through withdrawals.

The

ratio of deposits to circulation in Germany was approximately t w o . ^

So

long as this ratio was maintained, the r a t e of deposit expansion for the
system was only about twice the reduction in reserves, (2 )

Untersuchung des Bankwesens, Part II, p. 36 for deposits, and p.
for money in circulation.

kj2

W>

If one assumes no change in money in circulation - or a constant
volume of reserves - the volume of deposits varies inversely with the
reserve ratio and approaches infinity as the ratio approaches zero. If,
however, one assumes that the additional money in circulation must be
provided out of existing reserves, and deposits are twice money in cir­
culation, the maximum expansion of deposits remains twice the reduction
m reserves and this multiple does not Increase as the volume of reserves
is reduced.
Keynes, it may be recalled, felt that the relatively greater
importance of cash in Germany than in England was a real source of strength
°f the Reichsbank.

He reasoned as follows:

The part played by the Central Banks in most of
the pre-war European monetary systems, for example
in France or In Germany, was widely different from




that of the bank of England. The importance of
bank-notes relatively to cheques was far greater;
the resources of the Central Banks relatively to
those of the Member Banks were far greater (es­
pecially if we have in mind the resources avail­
able to meet fluctuations in the demand for work­
ing capital); there were no obstacles in the way
of increases in the Central Banks' "advances";
and the Member Banks were not tied by law or
custom to the maintenance of rigid reserve-ratios.
Since the Member Banks were not tied by reserve-ratios and were not prevented from freely
rediscounting with the Central Banks whenever
they wanted to expand their resources, the control
exercised over them by the Central Bank was very
imperfect, the main limitation on credit expan­
sion by the Member Banks being set by their supply
of bills eligible for re-discount. This weakness,
however, was balanced by the fact that, if Member
Banks as a whole were inclined to increase their
lending, they would get back as deposits a much
smaller proportion of the amount lent, because a
much larger proportion of the new loans would be
taken out in the shape of bank-notes. Thus the
Member Banks, having much less power than in Great
Britain to create credit, needed much less control, (l)

rn

Op. Cit., Vol. II, pp. 233-234.

This reasoning, it seems to me, diverts attention from the
heart of the problem to an interesting but essentially ancillary aspect
of it.

The key question is:

was the Reichsbank in position to enforce

its terms on the money market?
In answering this question, it is important to understand the
power of the Reichsbank to absorb any liquidity that the banks wished to
release.

At no time were its earning assets less than several times the




total primary reserves of the banks even as reported for the annual
■balance sheets.^ ^
The following illustrative data are taken from N.M.C., Statistics,

pp.

n k - 1 9 3 , 23i .

(in million marks)
End of
year

Reichsbank
Earning
assets
Discounts

1888
1893
1898
1903
1907

517
60^
865
Qk6

1,105

629
760
1,093
1,002
1,302

Primary reserves
of commercial banks
156
222
3h2

388
55^

The banks were fully aware that the liquidity of their portfolios of
eligible bills rested on the willingness of the Reichsbank to discount
them - and that to secure cash they would have to pay the rate established
by the Reichsbank.

The market as a whole was always indebted to the

Reichsbank and had to meet its terms to acquire additional reserves or
cash.

The Reichsbank had branches throughout the Empire at which credit

was available not only to commercial banks but to commerce, industry, and
agriculture as well.

A change in the terms on which the Reichsbank granted

credit was quickly felt at many points.

Although the administration of

discounting was not uniform at the branches (see above, pp. 2^-2 5 ), it
seems to me that the variations were not a significant link in the control
mechanism.

Administration of acceptability rules, of course, probably

operated to reinforce the policy, being tightened somewhat during expansion
and loosened somewhat during contraction.

The primary method of changing

lts terms, however, was to change its rate of discount.




The Reichsbank saw itself confronted b y essentially the same
problem both while the economy was experiencing slow, hesitant growth

and after this gave way in the middle 1 8 9 0 fs to unprecedented industrial
and commercial development.

The continuing problem, as the Reichsbank

saw it, was excessively liberal extension of credit by other lenders,
especially by banks.

During the period of easy money discussed in

Section III-B, it objected to the full investment policy of the inde­
pendent banks of issue.

During the period of prolonged prosperity

discussed in III-C, it objected to the rapid growth and the declining
reserve ratio of commercial banks.
Although emphasis shifted from notes to deposits, the Reichs­
bank viewed its problem as one of competition from other banks of one
kind or another.
own power.

This approach led the Reichsbank to underestimate its

In the earlier period, for example, it did not observe that

the full investment policy of the independent banks of issue reinforced —
rather than reduced —

its power to influence monetary developments.

In

the latter period, it did not observe that the market was continuously
indebted to it and had to meet its terms in securing cash.
Essentially, the Reichsbank tried to solve its problem by out­
bidding its competitors.
ential rates.
inappropriate.

In the earlier period it discounted at prefer­

It should not be inferred that making credit easy was
The important point is that the Reichsbank objected that

the independent banks of issue made credit so easy that it could not pursue
an effective policy.

In other words, it did not favor such low rates and

yet it met this problem by introducing preferential rates to acquire more
bills and thus ease credit still further.

In the later period it said that

1^'s P° licy was being frustrated by the actions of commercial banks which




discounted

at low rates.

But it kept its own rate low enough to increase

earning assets - without observing that it was thereby contributing to
the ease both directly and indirectly b y increasing the ability of others
to

expand.

It objected that other banks gradually reduced their reserve

ratios; but it followed their lead b y allowing reductions in its own.
Among the factors that led the Reichsbank to underestimate its
power w e r e an inability to appreciate that wide variations in the seasonal
demand for currency did not really weaken its power, a belief that somehow

it needed a large portfolio to pursue an effective policy, and a sensitivity
to criticism that its rate was usually higher than that of the other "great"
central banks.
The Reichsbank undoubtedly could have prevented the decline in its
own reserve ratio b y maintaining a somewhat higher discount rate.

For the

economy as a whole, however, it must be remembered that the Berlin money and
capital markets were intimately connected with their counterparts, especial­
ly in London, Paris, and New York.
substantial debtor on short-term.

Germany, though a net creditor, was a

(1 )

Had the Reichsbank maintained somewhat

U)
The distinction is important even though some of the long-term foreign
claims could be - and were - liquidated in time of trouble. Some institu­
tions followed a deliberate policy of not borrowing from prospective enemies.
For example, in its Annual Report for 1911 the Deutsche Bank stated at p. J :
For many years past we have so conducted our business that our short-term
indebtedness to foreign countries has been counterbalanced by quick assets
and loans abroad. In the critical times of the late summer of last year, our
position in this respect was especially strong. For a long time past we have
teen particular to abstain from becoming liable for short-term money from
France in any form whatsoever."
higher discount rates, it is almost certain that Berlin would have borrowed
wore in London and Paris.

The additional borrowing, however, would have

tended to force up rates in those markets also.

It is unlikely that all of

the pressure exerted b y the Reichsbank would have been absorbed.




My conclusion is that the Reichsbank was in position to pursue
an effective monetary policy.

Regardless of the reserve requirements that

the banks set for themselves at the moment, the Reichsbank was in position
to make cash scarcer, as measured b y interest rates, than the banks wanted
it to be.

The banks were never willing to accumulate sufficient cash dur­

ing the earlier months of the year to meet the autumnal and winter drains.
They had to go to the Reichsbank and meet its terms.

The Reichsbank did

not, however, develop an adequate procedure to withdraw funds from the

market as they returned from circulation.

It had sufficient earning assets

to do so; but it diverted its attention from the real nub of monetary con­
trol to the ancillary problem of who should bear the cost.
The international political atmosphere, however, leads one to
harbor a lingering doubt that a somewhat different policy b y the Reichsbank
would really have solved Germany's basic problem.

In retrospect one might

be surprised by the smoothness rather than b y the difficulties in meeting
the international monetary crisis of

1907 and

sion, as over Morocco and the Balkans.

the successive periods of ten­

Nevertheless, a large and rising

volume of short-term international indebtedness could not have been ignored
in a world of mounting international political tensions.




Date

End of month
Notes in
Metallic
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Vfp tU
FMa
l/BkTl»IkC
Reserve
ratio

rate
(Mo. average)

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

l i
jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug*
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

*51
485
499
521
564
550
531
540
504
487
506
501

657
631
678
677
659
778
691
666
740
733
720
7 66

68.6
76.9
73.6
77-0
85.6
70.7
76 .8
8 1.1
68.1
66.4
70.3
65.4

4.29
2 .7 8
2.83
2 .7 8
2.63
2.81
2 .8 7
2.53
3.01
3.51
3.19
3.28

Jan.
Jan.
Peb.

3
19
4

5.
6.
5.
4.

May

18

3.5

July

11

4.

Oct.

25

4.5

igiz
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

552
547
555
558
552
548
546
513
472
466
483
452

730
694
723
727
679
755
699
687
736
705
662
716

75-6
78 .8
76.8
76 .8
8 1.3
72.6
78 .1
7^-7
64.1
66.1
73.0
63.1

2.74
2.22
2.28
3.05
3.26
3.15
2.80
2.58
3.83
4.32
4.21
3.6 1

Jan.

5

May
June

11
16

i M
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec .

48l
524
503
494
513
510
511
499
469
455
477
472

645
621
645
625
593
673
637
619
671
638
588
664

74„6
84.4
78.0
79-0
8 6 .5
75-8
80.2
80.6
69.9
71.3
8 1 .1
71.1

2.94
2.31
2.26
2.62
2.84
2-99
2.8 7
2.59
3.53
4.09
4.22
3.5^

505
537
546
543
553
546
550
5^5
503
507
544
539

585
569
649
664
655
7^5
684
673
756
75^
719
793

86.3
94.4
84.1
8 1.8
84.4
73.3
80.4
81.0
66.5
67.2
75.7
68.0

3.17
2 .19
2.07
1.94
1.82
2.20
2.19
2.02
2.72
2.69
3.91
3.32

187?
Jan.
Feb .
Mar .
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oc t.
Nov .
Dec .



—

1

Sept. 12
Oct.
3
Nov. 12
Dec.
3

54.
5.
5-5
5*•5

Jan.

21

Aug.

29

5

Dec .

11

4.5

Jan.

11

4.

Mar.

21

3-

Aug.

13

4.

Oct.

11

4.5

D ec .

10

4.

Date

End of month
Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Ml 11 lor marks)

1880
Jan.
Feb.
Mar 0
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.

Oct 0
Nov „
Dec.

1881
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

Nov.
Dec.
1882
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July

Aug.

Sept .
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.
1883
Jan.
Feb.
Mar,
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov „
Dec.




568
583
572
576
593
582
576
536
535
539

547

728
727
786
774
718
8l4
748
724
786
750

714

Reserve
ratio
78.0
80.2
72 .8
74.4
82.6
71-5
77-0
74.0
68.1
71.9

76.6

Mar'k’
pt
rate
(Mo. average)
3.09
2.13
2.22
2.64
2.69
2.92
2.60
2.58
2.59
4.08
3.48
3.44

522

806

64.8

557
587
577

589
582
577
557
515
510
534
514

704
677
769
76l
724
839
740
740
839
791
755
859

79 =1
86.7
75*0
74.9
8.1.4
69.4
78.0
75.3
6l.4
64.5
7 0 .7
59-8

2.93
3.05
3.19
3.46
4.62
5.16
4 .76
4 .76

534
554
551
558
584
570
561
546
513
511
549
559

757
683
768
751
715
828
758
738
842
8l4
755
831

70.5
8 1 .1
71.7
74.3
8 1 .7
68.8
74.0
74o0
60.9
62.8
72.7
67.3

4.40
3.83
3.13
3.39
3.09
3.35
3.56
3.50
4.42
4.70
4* 64
4.67

617
634
617
621
644
615
613
601
548
547
585
559

733
692
780
751
703
820
741
725
806
789
747
830

84.2
9 1 .6
79-1
92.7
91.6
75.0
8 2 .7
82.9
68,0

3.52
2.71
2.77
2.72
2.65
3 ,2 1
3.12
2.90
3.15
3.48
3.35
3.37

570

69.3

78.3
6 7.3

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Aug.

18

Rate

Sept. 4
Oc t. 6
Oct. 18
Nov. 9

5^
5-5
54.5
4.

A ug . 2 6

5.

Oct.
Nov.

5
26

5.5
5-

Feb.
1
F e b . 18
Mar.
3
Mar. 10

6.
54.5
4.

Sept.

8

I

Jan,

4

1

3.04
2.16
2.2 7

2.63

r*--Date

r

End of month
Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Market
rate

Reserve
ratio

(Mo. average)

1884
Jan o
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct o
Nov.
Dee.

602
624
598
608
632
613
612
599
553
544
558
518

718
680
769
744
698
819
726
712
825
788
746
854

83.8
91.8
77.8
8 1 .7
90.5
74.8
84.3
84.1
67.0
69.0
74.8
60.7

2 .8 7
2.27
2.64
3.94
2.74
2.96
2.67
2.53
2.94
3.26
3.41
3.6 1

1885
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec .

553
578
558
566
609
597
598
591
558
594
624
618

724
682
773
732
683
8l4
727
712
824
775
728
859

76.4
84.8
72.2
77-3
89.2
73.3
82.3
83.0
6 7.7
76.6
85.7
71.9

3 .1 7
2.53
3.14
3.87
2.84
2.83
2.52
2.29
2.77
2.55
2.65
3.07

1886
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec „

671
700
682
687
713
705
735
730
670
652
676
670

732
705
823
795
764
910
812
811
947
872
845
1,010

91.7
99*3
82.9
86.4
93.3
77-5
90.5
90.0
70.7
74,8
80.0
66.3

2.12
1 .6l
1.81
1-79
1.74
2.19
1 .6l
1.71
1.99
2.56
2.86
3.90

720
753
7^3
773
805
803
8i4
810
743
751
791
767

860
806
921
864
811
961
849
828
959
912
884
1,0 11

83.7
93.4
80.7
89.5
99.3
83.6
95.9
97.8
77.5
82.3
89.5
75-9

3.29
3.0 1
2.34
1*93
2.03
2.4l
1.80
1.65
2.29
2.23
2.25
2.42

18§X
Jan.
Feb.
Mar,
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.



Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

Mar.
Apr.
May

10
4
11

54.5
4.

Jan.
Feb.

22
20

3.5
3.

Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

18
29
18

3.5
4.
5.

Jan.

18

4.

May

11

3.

Date




End of month
Metallic
Notes in
reserve » circulation
(Million marks)

821
857

840
912
989

Reserve
ratio

93

879
839

102

932

87
97

964
881

112

Market
rate
(Mo„ average)

Official bank ratie
Date of
change

Rate

1.68
1.45

I.85
1.55

1.56

988
992
964
882

1,059

948
940

104
102

1.69
Sept. 17

4.

860
866

1 , 0 11

972
1,093

85
89
78

2.45
3.24
3.15
3*51

Dec.

6

4.5

933
914

952
898
1,023

95
103

89

15
52

76

Jan.
Feb.

12
4

94

52

959

997
956

100

911

1,101

57
27
1.77

858
907

940
900
858
771
757
778
735

785

822
803

836
870
850
839
798
725
719
764
759

1,070

1,001

992
1,151
1,057

93

82

82
89
86

67

1.76

1.41

2.16
15

19

1,000

l sl6i

71
77-8
63.3

70

998
917

89.6

78.7

.83

1,052

997

940
l,o84
975
976

1,132

76.3
85.9

92 06
78 =4

86,1

81.8
64.0
68.3

78

.46
>75
.93
95
.72
.15

Feb. 22

,52

Sept. 26
Oct. 11

5.5

12

2.67

Jan.
Feb.
Feb.

3
13

4.
3.5
3.

2.85

May

15

4.

,07
‘
77

1,053
970
1,103

78.8
68.8

08

953

922

86.9
94.7

3.10
2.60

1 „04l

80*3

934

97.6
83,1
95-7

989

1,066

959
951
1,094
1,033
995
1,123

88.9

98.8

81.9
87.3

93.9
80.3

Sept,
Oct.

.14

2.68
3.26
3.32
3.20
3.30
3.20
3.13

2.92

End of month
Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Date

Reserve
ratio

Market
rate
(Mo, average)

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

1822
uTan
oU**Feb.
Mar.0
iW*
kr\r>0
Ayi
Ma
Weivj
June
July
Aug •
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

960
978
942
951
998
979
983
969
888
865
872
838

989
892
1,026
999
928
1,088
981
974
1,115
1,076
1,006
1,140

97.1
109.6
91.8
95-2
107.5
90.0
100.2
99,5
79-6
80.4
86.7
73.5

I .78
1.57
1.46
1.50
1.37
1-79
1.44
1.44
1.86
2.18
2.33
2.89

Jan.

11

3.

Oct.

28

4.

1893
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oc^fc.
Nov.
Dec.

901
924
869
863
886
8l4
810
804
739
773
827
798

988
928
1,070
1,013
947
1,100
990
950
1,101
1,033
962
1,110

91.2
99-6
81.2
85.2
93.6
74.0
81.8
84.6
67.1
74,8
86.0
71.9

1.77
1.31
1-75
2.06
2.83
3.14
3.10
4.06
4.63
4.51
4.52
4.40

Jan.

17

3.

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
UC 4
Z*0
wov .
T
\a* •
Dec

880
913
857
875
935
899
927
954
919
972
1,074
1,014

953
909
1,080
1,006
933
1,109
998
975
1,126
1,079
1,065
1,211

92.3
100.4
79.4
87.0
100.2
8l*l
92.9
97-8
81.6
90.1
100.8
8 3 .7

2.71
1.67
1.84
1.55
1.75
1.73
1.50
1,49
1.88
1.65
1.50
1.65

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.

1,092
1,096
1,039
1,070
1,076
1,011
1,018
991
915
914
903
853

1,056
984
1,157
1,096
1,060
1,228
1,093
1,074
1,283
1,192
1,149
1,320

103.4
111.4
89.8
97-6
101.5
82.3
93.1
92.3
71.3
76,7
78.6
64.6

1.38
1,26
1.63
1.55
1.74
2.10
1.64
1.57
2,50
2.54
2,93
3.33

May

12

4.

Aug.

11

5-

Jan.
Feb.

9
5

4.
3.

Nov.

11

4.

i§2£

Jo3ae «\
p it» .
UC g .

Nov

— -— — — _ _




Date

^896

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr*
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

i§21

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

Metallic
Notes in
reserve I circulation
(Million marks)

934
947
880
897
921
872
899
903
816
829
858
805
878
916
861
884
919
865
863
865

756

800

Reserve
ratio

Market
rate
(Mo. average)

1.078

86.6

1,011

2.90

1,249

93.7
70.5

2.28
2 .09

1,120

80.1

2 .2 1

88.6

2.66

70.9
83.3
86.4
64.9
73.4

2.38
2.52
3.41
4.09

1,040
1,230
1.079
1,045
1.257
1,129
1,065
1.258

80.6
64.0

1,050

83.6

983

93.2
62.7
79.5
87.9
70 .8
80.0

1,201

1,112

1,045

1,221
1,079
1,071
1,287
1,165

870
827

1,100

913
963
883
849
863
809
852
859
738

1,091
1,022
l f28l
1,162
1,078
1,266
1,097
1,064
1,340

1,320

80.8
58.7
68.7
79-1
62.7

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Feb.

Rate

12

3.

Sept. 7
Oct. 10

4.
5.

Jan. 19
Feb. 26

4.
3.

Apr.

10

3.

Sept. 6
Oct. 11

4.
5.

Jan.
Feb.

20
18

4.
3.

Apr.

9

4.

2.74

4.52

4.67

3.27
2.58
2.93
2.48
2.36
2 .6 7
2 .38
2.56
3.32

3.88
4.14
4.46

1828

1,211

83*7
94.2
68.9
73.1

80.1
63.9
77.7
8 0.7
55.1

.18
.59
•71
.07
.23
.57

.20

.21
.64

773
752

1,138
1,357

.02

67.9

55*4

.90
.26

Oct.
Nov.
Nov.

10
9
19

843
887
828
874
916
834
835
827
687
708
730
701

1,112

75.8
84.5

■
4.33
3.78
4.28
3.73
3.63
3-95
3.75
4.42
4.85
5.06
5.65
5.97

Jan.
Feb,

17
21

728

60.1

CTnUI VJl

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

1822.
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.



1,050
1,265
1,158
1,104
1,300
1,11 8
1,090
1,383

65.5

75.5
83.0
64.2
74.7
75.9

49.7

1,221

58.0

1,148
1,359

63.6
51.6

5.
4.5

May
June

9
19

4.
4.5

Aug.

7

5.

Oct.

3

6.

Dec.

19

7.

Date

End of month
Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Market
rate

Reserve
ratio

(Mo. average)

1222.
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr •
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

805
835
744
801
845
822
860
848
725
767
8l4
730

1,100
1,031
1,310
1,165
1,091
1,310
1,122
1,096
1,344
1,233
1,166
1,410

73,2
8l.O
56,8
68.8
77.5
62.7
7 6 .6
77.4
53-9
62.2
69,8
51.8

4.42
4.21
5.21
4.43
4.56
4.86
4.06
4.03
4.41
4.03
4.16
4.49

1?01
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

856
894
812
913
971
897
958
931
830
896
921
869

1,156
1,057
1,321
1,176
1,108
1,375
1,230
1,196
1,430
1,284
1,221
1,466

7^*0
84.6
61.5
77-6
8 7.6
65.2
77.9
77.8
58.0
69.8
75*4
59.3

3.57
3.22
3-79
3.38
3.19
3.20
2 .8l
2.26
2.68
2.83
2.84
2.9 6

1,008
1,050
95 6
1,038
1,072
991
1,021
981
840
858
878
786

1,202
1,116
1,349
1,247
1,182
1,410
1,232
1,191
1,^95
1,327
1,248
1,516

83.9
94.1
70.9
83.2
90-7
70.3
82.9
82.4
56.2
64.7
70.4
5 1,8

2 .1 1
1.85
1-79
1.65
I .98
2.17
1-59
1.73
2.14
2.73
3.12
3.38

892
919
818
875
909
884
926
934
858
866
899
793

1,235
1,166
1,450
1,260
1,199
1,435
1,216
1,197
1,516
1,360
1,278
1.565

72.2
78 .8
56.4
69.4
75-8
6 1 .6
76.2
78.0
56,6
6 3.7
70.3
50.7

2 .26
1.90
2.69
2.62
■3.09
' 3.29
2.96
3.30
3.68
3.32
3.46
3.54

mi

Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

Jan,
Jan.

12
27

6.
5,5

July

13

5-

Feb.

26

4.5

Apr.

22

4.

June

18

3.5

Sept. 23

4.

Jan.
Feb.

18
11

3-5
3.

Oct.

4

Feb.

11

June

8

4.

A222.
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.




3*5

4.




End of month
Metallic | Notes in
reserve 1 circulation
(Million marks)

Reserve
ratio

Marke t
rate
(Mo. average)

913
937
828
910
965
870
926
925
793
902
1,000
927

1,240
1,182
1,497
1,314
1,210
1,478
1,270
1,251
1,599
1,379
1,294
1,600

73.6
79.3
55-3
69.3
79-8
58.9
72.9
73.9
49.6
65.4
77 “
3
57.9

2 .58
2.77
3.44
2.83
3.10
2.98
2.60
2.62
3.09
3.69
3.99
3.94

1,069
1,096
1,016
1,054
1,073
951
961
932
732
794
843
80 4

1,284
1,211
1,544
1,349
1,273
1,555
1,320
1,308
1,683
1,442
1,330
1,657

83,3
90,5
65.8
7 8 .1
84.3
61.2
72.8
71.3
43.5
55.1
63.4
48.5

2,56
1*93
2.22
1.92
2.30
2.34
2.12
2.23
2.99
4.01
4.62
4.99

954
970
889
974
1,012
844
912
B 78
675
737
766
665

1,324
1,250
1,629
1,396
1,323
1,648
1,377
1,360
1,704
1,485
1,396
1,776

7 2 .1
77-6
54.6
69.8
76.5
51.2
66.2
64.6
3 9 »6
49.6
54.9
37.4

3.8 1
3.35
4.02
3 .44
3.39
3.68
3.49
3.43
4.23
4.83
5.27
5.58

843
890
776
898
953
831
878
861
737
750
679
704

1,412
1,340
1,731
1,510
1,419
1,729
1,478
1,453
1.825
1,6 17
1,511
1,886

59.7
66.4
44.8
59.5
67.2
48.1
53-4
59-3
40.4
46.4
44.9
37-3

4.90
4.68
5-40
4.65
4.44
4.66
4.44
4.62
5.08
4.91
6.61
7-07

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

Oct.

11

5-

Jan.
Peb.
Peb.

10
14
25

4.
3-5
3.

Sept. 11
Oct.
3
4
Nov.
D e c . 11

4.
5.
5.5
6.

'

Jan.

18

5.

May

23

4.5

Sept. 18
Oct. 10

5.
6.

Dec.

18

7.

Jan.

22

6.

Apr.

23

5-5

Oct.
Nov.

29
8

6.5
7.5 .

STATISTICAL APPENDIX

REICHSBANK RATE AND RELATED FACTORS (continued)
i
r " -------- —
Date

——
1308
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.
122!
Jan.
Feb.

Mar.
Apr.

May
June

July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

End of month
Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Reserve
ratio

Market
rate
(Mo. average)

886
918
871
947
1,006
1,032
1,097
1,127
1,034
1,064
1,087
980

1,484
1,411
1,782
1,542
1,456
1,795
1,519
1,494
1,897
1,674
1,547
1,975

59-7
65.I
48.9
61.4
69.1
57*6
72.2
75.4
54.5
63.6
70.3
49,6

4.98
4.48
4.49
4.11
3.91
3.33
2.76
2.82
3.14
2.79
2.54
2.92

1,096
1,091
1,013
1,059
1,063
1,029
1,067
1,0 64
910
925
982
915

1,512
1 ,4l8
1,853
1,623
1,508
1,886
1,597
1,565
2,023
1,736
1,599
2,072

72.5
76.9
54.7
65.2
70.5
54.6
66.8
68.0
45.0
53.3
61.4
44.2

2.24
2.17
2.66
1.98
2.32
2.91
2.28
2.13
3.06
3.83
4.47
4.34

1,060
1,082
1,041
1,089
1,140
1,027
1,059
1,047
908
947
1,014
924

1,579
1,480
1,916
1,667
1,536
1,924
1,617
1,578
2,056
1,751
1,599
2,073

67.1
73.1
54.3
65.3
74.2
53.4
65.5
66.3
44.2
54.1
63.4
44.6

3.09
2.94
3.52
3.14
3.19
3.23
3.03
3.33
3.85
4.15
4.50
4.53

1,10 7
1,139
1,059
1,135
1,178

1,573
1,486
1,974
1,659
1,558
1,965
1,647
1,640
2,295
1,915
1,755
2,251

70.4

3.50
3.07
3.34
2.96
2,84
3.38
2.46
3.03
4.16
4.32
4.51
4.86

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

Jan.
Jan.
Mar.
Apr.

13
25
7
27

6.5
6.
5.5
5-

June
June

4
18

4.5
4.

Feb.

16

3.5

Sept. 20
Oct. 11

4.
5-

Jan.
Feb.

4.5
4.

1310
Jan.
Feb.

Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.
m i
Jan.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
1,,..
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.



1,121

1,178
1,170
995
1,053

1,106
1,008

76.6
53.6
68,4
75.6
57*0
71.5
71-3
43.4
55*0

63.0

44.8

2
10

Sept. 26

Feb.
Feb.

6
18

Sept. 19

5,

4.5
4.

5-

End of month
Date

1?12
J •
pgb .
Ms
pjalTi*•
Aor.
May
June
July
Aug •
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.
1^13
Jan.
Feb.

Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July
Aug.
Sept.
Oct.
Nov.
Dec.

Metallic
Notes in
circulation
reserve
(Million marks)

Reserve
ratio

Market
rate
(Mo. average)

1,185
1,223
1,152
1,240
1,251
1,228
1,271
1,240
1,145
1,132
1,065
1,037

1,720
1,608
2,099
1,786
1,657
2 *008
1,743
1,753
2,274
1,993
2 ,010
2,519

68.9
76 .1
54.9
69.4
75-5
58.8
72.9
70.7
50.4
56.8
53.0
41.2

3.33
3.79
4.72
3.75
3.91
4.14
3.36
3.93
4.38
4.19
5.23
5.94

1,170
1,192
1,207
1,252
1,318
1,363
1,418
1,401
1,408
1,462
1,503
1,447

1,962
1,876
2,325
2,051
1,913
2,317
1,949
1,916
2,456

59.6
63.5
51-9
6l.O
68.9
58.8
72.8
73.1
57.3
69.0
75-8
55.8

4.68
5.15
5-90
4.56
5-31
5.53
4.65
4.88
5-35
4 .7 1
4.45
4.57

76.7
82.4
65.0
78.9
81.2
67.8
52.5

3.11
3.06
3.37
2 .38
2.60
2.86
2.48

2,119

1,982
2,593

Official bank rate
Date of
change

Rate

June

11

4.5

Oct.
Nov.

24
14

56.

Oct.

27

5-5

Dec.

12

5.

Jan.
Feb.

22
5

1214

Jam.
Feb.
Mar.
Apr.
May
June
July

1,575
1,611
1,579
1,657
1,635
1,631
1,528

Sources:
Metallic Reserves:

2,053
1,954
2,428
2 ,101
2,014
2M l

2,909

1876-19 10 , Memorial Volume:

Die Reichsbank, 1876-1910, pp. 26-51
1911-1914, Memorial Vol u m e :
Die Reichsbank, 1901-1925, P- 16
otes in Circulation: 1876—1887s Verwaltungsberlchte der Reichsbank
1888-1907, National Monetary Commission
Statistics for Great Britain, Germany
and Prance, 1867-1909, pp. 174-193
ib u
1908-191^, Verwaltungsberichte der Reichsbank
r et Rates:
1876-1910, Memorial Volume:
Die Reichsbank, 1876-1910, pp. 206-207
1910-1914, Statlstische Jahrbflcher fflr das
Offi

c al Bank Rates:




Deutsche Reich

1876-19 0 7, National Monetary Commission
Statistics for Great Britain, Germany
and France, 1867-1909 > P- 200
1908-1914, Memorial Volume:
Die Reichsbank, 1901-1925, PP- 90-91

4.5
. 4.