View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Approximately 1:00 p.m., EDT,
Thursday, May 20, 1965.

NATIONAL GOALS AND INTERNATIONAL RESPONSIBILITY:
SOUNDING A CHANNEL BETWEEN THE SHOALS

By
Karl R. Bopp
President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Bankers Luncheon
Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Banks of New York and Philadelphia
62nd ANNUAL CONVENTION OF THE NEW JERSEY BANKERS ASSOCIATION
12:45 p.m., Thursday, May 20, 1965
Wedgwood Room, Haddon Hall, Atlantic City, New Jersey




NATIONAL GOALS AND INTERNATIONAL RESPONSIBILITY:
SOUNDING A CHANNEL BETWEEN THE SHOALS

By Karl R. Bopp

In the two years since I spoke to you last, we have endured strains
and stresses:

the assassination of a President; international political

crises, ranging from the Gulf of Tonkin incident to the policy of strategic
bombing in Viet-Nam north of the 17th parallel and the threat of a communist
take over in the Dominican Republic; the deposition of Premier Khrushchev,
and the wrath of General De Gaulle.
On the economic front, the superstructure of economic finance created
since World War II has helped us to weather crises ranging from speculative
flare-ups in the London gold market to a major attack on the pound sterling.
Wherever we look we see complex problems without apparent solutions
on which all can agree.

Some individuals propose their own simple solutions

but when one compares their several solutions they frequently cancel out.
We have all been forced to reconsider our objectives and the appropriate
means of achieving them.

Today I should like first to trace how new problems

have emerged and forced us to recognize the inadequacy of our inherited
solutions, and second to comment on the current efforts to achieve our multiple
objectives•
I begin with my own introduction to the study of economics some
forty years ago.

We developed an internally consistent theory —

is now phrased, we constructed a model —

or as it

in which reasonably full utilization

of resources, a reasonably stable level of prices and reasonable balance in our




-2-

international accounts were consistent goals whose achievement would produce
growth.
In broadest outlines, the theory ran something like this.
suppose that a country is experiencing a recession.
unemployment and declining prices.

Let us

It will have rising

The lowered prices will make it a

favorable place from which to buy and a poor market in which to sell.

The

developing favorable balance of trade would be financed by gold imports and
capital exports.

Pursuit of all objectives would call for a cheaper and

easier monetary policy.

As such policies stimulated aggregate demand,

employment would rise, in due course prices would rise also, and the
international trade position would become unfavorable.

At this point all

signs would point to a tightening of monetary policy.
I need not tell you that American economic development since the
end of the war has not fit this model.

During the war and early postwar

period it was assumed that unemployment would be our major economic problem.
You may recall the gloomy predictions of economic chaos.
1930's reappeared.

The specter of the

The vast increase in productive capacity created during

the war brought visions of large chronic unemployment.

One result of our

concern with unemployment was passage of the Employment Act of 1946, which
directed all agencies of Government to coordinate their efforts toward the
end of fostering maximum employment.
Yet even then anxious eyes were scanning the horizon for other
problems which might disrupt the nation's economic equilibrium, problems
which would increase the likelihood of conflict in the attainment of
multiple objectives.
These problems were quick to emerge.

Fears of massive unemployment

soon gave way to a growing concern with inflation.




The high volume of liquid

-3assets accumulated during the war years, combined with generally rising current
income and removal of direct controls, helped to stimulate a massive demand for
goods.

The result:

rapidly rising prices.

Between 19^5 and 19^9 consumer prices jumped 25 per cent and wholesale
prices climbed over 30 per cent.

The President, in his economic reports to

Congress, expressed grave concern over the problem.

Though restrained in its

actions by the policy of supporting Government security prices, the Federal
Reserve stressed the importance of price stability.
In short, the problem of maintaining price stability had taken its
place beside that of promoting maximum employment.

In the late 1940*s a dip

in Gross National Product and in personal income was accompanied not only by
rising unemployment but by rising prices —
implied.

not falling prices, as our theory

The multiple objectives of national economic policy raised the

possibility of conflict and led to revival of the so-called cost-push theory
of inflation.
Nor did the problem of multiple goals stop here.

As the postwar

period progressed, political developments added new dimensions to our
economic problems.
At the end of World War II, this nation heaved a collective sigh of
relief.

The war was won.

achieved in our time.

The nation seemed confident that peace had been

American troops came home.

Military forces were reduced.

Indeed, so rapid was the return to civilian life that some called it a military
disintegration rather than a demobilization.
Soon, however, the bright hopes of peace and world cooperation were
dashed upon the stark reality of Soviet expansionism.
Soviet military might —
satellites —

200 divisions in Europe plus the forces of its

faced the largely disarmed and economically feeble Western

European democracies.



The awesome power of

-4-

That was the world scene.
strikingly

Something had to be done to redress the

one-sided balance of power.

The United States was the only nation

which could do the job.
In the process of coming to grips with the Soviet threat — and that,
of course, is a long story in itself — new national economic goals emerged.
Increasing emphasis was placed upon growth.

We wanted not only maximum

employment but also a rising real output per capita, so that we could meet
commitments abroad and, at the same time, raise living standards at home.
But our increasing foreign commitments had even further effects on
our set of economic goals.

Building and manning military bases and installations

and aid for reconstruction and development created a large outflow of dollars.
As long as foreigners used dollars to buy our products and to build depleted
monetary reserves to desired levels, all went well.

Indeed there was widespread

concern that the world was faced with a "dollar gap" that could not be filled.
But insoluble problems are transient.
dollar gap became a dollar glut.

By the end of the fifties the

As the countries devastated by war were rebuilt,

they became relatively less dependent upon the United States for imports —
became competitors in foreign and domestic markets.

indeed,

With business booming abroad,

our citizens and corporations invested in productive enterprises and high-yielding
loans and securities in foreign lands.
Once again the American people had a lot of new thinking to do.

By

1958, when great strides were made toward currency convertibility abroad, we
found ourselves paying to foreigners far more than we received.

Reduction of

this deficit was added to our list of national economic goals.

Once more the

probability increased that multiple goals might come into conflict and that
relative priorities would have to be reconsidered and a proper mix of national
economic policies would have to be developed to bring optimum results.




-5This is precisely where we find ourselves today.

Let us, therefore,

focus our attention on the more recent behavior of our policy goals.

What has

been the recent trend of prices, employment, the balance of payments and
economic growth?

What guides do these trends offer to the Federal Reserve

System?
As for prices, we are experiencing the most sustained period of
stability in wholesale commodity prices in our entire economic history.

This

would suggest that policy has been about right and should not be changed.
On the other hand, unemployment has remained a serious problem,
holding at near five per cent of our labor force, well above the four per cent
interim target level of national economic policy.

Unemployment, as a guide to

monetary action, would suggest a need for greater monetary ease.
Next, our balance of payments showed a sizable deficit in 1964, and
as a guide to policy, would call for greater restraint.
Finally, real output per capita rose substantially more in 1964 than
in all but one of the past five years.

Unfortunately, our enthusiasm for this

result is modified by the fact that we still have large unused material as well
as human resources.

As a guide to policy, therefore, growth does not give a

clear indication.
Totaling up the scoreboard, then, we have one vote for no change:
prices; one vote for greater ease:

unemployment; one vote for more restraint:

the balance of payments; and one indecisive vote:

growth.

Obviously the

objectives of policy give us conflicting guides to the implementation of policy.
We need more than mere statistics.

We need to use judgment.

We, as

central bankers, like you, as commercial bankers, must weigh risk against return.
According to the theory of my youth our only option would be to weigh
the benefits that tighter money might confer on the balance of payments against




-6-

the risks that it would weaken the underpinnings of domestic growth and
employment.

Faced with this dilemma, it is surely understandable that one

would take another look at his theory.
Although the balance of payments and unemployment are related, there
is merit in analyzing them separately with the hope of devising means of
dealing constructively with each without imperiling the other.

This selective

approach is the direction in which national economic policy has been moving.
Let us look first at employment.

It is increasingly clear that in a

rapidly automating society, full employment without inflation calls for both
a high level of aggregate demand and for qualified workers in the right place.
On the side of stimulating consumer demand we have had the income
tax cuts of 1964 and 1965 and have excise tax cuts in prospect.

The Federal

Reserve, on its part, has facilitated the flow of a large and increasing volume
of funds at moderate rates through the capital and mortgage markets.

Total funds

flowing through the capital markets increased from $58 billion in 1962 to $62
billion in 1963 and $71 billion last year.
In dealing with structural unemployment, it is recognized the skills
and education necessary to gain employment often do not coincide with the skill
and educational level of the job seeker.

Examples of actions designed to deal

with that problem include the Manpower Development and Training Act of 1962; the
Economic Opportunity Act of 1964, better known as the Anti-Poverty Bill, which
established such programs as the Job Corps to provide work experience and training
for youths in conservation camps and in urban and rural training centers with
emphasis on remedial education and manual skills, Neighborhood Youth Corps for
training and part-time work aimed at 16 to 21 year olds who are school dropouts
or potential dropouts; the Elementary-Secondary Education Bill with a first year
expenditure estimated at $1 billion to be allocated to school districts which




-7have large numbers of low-income families; the Appalachia Assistance Bill,
which authorizes expenditures of more than $1 billion for the development
of that depressed region.
Let us now look at the balance of payments.
combined the general with the selective approach.

Here, too, we have

The chief contribution

that monetary policy has made has been in the short-term area.

Treasury

bill rates, which were below 2j per cent in 1961 are now near 4 per cent.
The banking system, which held net free reserves of about $100 million a year
ago, has recently been operating under the constraint of more than $100 million
of net borrowed reserves.

At the height of the sterling crisis last year the

discount rate was increased from 3 j per cent to 4 per cent, as high a level as
any in the past 35 years.

The Treasury has contributed to these results by

issuing additional bills.

Taken together, these actions have enabled

U. S. Treasury bills to remain competitive on a covered basis with short-term
Government issues in London and Canada.
In addition, interest rates on official foreign and international
time deposits were made exempt from Regulation Q and maximum rates on other
time deposits were raised successively to enable American banks to compete
for foreign private deposits.
The Federal Reserve has entered into arrangements with foreign
central banks whereby reciprocal lines of credit are made available to
provide financing for temporary balance of payments needs.

At present such

swaps with eleven central banks and the Bank for International Settlements
exceed $2j billion.

Their effectiveness in preventing crises has been

illustrated on numerous occasions, such as the time of the assassination of
President Kennedy.

Frequently natural forces have operated to enable such

swap drawings to be repaid before maturity.




Incidentally, a complete report

-8-

of such operations is published regularly in the FEDERAL RESERVE BULLETIN.

The Government has taken other measures to absorb dollars that
might otherwise have been converted into gold.

In has sold special issues

of securities —

the so-called Roosa bonds —

to countries that have accumulated

excess dollars.

It has negotiated agreements with individual countries to use

accumulated dollars to prepay debts owed to the United States.

It has made

agreements with West Germany to offset our defense expenditures there with German
equipment purchases here.

It has intensified its effort to trim military outlays

abroad and to see that all possible foreign-aid dollars are spent in this country.
With restoration of convertibility in the late 1950's, vast new
opportunities for private American investment became available, and such
investment added to our balance of payments problem.

We continued to export

each year more than we imported; but the balance was not sufficient to offset
our continuing governmental expenditures for defense and development and these
rising investments.

Each year we became wealthier on international account,

but as we increased our solvency, we reduced our liquidity.
Measures have been taken to increase the net yield of domestic
investment relative to that of foreign investment.
were increased.

Depreciation allowances

An investment tax credit of 7 per cent is allowed for new

plant and equipment.

The corporate income tax rate has been reduced both last

year and this.
An interest equalization tax has been inposed on purchases by United
States citizens of stock and debt issues of selected foreign nations to make
investment in those countries less attractive.

Recently, the tax has been

extended to bank loans of one year or more maturity to the same countries.
A program is also being prepared to encourage foreign investment in the United
States.




-9-

In February, the President called on banking and business to exercise
restraint in lending and investing abroad.

He asked the Federal Reserve System

to guide the program as it affects financial institutions and the Secretary of
Commerce to supervise others.
Guidelines have been developed to permit a maximum of flexibility
and yet achieve the national purpose.

For banks, over-all targets have been

established at 5 per cent above the level of credit extended at the end of
last year.

Within this target priorities are established for export credits and

underdeveloped countries.
Although it is too early to measure the results of the program,
preliminary indications are highly favorable.

Euro-dollar rates have risen

and there is evidence that dollars are not as readily available abroad.
Occasional complaints are heard from some of those who were most emphatic that
we "do something" about our balance of payments, that we now be careful not to
go "too far."
The use of selective as well as general measures arises from the
complex nature of our problems.

They are designed to redress our balance of

payments without depressing domestic prosperity and thus aggravating our
unemployment.
Looking to the longer run, we have some powerful economic forces
working for us.

We have maintained stability in our wholesale price level.

In contrast, industrial prices in the European Common Market have increased
more than 10 per cent on average in the past four years.

We have achieved

this record through research and development which has increased our efficiency
and resulted in rising standards of living.
this excellent record; and it can be done.




It is imperative that we continue

-1 0 -

Second, our investment in the rest of the world exceeds foreign
investment here by some $40 billion.
plus in our balance of payments.

The net return each year is a powerful

As Western Europe catches up and develops

its own capital markets, the relative attractiveness of their markets for
our funds may well diminish, particularly if we maintain or increase our rate
of growth at home.
Third, continued negotiations with our allies to share more
equitably the military and economic aid burdens and to reduce tariff barriers
and other trade restrictions could produce significant results for our balance
of payments.
We do, indeed, have powerful forces working for us in the long run.
But we are confronted with temporary difficulties.

It is important, therefore,

that the voluntary restraint program be successful.

Once we demonstrate that

we have brought our balance of payments under control, we can hope to make
progress in devising a more effective international monetary and financial
system.

Such a system should indeed put pressure on a member that is running

a deficit because of domestic inflation.

It should not require a member that

has stable prices and large unused resources to put pressure on its own economy.
An economic sneeze in the United States may no longer spread pneumonia
abroad, but it remains true that the greatest bulwark of the western world is a
prosperous and growing United States.




#

#

#

#

#