View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 6, 1955

To:

Mr. A. H. Williams

From:

Karl R. Bopp

Re:

Some comments generated by the discussion concerning the discount
rate at the meeting of the Board of Directors on September 1, 1955-

MONEY MARKET IMPLICATIONS OF NEGATIVE FREE RESERVES

I.

The discount rate, market rates, free reserves and member bank borroving
Since free reserves are defined as excess reserves minus member

bank borrowings from the Federal Reserve Banks, they can be negative only
if borrowings exceed excess reserves.

Furthermore, since excess reserves

rarely fall below $§■ billion, free reserves do not reach a negative level
until borrowing exceeds that figure.

In other words, negative free re­

serves mean that the money market is dependent directly on the Reserve
Banks to a considerable degree.
Attempts of member banks to reduce this dependence, either be­
cause of tradition possibly reinforced by moral suasion or because it is
made more expensive, will tend to tighten the money market in terms of
both availability and cost of credit.
But these attempts to reduce dependence will be frustrated if a
specified level of negative free reserves continues to be the goal.
primary effect will be a further rise in market rates.

A

If the discount

rate is to continue to be a penalty rate or to lead the market, it will
have to be increased again.
We may begin with member bank borrowing of, say, $700-800
million and negative free reserves of $100-200 million.

The discount

rate is raised to lead the market - or to make it a penalty rate.
this penalty rate will not reduce borrowing so long as open market




But

- 2 -

operations are designed to maintain negative free reserves at the original
level.

Market rates, however, may he expected to rise because credit has

become more expensive at one of its important sources (Federal Reserve
Bank discount windows).

If the new discount rate is to be kept above

market rates, it will have to be increased again.
The point is that the periodic upward adjustments of rates could
be very rapid.

Too rapid an upward adjustment could create a liquidity

crisis.
An ultimate purpose of tightening the market is, of course, to
curb demand, but the question of policy is the speed with which the brakes
should be applied.

Although the central bank operates in the money mar­

ket, its ultimate purpose is to influence the flow of purchases throughout
the economy.

If the existing tone of the money market is judged to be

appropriate to the state of the economy, the discount rate should not be
changed for the purpose of assuring that it will continue to "lead" rather
than to "follow" market rates.

II.

Anticipations and the rate structure
Although many factors influence the time structure of interest

rates, a pervasive influence is the market's expectations as to rates in
the future.

If the market expects rates to rise, the slope will tend to

be positive (rates on short maturities will be lower than those on longer
maturities).

The basic reason is that borrowers will wish to issue long

terms before the expected rise takes place, and the lenders will hesitate
to invest in long issues until after the expected rise has taken place.
In other words, the expectation tends to increase the demand for and to
reduce the supply of long-term funds.

At the same time, lenders, not

wishing to keep funds idle, will tend to invest in short terms, whereas




- 3 -

borrowers will borrow on short term only if they secure a rate concession.
The expectation of a rise tends to increase the supply of and reduce the
demand for short-term fundsc
If the market expects rates to rise, it may be difficult to
force up short-term rates without "drying up" the long-term capital mar­
ket to a greater extent than may appear desirable.